the full document HERE - Links International Journal of

advertisement

¿Cogestión es Revolución?

Worker participation during the first Chávez administration (1999-2006)

Federico Fuentes

A thesis submitted in partial fulfilment of the requirements of an Arts Degree

School of Social Sciences and International Studies, Faculty of Arts and Social Sciences,

University of New South Wales, November 2011

Word count: 19,873

1

Statement of Originality

I hereby declare that this submission is my own work and to the

Best of my knowledge it contains no materials previously published or written by another person, nor material which to a substantial extent has been accepted for the award of any other degree or diploma at UNSW or any other educational institution, except where due acknowledgement is made in the thesis. Any contribution made to the research by others, with whom I have worked at

UNSW or elsewhere, is explicitly acknowledged in the thesis.

I also declare that the intellectual content of this thesis is the product of my own work, except that assistance from others in the project’s design and conception or in style, presentation and linguistic expression is acknowledge.

Signed:..................................................................................................

Approved as suitable for submission by

...............................................................................................................

(Supervisor)

2

Abstract

Attempts to analyse Venezuela’s experiments in cogestión

(generally translated as ‘comanagement’) during the first Hugo Chávez administration (1999-2006) have tended to centre on form rather than content. Almost all have concluded that the government ultimately abandoned cogestión, and with its support for worker participation. However, rather than focusing on pre-established models or comparisons with historical experiences, the development of cogestión can be better understood as the product of a complex interaction between competing visions within the government and workers' movement in the broader context of attempting to create a uniquely Venezuelan model of socialism. At the heart of these debates were the issues of ownership, production and distribution. The end result of all this was that by early 2007, cogestión came to resemble something quite different to its initial conception, that is: a mechanism for co-governance in the economic sphere and a necessary means by which to ensure integral human development. While the term cogestión would disappear from government discourse in the second Chávez administration, much of the initial spirit of cogestión, and the lessons learned in implementing this government policy, would come to be encapsulated in Chávez’s theory of the “socialist triangle”, based on social ownership, social production and social needs.

3

Contents

Introduction

Cogestión: co-management or co-governance?

Cogestión and the first Chávez administration

Cogestión and social ownership

Cogestión and social production

Cogestión and social needs

Cogestión and the ‘socialist triangle’

Conclusion

Appendix

Bibliography

List of acronyms, key names and Spanish terms

Timeline of key events related to cogestión during first Chávez administration

5

29

36

46

15

22

52

58

63

63

66

70

4

Introduction

During President Hugo Chávez’s first term in government (1999-2006) 1

Venezuelan workers came to see cogestión

(generally translated as ‘co-management’) as synonymous with his call to build “twenty-first century socialism.” The close affinity between these two concepts was graphically symbolised on the 2005 May Day march. There, on a stage adorned with a banner that read “ Cogestión es revolución ” (Cogestión is revolution), union leaders presented Chávez with their proposed law on worker participation. Addressing the march, Chávez proclaimed his support for cogestión, describing it as a means to create “new work relations” through

“workers participation … in the management and running of companies” (Despacho del

Presidente 2005b:324).

Several factors explain the close relationship between cogestión and twenty-first century socialism. Although the term was included in the 1999 constitution and the first cogestión experiment was initiated in March 2001, it was not until early 2005 – when Chávez first began talking about socialism – that his government moved to introduce cogestión across a variety of workplaces. Throughout 2005, the government’s increasing use of socialist discourse was matched by moves to implement cogestión in state-owned companies, privately run enterprises and fabricas recuperadas (recuperated factories).

2

Workers’ discussions on cogestión also became increasingly intertwined with the broader debate over socialism, with many viewing the two as intrinsically linked. As Michael

Lebowitz noted: “Given the constitution’s support for co-management and self-management and protagonism in general, as well as Chávez’s stress upon the need for new productive relations, it was natural that organized workers would take up the same themes” (Lebowitz

2006:203).

Yet, less than a year after the 2005 May Day march, the implementation of cogestión had stalled. In early 2006, Chávez explicitly came out against cogestión in “strategic sectors” such as the state oil company,

Petróleos de Venezuela Sociedad

Anonima (PDVSA, Venezuela

1 While technically Chávez served two terms during this time, his first (1999-2000) essentially involved the convening of a constituent assembly to rewrite the constitution. Once approved, Chávez was re-elected at the end of 2000, serving as president until 2006. For this reason, we have referred to all this period as his first administration.

2 Recuperated factories is the name given to companies that were shut down by their owners and subsequently taken over, or recuperated, by workers.

5

Petroleum Company), and by the start of his second term (2007-2012), the government seemed to have moved away from promoting workplace democracy (Aló Presidente 2006:82).

How did it come to be that a policy viewed as integral to the project of twenty-first century socialism was so quickly abandoned? If cogestión was revolution, did this mean that the revolution had lost its way?

A new socialism for the twenty-first century

In order to answer these questions, it is necessary to return to the original spirit of Venezuelan cogestión rather than simply focus on the end result. Attempts to mechanically impose previous historical models onto the Venezuelan reality must be avoided.

While generally translated to mean co-management, cogestión had little to do with this concept. In fact, cogestión was presented by state officials and union leaders as a radical alternative to the failed experiments of co-management, which involved workers owning shares and having representatives on company boards (Lanz Rodríguez 2005a:8; Gómez,

Tábata & Gámez 2005:45). Unlike co-management, which was viewed as a means to co-opt workers into accepting pro-capitalist measures, cogestión was seen as a means for transforming capitalist relations of production. Some prefer to use the term cogestión revolucionaria (revolutionary co-management) in order to draw a sharp distinction between the two (Lanz Rodríguez 2005a:9).

Moreover, while cogestión was seen as part of the broader socialist project, Venezuelans were insistent that theirs was a “new socialism for the twenty-first century.” “We have to reinvent socialism” proclaimed Chávez when first announcing his socialist beliefs, “but we cannot resort to state capitalism, which would be the same perversion of the Soviet Union” (cited in

Lebowitz 2006:109). Instead, socialism needed to be reclaimed “as a thesis, a project and a path, but a new type of socialism.”

