Analyse économique de l*intermédiation * Application au transport

advertisement
Economic Analysis of Intermediation
Applied to Road Transport
Maurice Bernadet
IRU - 21 February 2014
1
• While there are intermediaries in all sectors of economic
activity, economic theory has focused solely on intermediation
in finance. There are also some studies - more applied than
theoretical, however - devoted to trade intermediaries. To my
knowledge, no specific work has been devoted to the logic of
intermediation and the role of intermediaries in the field of
transport in general, and road transport in particular.
• However, we can use the concepts and analysis of the so-called
“New-Institutional Economics” in an attempt to understand this
logic and this role.
• We shall present an extremely simplified overview of neoinstitutional analysis, although this is a very broad approach,
whose scope does not specifically address intermediation
issues.
2
Presentation Outline
1. New Institutional Economics
2. Transaction Costs
3. Integration vs. Outsourcing in the Transport
Sector
3
Part I
New Institutional Economics
4
New Institutional Economics
• New Institutional Economics are linked to two extremely
famous economists, as both of them received the Nobel Prize.
• The first is Ronald Coase, a British economist, but who spent
most of his career in the USA. In 1991 he was awarded the
Nobel Prize "for his discovery and clarification of the
significance of transaction costs and property rights for the
institutional structure and functioning of the economy".
• In 1937 he wrote The Nature of the Firm, the founding article
for New Institutional Economics.
5
New Institutional Economics
• The second author whose work we shall refer to is Oliver
Williamson. This American economist born in 1932 received the
Nobel Prize in economics in 2009.
• Williamson developed the concept of transaction costs, rooted
in Coase’s 1937 article, and turned it into an essential tool for
analysis of market economy.
• Both authors have in common a closeness to the legal
dimension of economic operations. Institutions (hence the
“neo-institutional” approach) and contracts are at the heart of
their analysis.
6
New Institutional Economics
• Both authors are particularly interested in the way in which
activities by economic actors are coordinated. They
schematically distinguish two methods of coordination:
- by grouping activities within an institution – the company –
which operates according to a hierarchical rule and is based on
the principle of authority;
- by coordination in the market, which operates in a
decentralised way through contractual procedures and the
price mechanism.
• Both these forms of coordination are alternate as well as
complementary and may be combined in a host of different
ways (networks, franchises, subsidiarising, etc., which are
“hybrid” forms).
7
New Institutional Economics
• But coordination always has a cost - whether this is the cost of
coordination within companies (part of the structural costs), or
the transaction cost when relationships are decentralised and
organised by the market.
• The authors hypothesise that economic actors seek to minimise
the sum of production costs and coordination costs, and that
the chosen solution, in every circumstance, is that which they
consider (rightly or wrongly!) the least expensive.
• We see that this analysis is essential to shed light on the
company’s choice between performing the activity in-house or
outsourcing it to a third party via a contract.
8
New Institutional Economics
• When applied to the field of transport, analysis of coordination
and transaction costs serves to understand why a manufacturer
or retailer might choose to perform transport on own account
or, rather, to externalise the transport function.
• And if the company decides to outsource the transport
function, analysis of coordination and transaction costs then
explains the choice between
- selecting carriers (and more generally, all providers involved in
the transport chain) itself and contracting with each of these,
or
- resorting to an intermediary to entrust this responsibility to
the latter.
9
Part II
Transaction Costs
10
Transaction Costs
• Indeed, Coase and Williamson’s essential contribution is to
state that choosing the market as a coordination tool has a
cost, which “classical” theory, which supposes that competition
is pure and perfect, denies.
• “In order to carry out a market transaction it is necessary to
discover who it is that one wishes to deal with, to inform
people that one wishes to deal and on what terms, to conduct
negotiations leading up to a bargain, to draw up the contract,
to undertake the inspection needed to make sure that the
terms of the contract are being observed, and so on.” (RH Coase,
'The Problem of Social Cost’, Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 3 (Oct.,
1960), pp. 1-44)
11
Transaction Costs
• The theory of transaction costs - specifically Ronald Coase gathers these into three subsets:
- Costs prior to the conclusion of the contract (“search and
information costs”): the costs incurred in identifying potential
partners and comparing the services, prices, reliability,
security, etc., which they offer;
- Costs related to establishment of the contract (“bargaining
and decision costs”) incurred in discussions with potential
partners, cost of drawing up the contract ...;
- Costs related to contract execution (“policing and
enforcement costs”) incurred in monitoring service
performance, service quality, accuracy of billing, etc..
12
Transaction Costs
• However, Oliver Williamson and other more recent authors
complement this analysis by building an actual economic
theory of contracts and seeking to identify the factors which
determine the level of transaction costs. In a nutshell, we may
list three factors explaining the level of transaction costs:
- uncertainty and the resulting risk of opportunism;
- the more or less specific nature of assets involved in the
transaction;
- the frequency of transactions.