None of this meant that Venezuela was exempt from the same dilemmas encountered in previous attempts to build socialist societies. In fact, the same issues regarding ownership, production and distribution that plagued these experiments have constantly reappeared in

6

twenty-first century Venezuela. It is also clear that many in the government had studies these lessons and drawn their own – in some cases conflicting – conclusions.

When it came to the Soviet model of state ownership, those within the Ministerio para la

Energia y Petróleo (MENPET, Ministry for Energy and Petroleum) argued that its downfall should not be attributed to state-owned property (Valderrama & Mena 2005:39). In opposition to this view, Víctor Álvarez, who was Minister for Basic Industry during the period of cogestión, contended that “within the false belief that socialism is based on state property and wage labour lay the seed of the debacle of ‘real’ or ‘state socialism’” (Álvarez 2009:193).

State ownership, argued Álvarez, was predestined to lead to the creation of “state monopoly capitalism.” As an alternative, he proposed developing “new forms of social property based fundamentally on direct worker and community control” (Álvarez 2009:183-4). Haiman El

Troudi, who was Chief of Staff to President Chávez in 2005, also argued that state ownership inevitably led to state capitalism. Twenty-first century socialism therefore required the construction of a system based upon “new productive relations involving the participation of organised communities and small, medium and large entrepreneurs, both public and private”

(El Troudi 2006:6-7). Those within MENPET responded that eschewing state property altogether amounted to a belief that socialism could be “built with bourgeois property forms”

(Valderrama & Mena 2005:40). Socialism required that social property be administered by state to which society had delegated the responsibility of “social planning and administration”

(Aponte 2007a:129).

For some, the Yugoslav model of self-management offered useful lessons. Confronted with the failures of Soviet state capitalism, the Yugoslav regime posed as an alternative, worker self-management and the transformation of state property into “a superior form of property, socialist property in the hands of the workers” (Álvarez 2009:187). This would allow for a change in property relations and relations of production, eliminating the traditional division of labour inherent within private and state-owned companies. Álvarez also acknowledged that certain problems had arisen, as workers began to focus on maximising profits for themselves rather than the needs of the communities. “In the struggle against state bureaucracy, the workers had forgotten about the struggle against capitalism” (Álvarez 2009:188). Instead of social property, what emerged was privately owned “group property.” For those in MENPET, this was the inevitable result of “transferring what belongs to all of society to a part of it, thereby stimulating collective egoism” (Aponte 2007:29). Only state-administered social

7

property, within which “human labour enriches all of society and not a portion,” could ensure a transformation in relations of production (Aponte 2007a:123, Aponte 2007:37).

Perhaps the biggest dilemma posed in the construction of twentieth century socialism was the question of distribution. While the Soviet Union relied on a centralised planned economy directed by the state, in Yugoslavia, ‘market socialism’ was proposed as an alternative to a bureaucratically run command economy. Reflecting on these experiences, Elías Jaua, head of the Ministerio de Economía Popular (MINEP, Ministry for the Popular Economy) between

2004-2006, contended that Venezuelan socialism would instead be based on “a new mixed economy, where the market does not govern all areas of society, but rather serves as a complement to strategic and democratic planning” (Jaua Milano 2005:26). El Troudi disagreed, arguing that the problem with the dilemma of state planning versus market was that it left out a key factor: the organised community. In the relationship between the state, market and the community, it was essential to “always depend on the organisational force of the community” (El Troudi 2006:5). Reflecting on the same issue, thinkers in MENPET proposed the integration of companies into “socialist zones” to facilitate a process of planned production and consumption (Aponte 2007a:141). Social property had to be combined with central planning that extended beyond strategic sectors and to the entire economy. Otherwise, the continued presence of the market and capitalist property forms would make impossible the formation of socialist consciousness, opening the path towards capitalist restoration (Aponte

2007a:145).

In all this, the one experiment in twentieth-century socialism significantly not discussed was

Cuba. Undoubtedly, the close relationship between Venezuela and Cuba, and the widespread admiration in Venezuela for this small island and its continued struggle for existence against

US hostility, made difficult any public or critical examination of the Cuban model.

Nevertheless, while stating his unwavering support for Cuban socialism, Chávez reiterated on several occasions “the Bolivarian project is very different to the Cuban model” (Mastronardi

2011).

On this point indeed, all Venezuelan thinkers about socialism have concurred. Venezuelans were attempting to construct their own, original model of socialism. Moreover, everyone was aware that Venezuela’s attempt to create twenty-first century socialism could rely on the wealth that came with being an oil-rich nation, even if, as we shall see, that wealth in itself

8

created many other complications for the experiment. For the purposes of this dissertation therefore, I have chosen to focus on the Venezuelan experience of cogestión and its attempt to deal afresh with the issues of ownership, production and distribution in the construction of socialism. Specifically, my focus is on how Venezuelans have understood the theory and practice of cogestión, and how those understandings have changed in a continually shifting economic and political situation.

In tracing the development of cogestión, it becomes evident that government policy was shaped by competing visions that existed within the government over issues of ownership, production and distribution. The views and activities of Venezuelan workers themselves also had a significant impact on cogestión, because, in part at least, it became a means by which they began to challenge the historically entrenched union bureaucracy and develop goals and objectives beyond a narrow pursuit of improved wages and conditions.

And finally President Chávez himself was both a significant actor in this complex development, and was also profoundly influenced by it. As we will see, it led him to not only question his support for cogestión but to reconsider some of his ideas on socialism. By early

2007, Chávez had come to the conclusion that cogestión was only feasible if applied within the context of what he described as the ‘socialist triangle’ of social ownership, social production and the satisfaction of social needs.

Venezuela’s ‘magical state’

The debate and struggle over cogestión and socialism in Venezuela, must, like much else in its recent history, be situated against the backdrop of the role of oil. The rise of oil production in the 1920s fuelled a dramatic transformation in Venezuela’s economy. Over the next decades, agricultural production slumped as capital poured into the oil sector. Reliance on imports from abroad to satisfy the needs of the domestic market became an alternative to any real attempt to diversify Venezuela’s economy.

The discovery of oil not only impacted Venezuela’s economy, but also profoundly shaped the

Venezuelan state and society as a whole. Fernando Coronil contends that oil wealth is the key to understanding Venezuela’s “magical state” which, standing over and above Venezuelan

9

society, “appeared as a single agent endowed with the magical power to remake the nation”

(Coronil 1997:4).

As oil’s contribution to state revenues jumped from a mere 1.44% in 1920, to 97.7% in 1940, business elites became increasingly dependent on their connections within the state in order to accumulate wealth (Godio 1986:2). This process facilitated both a fusion of power and wealth within the state as well as the creation of a parasitic capitalist class, which sought to enrich itself not by extracting surplus value but rather by appropriating it from the state (Coronil

1997:8; Lebowitz 2006:87). It also underpinned the emergence of a pervasive culture of clientalism and corruption as Venezuelan society came to be dominated by a “social system and political culture deeply implicated in legitimating and consolidating the vast set of formal and informal mechanisms through which oil is produced and oil money is appropriated”

(Coronil 2008a:20). “Enchanted by its spectacular performances”, Venezuelans came to view the state as a vehicle for lifting themselves out of poverty.

With the onset of the international oil crisis of the 1970s, this “magical state” entered into crisis (Bilbao 2008:103). The nationalisation of oil in 1976 was unable to turn the situation around given the state-owned oil company’s propensity to function as a “state within a state” that acted in the interests of transnational oil corporations (Mommer 2003:28). While in 1981,

PDVSA was handing over 71% of its income to the government, by 2000, this figure had plummeted to 39%. This in turn led to a steep decline in fiscal income, from US$1,500 per person in 1975 to US$350 in 1999 (measured in 1998 dollars) (Bilbao 2008:103).

Venezuela’s sole attempt at industrialisation, the Corporación Venezolana de Guayana

(CVG, Venezuelan Corporation of Guayana) similarly entered into crisis. Located in the southeastern state of Bolivar, this basic industry complex comprised of 16 state-owned aluminum, steel, bauxite and mining companies was created as a result of the import substitution policy promoted in the 1950s (Vitale 1984:6). Importantly, the CVG became home to highly unionised “vanguard” elements of the Venezuelan labour movement (Ellner

1993:161-2). Like the oil industry, CVG also came to be dominated by clientalism and corruption, and remained subordinate to the interests of foreign multinationals. Moreover, during the 1990s neoliberal governments disinvested state funds in the complex to pave the way for its privatisation, beginning with the sell-off of SIDOR in 1998.

10

Meanwhile, the deepening economic crisis only accelerated the process of rural-urban migration, as people flocked to the cities in pursuit of their share of the oil wealth. This, combined with rising unemployment, led to the creation of a massive belt of barrios (poor neighbourhoods) all along the hillsides of the capital, Caracas and other major cities. There, informal sector workers crammed into makeshift housing attempting to eke out a living in whatever way they could. Poverty levels rose steeply, as the average wage in real terms decreased from US$5,200 in 1978 to US$2,000 in 1999 (Bilbao 2008:103). The share of workers employed in the informal sector rose from 37.9% to 46% between 1984 and 2000. By the end of the 1990s (when unemployment was running at 13.4%), informal workers for the first time outnumbered their counterparts in the formal sector.

Simmering discontent exploded onto the streets in February 1989, when then President Carlos

Andres Perez (1989-1993) implemented an International Monetary Fund (IMF) package that sent fuel prices skyrocketing overnight (Ciccariello-Maher 2007). For four days, a massive uprising rocked Caracas, and extended out to several other cities and towns. Although a wave of repression succeeded in quelling the uprising, Venezuelans continued to take to the streets during the next decade. As disillusionment with the status quo grew, Venezuelan society became engulfed by “a stream of demands and complaints levelled at local and national authorities,” with over 7,000 protests taking place in the 1990s – a majority acquiring a

“confrontational” or “violent” form (Bruce 2008:25-9; López Maya 2002:13, 19).

This spontaneous and incoherent ferment from below had very little impact on government policy. However, it was a critical factor in speeding up the plans of a group of dissenting officials within the Armed Forces plotting a patriotic military coup. Although the February

1992 military rebellion failed, the coup succeeded in propelling its leader – Hugo Chávez – into the collective imagination of Venezuela’s poor majority, “in constant search of a messiah with a magical formula to relieve them of their misery” (McCaughan 2004:158).

Chávez’s growing popularity led to him being pardoned in 1994, after which he travelled the country to listen to the demands of the people. Having decided to stand in the 1998 presidential elections as a political outsider and without the backing of any of the traditional parties, Chávez won in a historic landslide. As promised, his first step in power was to convene a popularly elected constituent assembly entrusted with the task of redesigning

Venezuela’s institutional framework and incorporating the previously marginalised majority

11

into the management of public affairs. Throughout 1999, Venezuelans intensely debated and then approved a new constitution that stated that “the participation of the people” in all spheres was the key to “ensuring complete development, both individual and collective”

(Asamblea Nacional Constituyente 2003:23).

Quickly realising the threat that the process opened up by Chávez’s election represented to their interests, the traditional elites sought to overthrow his government; first via a failed military coup in April 2002, then a two-month management lock-out at PDVSA that began in

December 2002, and finally a recall referendum in August 2004 (Wilpert 2003; Medina,

López Maya & Lander 2007:147-204; Bilbao 2007:235-242). Each attempt was defeated by the combined mobilisation of the people and the Armed Forces, which, following the failed

April 2002 coup (and subsequent purge of disloyal officers), was now in the hands of prorevolution forces (Harnecker 2003:11-18).