13
Transaction Costs
• The "real" world is very different from the theoretical world
where perfect competition prevails, in that information is
always costly and uncertainty is always there.
• Economic agents may be rational, but their rationality is limited
as their calculations are based on incomplete information.
• Under these conditions the contracts themselves, even if
carefully prepared, are necessarily incomplete because they
cannot anticipate all contingencies that may occur.
14
Transaction Costs
• Incomplete contracts open up room to maneuvre: the parties to
the contract may take advantage of circumstances not covered
by the contract to benefit ("opportunism") at the expense of
the other party.
• Incomplete contracts and the ensuing risk of opportunistic
behaviour by the other party make it imperative to include
enforcement measures, incentives and sanctions, arbitration
and renegotiation systems in the contract in case of dispute. All
such provisions are expensive to plan and implement.
15
Transaction Costs
• The relative position of the parties to a contract varies greatly
depending on whether the assets involved are "specific" or
commonplace.
• The concept of specificity is a complex one. In a somewhat
simplistic view, an asset is specific if it is specialised, i.e. can only
be used for the production of a particular service and hardly be
redeployed – i.e. assigned to another use -, either due to this
very specialisation, or for lack of a market opportunity. To
illustrate the concept of specificity, let’s say that an articulated
vehicle for "general cargo" is commonplace, while a car carrier
vehicle is specific ...
16
Transaction Costs
• The owner of a specific asset who engages in a transaction (and
especially the contracting party who has to invest into a specific
asset in order to engage in a transaction) can encounter two
opposite situations:
- the specificity of the asset does not allow another assignment,
making the asset holder dependent on the other party;
- it would be difficult for the other party to find another partner
holding this specific asset and able to deliver, so the other
party is dependent on the asset holder, and the owner of the
specific asset is in a strong position.
17
Transaction Costs
• The balance between these two situations is difficult and calls
for particular care in drawing up the contract and monitoring its
enforcement.
• Note that the assets involved, whether specific or not, are not
necessarily physical assets. They may be intangible assets,
including the competence of the people involved in providing
the service.
• According to Williamson, the higher the asset specificity, the
more the chosen solution will tend towards vertical integration
of activities, rather than opting for a decentralised contractual
mode, which is too costly and too risky.
18
Transaction Costs
• The situation of contracting parties is also very different
depending on whether one is dealing with a one-off transaction
or frequent transactions. But here again conflicting
considerations come into play:
- When the transaction is infrequent, the search costs for a
provider are proportionately high, the risk of choosing a "bad"
partner is great, but the consequences of such a choice are
limited.
- When the transaction is frequent, the uncertainty associated
with a service spread out over time is large, and the stakes of
the choice of partner are high; contractual arrangements must
take this into account and call for particular caution.
19
Transaction Costs
• It is generally accepted that the higher the frequency of
transactions, the more the chosen solution will tend toward
integration of activities rather than outsourcing.
• Furthermore, the two factors "asset specificity" and "frequency
of transactions" reinforce one another: if a company needs a
very specific asset for frequent use, it will be in its interest to
buy the asset and provide the service itself, rather than
resorting to an external provider on which it would be overly
dependent.
20
Transaction Costs
• In short, the pro-integration factors are:
- the degree of uncertainty and related risks of opportunism,
- asset specificity,
- transaction frequency.
• This analysis has been applied to businesses and industry more rarely to the service sector, and even more rarely to the
transport sector.
• However, one may give a few examples to illustrate the benefits
of this analysis.
21
Part III
Integration vs. Outsourcing in the
Transport Sector
22
Integration vs. Outsourcing in the Transport Sector
• The first work we may mention that applies New Institutional
Economics to the transport sector is the thesis by Lionel Grand
("Les relations de sous-traitance dans le secteur des transports
routiers de marchandises" - Lyon, 1997).
• The purpose of the thesis is to analyse subcontracting in road
haulage, especially the phenomenon of subcontractor
dependence on their principals (forwarding agents and other
carriers) depending on the specificity (or commonness) of the
(tangible or intangible) assets involved and the frequency of
transactions.
• This thesis leads to a typology of subcontracting relationships.
23
Integration vs. Outsourcing in the Transport Sector
• More recently a paper by Emeric Lendjel and Marianne
Fischman (to be published) analysing how container transport is
organised on the Rhone, shows how complex this organisation
is. Performing this service involves a huge number of
transactions:
- A "mother" transaction whereby a carrier takes responsibility
for the operation
- "Secondary" transactions: hiring a container, hiring space on a
barge, loading the container onto the barge, driving the barge,
unloading the container, etc.. , not to mention pre- and postcarriage operations.
• According to the authors, performing this service involves at
least 8 transactions or sub-transactions.