Empowered by these victories, the government set about trying to tackle Venezuela’s huge social problems, while also seeking to convert the new, but still vague, ideas enshrined in the constitution into reality. In the economic sphere, this required moving forward on two fronts: dealing with immediate problems (such as unemployment and the reactivation of an economy that had contracted by 26.7% in the first quarter of 2003 as a result of the lock-out at

PDVSA), while promoting initiatives toward a longer term structural transformation of the economy (El Troudi 2010:45; Álvarez 2009:32). The promotion of cogestión was seen as an essential element to simultaneously tackle both issues. However, attempts to implement cogestión revealed a variety of views on this issue among government officials, union leaders and workers more generally. The thesis which follows aims to describe and explain the emergence of these differing views, and the ways in which the conflicts and interactions they produced ended up changing the whole meaning of the cogestión idea, and the broader policy and political context in which it was seen.

Thesis structure

Chapter 1 sets out to provide a brief survey of some of these competing Venezuelan views on cogestión, as well as some of those put forward in ‘outsider’ academic studies that have attempted to come to grips with Venezuelan debates. In most cases the views surveyed have

12

little in common with the idea as it first appeared in the constitution and the first national development plan.

Outlining the chaotic development of cogestión and the diversity of experiments in this area carried out during the first Chávez administration is the focus of Chapter 2. The aim here is not to describe and analyse each individual workplace where cogestión was introduced, but to pinpoint key initiatives and turning points in the complex and uneven process of implementation.

The subsequent three chapters focus on the more specific aspects of ownership, production and distribution. Chapter 3 is concerned with cogestión experiences in recuperated factories and the private sector, where the issue of collective versus social ownership appeared most starkly. In Chapter 4, the focus shifts to the state sector, in particular the aluminium plant,

CVG Aluminio del Caroní S.A.

(ALCASA, CVG Caroní Aluminum), where arguably the most ambitious experiment in social production took place. Chapter 5 endeavours to grapple with the innovative idea of the

Empresas de Producción Social

(EPSs, Social Production

Enterprises), Chávez’s attempt to ensure that production was geared towards satisfying social needs.

Finally, in Chapter 5, I bring these threads together and analyse the basic foundations of

Chávez’s so-called socialist triangle. Premised on the idea that socialism requires simultaneously moving forward on all three fronts – social ownership, social production and social needs – it will by then have become apparent that this “socialist triangle” was heavily shaped by his shifting views on cogestión. In many ways, the emergence of the “socialist triangle” simultaneously involved returning to the original concept of cogestión, while placing it in a much more radical setting. I will refer in this chapter to the writing of two key intellectuals who played a part in influencing Chávez’s thinking as he was developing his ideas on socialism: István Mészáros and Michael Lebowitz.

One final note: throughout this study, an emphasis is placed on Chávez’s ideas and words.

The absence of specific government documents or laws on cogestión means that a certain focus on unofficial government statements is necessary. However, a more important reason for focusing on Chávez’s words is given by Coronil, who argues that through his words “that are also acts and guide actions” Venezuela’s head of (the magical) state “has brought the

13

pueblo [people] to center stage” (Coronil 2008:4). Many of Chávez’s public pronouncements are pedagogical in intent. They are intended to act as a guide to public discussion of policy and its problems in a country where many of his supporters are poor people with limited formal education who have long been excluded from public debate and discussion, let alone from positions of power or responsibility. To that end, his statements are usually undogmatic and open in tone, and designed both to express the President’s own uncertainties and to elicit popular responses, suggestions and actions. In other words, Chávez’s reflections on cogestión and socialism in Venezuela are no mere academic commentary on a political process, rather they are a vital part of that process, and often influence it deeply.

14

Cogestión: co-management or co-governance?

Among the numerous policy initiatives undertaken during the first Chávez administration towards organised labour, none was more contentious than cogestión. Given its association with twenty-first century socialism, this experiment in worker participation became a key concern for unionists, government officials, and observers of the revolutionary process.

Unsurprisingly, attempts have been made to compare the policy of cogestión with previous experiments in co-management. Others have endeavoured to squeeze the concept of cogestión into pre-existing models. Almost all commentators agree that cogestión was dumped during

Chávez’s second administration.

There is little doubt that many of the same challenges and issues that emerged in previous experiments with worker participation were revisited during the Venezuelan debate over cogestión. The almost complete disappearance of cogestión from Chávez’s discourse, and his attempt to remove the term from the constitution in 2007, add weight to the argument that support for worker participation was subsequently dropped.

Nevertheless, such views contain two important shortcomings. Firstly, in the minds of workers, the term cogestión had little to do with a desire to replicate any specific model

(Cerceau 2007a:15; Gómez, Tábata & Gámez 2005:47, 49). The same was true for the government, and Chávez in particular, who continuously emphasised the uniqueness of

Venezuela’s socialist experiment. Referring to a pamphlet written by Michael Lebowitz on the lessons of self-management in Yugoslavia,

3

Chávez explained that while it provided a useful reference point, Venezuela was “not going to copy any model, we are creating our own model” (Aló Presidente 2005:19).

Second, it is insufficient to focus on the final forms, or “models” of cogestión that ultimately emerged. Such views tend to imply the presence of a uniform and defined blueprint when in fact government policy was shaped by the constant struggles of competing forces that held widely differing opinions on cogestión.

3 See Lebowitz 2004

15

For this reason, I propose to trace the non-lineal development of cogestión, focusing on how the battle between competing visions regarding ownership, production and distribution were ultimately resolved. This will allow for a better understanding of the actual course that cogestión took, as well as provide an insight into some of the thinking behind Chávez’s subsequent adoption of his socialist triangle.

Competing concepts of cogestión

Osvaldo Alonso argues that the focus of cogestión was on workers and owners jointly administrating companies (Alonso 2007:9-10). Drawing parallels with the West German experience of the 1950s, he argued cogestión differed from self-management in that “workers administer as workers and not as owners.” Hector Lucena also refers to German comanagement when offering a definition of cogestión as the participation of workers in the

“decision making and running of a company” (Lucena 2006:26, 29). Maria Vera Colina maintains that Venezuelan cogestión was not focused on “co-ownership” but rather the

“voluntary application” of “co-administration” between workers and company owners (Vera

Colina 2006:173-4).

Yet, as Rodolfo Cibank, the vice president of the

Federación de Industriales, Pequeños,

Medianos y Artesanos de Venezuela (FEDEINDUSTRIA, Venezuelan Federation of Small,

Medium and Artisan Industries) noted, Venezuelan cogestión took on a “novel characteristic,” with co-ownership “superimposed” onto a concept generally limited to worker participation in management (Cibank 2005). The focus on ownership was also present in the discourse of different government ministries. Asked to define cogestión, a vice-minister in the Ministerio de Industria Ligera y Comercio (MILCO, Ministry of Light Industry and Commerce) stated:

“When we talk about cogestión … [we are referring to] the co-responsible participation of workers in running the entire company, which is made concrete via the acquisition of shares; shares that do not belong to individual workers, but rather a cooperative” (Fernández 2006).

A different view of cogestión was put forward by MINEP, another of the ministries assigned responsibilities to oversee some of the companies under cogestión. Its course readings for students preparing to take up jobs within these companies, stated that in places such as

Germany, cogestión had been implemented as a “reformist” measure, limiting worker participation to owning shares and naming representatives to company boards (MINEP

16

2005:17). Only by linking cogestión to the demand for workers’ control could cogestión take on a revolutionary character. Moreover, cogestión revolucionaria

was only a stepping-stone towards achieving the ultimate goal of autogestión

(self-management), where workers owned

“the means of production, without state mediation” (MINEP 2005:18).

Such views were strongly opposed by others in the government. As head of MENPET, Rafael

Ramirez, together with his party colleagues from Esperanza Patriótica (Patriotic Hope) who worked within the ministry, waged an intense public campaign against cogestión. Agreeing with MINEP’s characterisation of cogestión as a reformist measure focused on workers owning shares, those around MENPET drew the opposite conclusion: rather than culminating in self-management, cogestión would inevitably provoke a regression towards capitalist relations of production and the privatisation of strategic industries (Valderrama & Mena

2005:46-52).

While debates raged within the state over the issue of property, union leaders preferred to view cogestión as a banner with which to advance their struggles for worker participation.

The

Federación de Trabajadores de la Industria Eléctrica de Venezuela

(FETRAELEC,

Federation of Venezuelan Electrical Workers) saw cogestión as superior to previous models of co-management, because it represented “the governing of [publicly-owned] company in a co-responsible manner” between the state, workers and communities (FETRAELEC 2005c:4;

Harnecker 2005:7). FETRAELEC leader Joaquin Osorio argued that Venezuelan cogestión had nothing to with the social democratic models of “Germany, Sweden, Spain, Yugoslavia or any other” country (Osorio 2005:7-8). Moreover, cogestión should have nothing to do with workers owning shares, as this would transform workers into “owner-bosses and reproduce capitalist egoism.”

The

Frente Revolucionario de Trabajadores de Empresas Cogestiónadas y Ocupadas

(FRETECO, Co-mananged and Occupied Factories’ Worker Revolutionary Front) saw cogestión as synonymous with workers’ control, and argued for the creation of workers councils along the lines of those that existed in “revolutionary Russia” (FRETECO 2007:12-

17). Pablo Cormenzana agreed, stating that behind the confused notion of cogestión lay a battle between workers and Chávez fighting for workers control, and “union bureaucrats and

Bolivarian reformists” who believed workers were incapable of running companies

(Cormenzana 2009:14, 75). In the end, according to William Sanabria and Yonie Moreno, this

17

“reformist bureaucracy” won out, imposing its model of cogestión based on co-ownership between workers and bosses (Sanabria & Moreno 2009:23).

Iain Bruce’s survey of cogestión at ALCASA however, led him to conclude that there, “comanagement, albeit supported from below, had been essentially designed and nurtured from above as a deliberate test bed for moves towards a socialism of the twenty–first century”

(Bruce 2008:137-8). Here, the Ministerio de Industrias Básicas y Minería (MIBAM, Ministry of Basic Industry and Mining) headed by Víctor Álvarez, and the state-appointed company president, Carlos Lanz, played a fundamental role in the introduction and implementation of cogestión.

It is evident that various actors and observers of the process held differing views of cogestión.

While some focused on cogestión as a means for worker participation within companies, others emphasised the question of co-ownership. Whereas some saw it as a transitional measure towards self-management, others denounced it as “counter-revolutionary.” In some cases, cogestión was seen as a battleground between “reformist bureaucrats” and

“revolutionary workers”; in others the positive role of state officials in promoting cogestión was highlighted. Some drew parallels with experiences of co-management in Germany and

Russian soviets, but almost all agree that the Chávez government ultimately dropped its support for cogestión (e.g. Bruce 2008:103; Navas & Osorio 2007:8).

The original concept of cogestión

What few take into consideration is the original concept of cogestión, in the constitution and the government’s first national development plan, the Plan de Desarrollo Económico y Social de la Nación 2001-2007 (Economic and Social Plan for the Nation 2001-2007) with its emphasis on participation and “co-governance” between the state, workers and communities

(MPD 2001:13). In the constitution, cogestión appears in the section dedicated to political rights, framed by Article 62, which states:

All citizens have the right to freely participate in public affairs, either directly or through their elected representatives.

Peoples’ participation in forming, carrying out and controlling the management of public affairs is the necessary means by which to achieve the involvement that ensures their complete development, both individual and collective. It is the state’s obligation

18

and the duty of society to facilitate the generation of optimum conditions for putting this into practice (Asamblea Nacional Constituyente 2003:23).