24
Integration vs. Outsourcing in the Transport Sector
• Now the analysis conducted by the authors shows that governance
structures put in place by both operators involved in this market are
integrated or quasi-integrated (services performed in-house, or
outsourced to external providers, but which are subsidiaries or
companies in which they hold minority interests).
• This article has the merit of emphasising an original feature of
transport services: while the transport chain may occasionally be
simple and involve only a single transaction, it is common for the
chain to be made up of successive segments involving several physical or administrative - services which must be coordinated,
especially when the transport operation is multimodal and / or
international.
25
Integration vs. Outsourcing in the Transport Sector
• Does neo-institutional analysis serve to explain the distribution
of transport between own-account and for hire or reward?
• The answer is not straightforward:
-the tendency to internalise (own-account transport) is
unquestionably stronger when the services to be performed
are frequent and involve specialised assets (physical or knowhow);
-yet own-account transport may occur even when these
conditions are not met. Manufacturers and retailers, in
particular, may perform own-account transport which does not
rely on specific assets.
26
Integration vs. Outsourcing in the Transport Sector
• In very broad terms, studies show that the production cost of
own-account transport is often much higher than that of
transport for hire or reward (especially because the rate of use
of the vehicle is low, driver salaries are higher...).
• The existence of transaction costs when outsourcing can
partially offset this cost difference – however, only in part. And
besides, these costs are generally ignored or underestimated by
manufacturers or retailers.
• Therefore, the assumption by neo-institutional theory that
companies seek to minimise the sum of production and
coordination costs does not appear to be verified.
27
Integration vs. Outsourcing in the Transport Sector
• If the share of own account transport is greater than predicted
by theory, one may invoke four arguments related to the
behaviour of manufacturers and retailers:
- their choices are based on incomplete information,
particularly regarding the cost of own account, which they
tend to underestimate - their rationality is thus limited;
- they want to control service provision directly for the sake of
quality;
- performing own account transport allows them to keep in
touch with clients – the driver is a "sales representative" of the
company;
- they wish to retain a “test” activity allowing them to make
comparisons with transport for hire or reward which they
otherwise use.
28
Integration vs. Outsourcing in the Transport Sector
• Ultimately, the neo-institutionalist approach, because it
neglects these arguments, does not provide a complete analysis
of the conditions of the choice between integration and
outsourcing.
• These arguments - or at least a part of them - are specific to the
transport sector.
• But suppose a manufacturer or retailer decides to outsource
transport services. Does the neo-institutionalist theory serve to
understand the choice between
- internalising the choice of carriers and other service providers,
or
- outsourcing this choice and resorting to an intermediary?
29
Integration vs. Outsourcing in the Transport Sector
• If the company wishes to select the transport providers itself, it
must:
- analyse this service to break it down into its various physical
and administrative segments,
- estimate the uncertainty attached to performance of these
different segments and assess related risks,
- gather information to identify the operators able to perform
these segments and find out what they offer, at what price,
with what quality assurance ...
- draw up with each provider a contract stipulating, among
other things, how their services will interact with those of
other operators upstream and downstream,
- monitor performance of the various services,
- etc..
30
Integration vs. Outsourcing in the Transport Sector
• In other words, the company must hold or acquire knowledge and
skills which, according to New Institutional Economics, constitute a
specific asset. This intangible asset is undoubtedly costly.
• Acquiring such an asset is only possible if transactions are frequent
in order to make the investment profitable.
• And even if the company has this competence, transaction costs in
dealing with a large number of operators can be very high if the
service is a complex one.
• Therefore, in practice, except in the case of relatively simple and
repetitive services, it is in the interest of the manufacturer or
retailer – the “loader” - to outsource the organisation of the
service.
31
Integration vs. Outsourcing in the Transport Sector
• Instead of multiple contracts with operators, the loader
concludes a single contract with an intermediary - a transport
organiser - who has the competence - the knowledge and
know-how - to select operators, assess risks, draw up contracts,
monitor implementation, etc..
• For the loader, transaction costs are limited to the search for
and drawing up of a single contract. In addition, a commission
must be paid. However, the commission amount is less than the
transaction costs the loader would have to bear if it did not
outsource the choice of operators involved in the transport
chain.
32
As a conclusion
• New Institutional Economics are primarily concerned with the
forms of coordination of economic actors, which it
schematically describes by opposing integration within a
company, to market coordination through contractual
arrangements. Relating to the latter, it identifies and highlights
the role of transaction costs.
• The analysis of transaction costs serves to explain, or at least to
shed light on, the choice which companies have between
integration or outsourcing.
33
As a conclusion
• This analysis is particularly relevant when considering the role
of intermediaries: intermediation appears as a means to:
- pass on to the intermediary the transaction costs which would
be involved in selecting several co-contractors,
- restrict transaction costs - for the company outsourcing service
production – to those of establishing a single contract with the
intermediary.
34
Thank you.
35
Download