As to what forms such participation could take, Article 70 listed cogestión as a vehicle for the

“participation and involvement of people … in social and economic affairs” (Asamblea

Nacional Constituyente 2003:25).

Cogestión is also mentioned in Article 184, Point 4, which enshrines “the participation of workers and communities in the running ( gestión ) of publicly-owned companies, through selfmanagement and cogestiónarios

methods” (Asamblea Nacional Constituyente 2003:62).

While the scope of this article was limited to companies in the hands of regional and municipal governments, the constitution extended participation in such companies to include communities as well.

Also of note is that Article 184 draws a distinction between cogestión in public companies

(Point 4) and forms of participation within “the social economy” (Point 3) (Asamblea

Nacional Constituyente 2003:62). Whereas the emphasis of cogestión in public companies is on participation, the focus of the social economy is on promoting collective property such as cooperatives “and other associative forms.” This separation is important, as it implies a distinction between cogestión, as a form of participation, and collectively owned enterprises within the social economy.

This differentiation is reinforced by the absence of the term cogestión in the section dedicated to the “socioeconomic system.” Coinciding with Article 62’s focus on participation, Article

299 states that the goal of the “economic regime” is “ensuring integral human development”

(Asamblea Nacional Constituyente 2003:99-100). The constitution identifies three distinct sectors within the overall economic regime: a state sector entrusted with control over industries deemed to be “in the public interest and of a strategic nature” (Article 302); a private sector (Article 299), and a social sector comprised of small businesses, cooperatives,

“and any other form of community association for purposes of work, savings, and consumption, under an arrangement of collective ownership” (Article 308) (Asamblea

Nacional Constituyente 2003:99-102).

This vision of an economic regime comprised of three different sectors, each involving different property forms (state, private and collective) is also present in the government’s

19

national development plan. Nowhere does the plan draw any direct correlation between cogestión and collective ownership, nor is the application of cogestión limited to any particular sectors.

What stands out in the national development plan is its emphasis on participation in the political, economic and social sphere, as the only means by which to change society.

Discussing the new development model proposed by the government, the plan states:

…the motivation to achieve and the productive disposition of all social agents for change will be achieved by a society which demands co-responsible and democratic participation of all sectors, in all spheres and in each moment of the future. This shared and simultaneous action of all society will manifest itself in the deconcentration and decentralisation of decision making in order to expand the dynamic of change across the whole nation (MPD 2001:16, emphasis in original).

This idea of co-responsibility reappears in the section dealing with “participatory and protagonist-based ( protagónica ) democracy” (MPD 2001:106). According to the plan, such a democracy is only possible through the establishment of “a new relationship between the state and society where what is public is assumed by the people and by the state in a co-responsible manner. This forces a change in the way of governing, governing with the citizens”.

While no explicit definition of cogestión is offered anywhere, in pulling together the different threads running through these key documents, it is possible to identify two important elements. The first has to do with the significance given to the ‘co’ in cogestión, with its emphasis on workers, communities and the state forming a co-responsible relationship as part of changing the way in which society is governed. The other relates to the second half of the word, ‘gestión’, which despite its literal translation as management, emphasises participation as the necessary means to ensuring integral human development. In this sense, cogestión takes on a vastly different meaning to that traditionally ascribed to co-management. Participation is neither viewed as synonymous with ownership nor with workers having representatives on company boards. Instead, the focus of cogestión is on co-governance and co-participation “of all sectors, in all spheres”, as the necessary means for promoting “complete development, both individual and collective.”

This focus was also at the heart of Chávez’s socialist triangle. However, this shift to the

“socialist triangle” is really only comprehensible in light of the many-sided divisions and

20

conflicts that had arisen as the result of the attempt to turn cogestión from a noble, if vague, idea in the constitution, into a practical policy. It is to this attempt that I now turn.

21

Cogestión and the first Chávez administration

The choice of the word cogestión was largely related to its inclusion in the new constitution

(Cerceau 2007:4). The vision of cogestión presented in the constitution was one that focused on co-participation and co-governance in the economic sphere as necessary means for ensuring human development. This vision was also evident in the early experiments in cogestión.

In March 2001, the Chávez government converted a re-opened sugar processing plant

Central

Azucarero Pío Tamayo

(Pío Tamayo Sugar Mill) into its first cogestión experiment. Referring to this venture ten months later on

Aló Presidente , Chávez congratulated all those involved in

“this example of cogestión” where workers and the state were “co-governing the plant together” (Aló Presidente 2002:33).

Chávez added that “cogestión or co-government” was necessary component in the process of “beginning to de-concentrate” power and decisionmaking. Reaffirming the centrality of participation within the idea of cogestión, in November

2002 Chávez referred to the sugar mill as the “model of cogestión” that the government wanted to promote, where “workers are part of company board of directors, with new and much higher levels of participation” (Venpres 2002).

Present within this “model” was the idea of workers owning shares. Ownership rights were also extended to local sugar cane cutters. Organised into two separate cooperatives, each owning 25.5% of the company’s shares, they controlled a majority stake in the operation

(Lucena 2006:15). However, this aspect of Chávez’s cogestión “model” was never emphasised in his various interventions. Rather, Chávez proclaimed the company to be the

“property and pride” not of the workers, but “of the tocuyanos

”, in reference to the name of the local town, Tocuyo (Aló Presidente 2002:92).

This focus on co-participation between the state, workers and community could also be seen in the initiatives promoted by electrical workers. In April 2001, FETRAELEC succeeded in incorporating the term cogestión into the

Declaración de Principios (Declaration of

Principles) that it jointly signed with management at the

Compañía Anónima de

Administración y Fomento Eléctrico

(CADAFE, Electricity Generation and Administration

Company) (Harnecker 2005:6). While concrete steps towards cogestión would not be taken

22

until 2003, workers in this sector had enshrined – at least on paper – “the revolutionary principle of the right of workers to direct the company, at all levels, together with the state”

(FETRAELEC 2005:4).

When pro-revolution unions held a national gathering in September 2002 to discuss breaking with the rightwing-controlled Confederación de Trabajadores de Venezuela (CTV,

Confederation of Venezuelan Workers) and “refounding” a new labour movement, they too raised cogestión as a key demand (Encuentro Nacional de Trabajadores 2002). In response,

Chávez said the proposal to promote “cogestión, shared responsibility” was “marvellous”

(Despacho del Presidente 2005:442-445). While raising the idea of workers owning companies, he stressed his belief that “workers will know how to assume their responsibilities in order to successfully run these companies with shared responsibility, together with business owners and with the government” (Despacho del Presidente 2005:445).

One month later, hundreds of pro-revolution union leaders presented a list of demands to

Chávez. Among them was a call to “establish and legitimise mechanisms of worker participation” and to speed up “the establishment of cogestión in state companies and private ones whose survival depends on [state aid]” (Varios 2002). One leader of the national teachers union expounded the need to “continue concretising that project of the country contained in the constitutional text” through the establishment of worker participation “in running companies, in running the Venezuelan economy” (Varios 2002).

Birth of a new labour movement

In all these cases, the desire to move forward with cogestión as a means for promoting “cogovernance” was evident. However, it was the bosses’ lockout at the end of 2002 that really opened up the possibility of turning this desire into reality. When PDVSA management walked out of their jobs, workers stepped in. Organised into comités guia (guide committees), workers took over direct control of oil production. Recalling these events, union leader

Marcela Maspero said:

Venezuelan workers carried out our first act of workers’ control when the oligarchic bureaucrats of this country dared to sabotage the oil industry in order to put an end to a legitimate government elected by the Venezuelan people. It was the oil workers that recuperated the Venezuelan industry (MINCI 2006:13).

23

Elsewhere, workers confronted business owners, who closed their companies, by occupying them. During the 10-week general strike, pro-Chávez unionists called on the government to issue a decree that would allow workers to take over these companies (Ellner 2006:118).

With control of the state oil company firmly in government hands, the aim was to transform la nueva PDVSA (the new PDVSA) into the driving force of a program to develop and diversify

Venezuela’s economy. Moreover, the increased mobilisation of the labour movement had led

Chávez to state that it was time to “change this rancid capitalism for cogestión obrera

(workers’ cogestión)… ”, as he put it on his March 2

Aló Presidente

program (cited in Barrios

2005). “I want and demand that cogestión obrera be implemented, that workers be incorporated onto company boards.”

The first steps in this direction occurred four days later, when Chávez appointed two union leaders onto PDVSA’s board of directors. He argued that these workers had to “represent the interests of workers and conciliate them with the interests of the company and the interests of the country” as PDVSA, “now and forever must be property of the republic and must exist solely to promote the interest of the republic and not the personal interests of anyone, of any political party or specific social group” (Despacho del Presidente 2005:220, 225). Chávez also argued that appointing workers to the company board was insufficient; it was necessary to

“progressively incorporate, as part of our strategic plan, concepts such as cogestión obrera in the management of sectors within the oil industry… cogestión obrera for decision-making, for controlling operations” (Despacho del Presidente 2005a:225).

One month later, similar steps were taken in CADAFE, breathing life into what was, until then, cogestión on paper only. As with PDVSA, the appointment of two union leaders onto the company board was accompanied by the promotion of worker discussions and organisation from below. The focus was on establishing collegial structures right throughout the company hierarchy that could integrate worker, community and management representatives into a process of co-governance (Harnecker 2005:19).

Emboldened by their victorious struggle, Venezuelan unionists came together in April 2003 to form an alternative to the CTV: the

Unión Nacional de Trabajadores

(UNETE, National

Union of Workers). Assuming the banner of cogestión as their own, the chant “ Empresa

24

cerrada es empresa tomada

” (a closed company is a company taken over) rang throughout the congress (Ellner 2006:118). This slogan soon began to reverberate across the country as

UNETE leaders promoted workplace discussions on cogestión, focusing on the concrete experiences of PDVSA and CADAFE (Lebowitz 2006:102-4).

Throughout the next two years, the constant focus on cogestión as an instrument for worker/community participation and the creation of new relations of production was evident in numerous documents, resolutions and speeches produced by workers (e.g. Comité Guía

2003; Comités Guía de la industria petrolera 2004; Comité de Refundación 2005;

FETRAELEC 2005a). A commission established by the Ministry of Labour, with the purpose of interviewing workers from occupied factories in order to come up with a proposal for their situation, concluded that the best action to take was nationalisation under workers’ control

(Cormenzana 2009:23). Nevertheless, 2005 would prove to be the year that cogestión really took off, as the government began to expropriate some of these companies and place them under cogestión.

2005: Year of cogestión

The first of these companies to be expropriated were Venezolana de Pulpa y Papel

(VENEPAL, Venezuelan Pulp and Paper) and

Constructora Nacional de Válvulas

(CNV,

National Valve Constructor) in January and April 2005, respectively. Renamed Industria

Venezolana Endógena de Papel

(INVEPAL, Venezuelan Endogenous Paper Industry) and

Industria Venezolana Endógena de Válvulas (INVEVAL, Venezuelan Endogenous Valve

Industry), both were placed under cogestión

Throughout the rest of the year, a handful of other expropriated companies were also placed under cogestión. All of these experiments involved worker-cooperatives owning shares in the company. While this aspect had been present in the cogestión model introduced at the Central

Azucarero Pío Tamayo (though not in PDVSA and CADAFE), the difference now was that the issue of ownership was increasingly emphasised in government discourse.

In August 2005, Chávez launched an initiative to promote cogestión in the private sector: the

Acuerdo Marco de Corresponsibilidad para la Transformacion Industrial

“Fabrica Adentro”

(Framework Agreement of Co-responsibility for Industry Transformation “Inside the

25

Factory”). Through

Fabrica Adentro , companies that were financially struggling were given access to low-interest state loans in return for granting workers participation and shares in the company. With over 1500 companies applying to be part of the program by the end of 2006, and government expectation’s that some 100,000 jobs would be created through this process,

Fabrica Adentro arguably proved to be the vehicle by which cogestión was most widely implemented (Azzellini 2009:23; Rangel 2006).

The focus on workers owning shares, however, was not present across all experiences of cogestión in 2005. The experiment undertaken in ALCASA (employing 3,000 workers) was not only the largest of its kind, but was viewed as a stepping-stone for expanding worker participation across the CVG. It also developed into the most ambitious experiment in social production , with workers directly electing managers and participating in drafting the company’s overall budget.

It should be noted though that, by this time, cogestión was moving backwards or had been completely dismantled in other state-owned companies. In PDVSA, union leaders became entangled in cases of clientalism and corruption (Lebowitz 2006:106). In CADAFE, despite the fact that management and workers had formally signed an agreement stating that the decisions of the comités de gestión

“would have a binding character on the function of the company”, the company president was now arguing that workers’ participation, should involve consultation, but should not be interpreted as meaning managers had to cede “their competencies and hand them over to workers” (Cerceau 2007:16, emphasis in original; Perez

Vigil 2005). By the end of 2004, this clash of views and interests had led to threats of industrial action, with union leaders denouncing that the company had been taken hostage “by managerial authoritarianism” (EFE 2005; FETRAELEC 2005).

Throughout this period, Chávez also emphasised the issue of satisfying social needs .

Referring to notes he had drafted while reading Mészáros’ Beyond Capital , Chávez stated during his July 17, 2005

Aló Presidente program that within this book he had found the key to building socialism: “communal production” had to be accompanied by “communal consumption” (Aló Presidente 2005a:18).

In an attempt to turn this idea into practice, Chávez called for the creation of Social

Production Enterprises (EPSs), which according to a September 2005 government decree, had

26

as their fundamental objective the generation of “goods and services that satisfy the basic and essential needs of the community and its surroundings” (Gaceta Oficial 2005a:5). Moreover,

EPSs had to be motivated by “the values of solidarity, cooperation, complementarity, reciprocity, equity and sustainability over... profit”. All the ministries involved with cogestión experiments would go on to promote the creation of EPSs.

A cogestión model?

As Osvaldo Alonso notes, by the end of 2005 it was possible to differentiate between three distinct cogestión models (Alonso 2007:26-27). Within the state sector, worker participation had been introduced in PDVSA, CADAFE and ALCASA. The first two fell under the auspice of MENPET and were rolled back, while ALCASA operated under the jurisdiction of the newly-created MIBAM. The second group was made up of recuperated factories such as

INVEPAL and INVEVAL, which came under the jurisdiction of MINEP, entrusted with overseeing the social economy. Finally, there were the private sector companies that participated in the MILCO-administered Fabrica Adentro program.

Given the diversity of projects that came to fall under the cogestión umbrella, it is unsurprising that a commonly agreed upon “model” or definition could not be found, even among ministries within the same government. The lack of any defined legislation also contributed to this situation. A further contributing factor was that government ministries preferred to tailor cogestión projects according to their particular views rather than attempt to work collectively to come up with a common vision of cogestión. In El Troudi and

Monedero’s words, the state resembled “an archipelago of unconnected islands” with little articulation and synergy between ministries (El Troudi & Monedero 2006:169).

Within the labour movement a variety of perspectives could also be found. While many union leaders talked of the need for workers’ control, there is little doubt that the government’s promotion of cooperatives, and the many financial incentives offered by the state for such enterprises, were attractive to many workers. Also important was the fact that the organized labour movement outside of the state sector remained small and largely unorganised. The prevalence of strong economistic tendencies within the working class that, compared to those in the informal sector, was relatively privileged was another factor to be taken into consideration. Finally, the lack of a strong, united national union federation that could

27

accompany and unify these struggles was a key factor in the reversal of fortunes in a number of cogestión experiments (Navas & Osorio 2007:8; Gómez, Tábata & Gámez 2005:17). This situation further deteriorated when the UNETE suffered a debilitating split in 2006 (Pollack

2006).

The overall weakness of the workers’ movement was revealed in its response to Chávez’s call to take over some 1000 abandoned factories (Aló Presidente 2005a:36). Despite the UNETE’s announcement that it had plans to occupy 800 factories over the next two years, the number of recuperated factories never exceeded 40 (Azzellini 2009:11).

These factors, combined with the government’s necessity to prioritise immediate needs such as reactivating the economy and creating jobs, meant that the model(s) of cogestión that came to predominate were exactly those that seemed furthest away from its original conception. It was not just in government discourse but in realities on the ground that the place initially reserved for worker participation was overtaken by worker ownership and profit sharing. It was also in this confused and highly dynamic context that Chávez began to rethink cogestión as part of a much broader concept of socialism focused as much on distribution and consumption as on production.

28

Cogestión and social ownership

Cogestión, as originally conceived, had as its primary focus the creation of a mechanism for co-governance between the state, workers and communities in the economic sphere. This was seen as essential to ensuring integral human development. The question of property rights, while present, was generally a secondary aspect. While the issue of workers owning company shares was present in similarly named experiences internationally, such considerations did not weigh heavily in the initial debates in Venezuela.

The focus on co-governance and worker participation was also evident at the 2005 May Day march. In his May Day speech, Chávez’s emphasis was clear: cogestión was not about replacing one owner with “300 proprietors who believe they are now the owners of the company… that would be perverse, we would be multiply the beast that is capitalism, that is egoism, that is individualism, to another level” (Despacho del Presidente 2005a:321). Instead, cogestión was about transforming relations of production via the incorporation of workers into the administration of enterprises.

The prominence given to participation was equally visible in the UNETE’s draft law on cogestión presented to Chávez at the march. Within the Ley de Participación de Trabajadores y Trabajadoras en la Gestión de Empresas Publicas y Privadas

(Law of Worker Participation in the Management of Public and Private Companies), the question of workers owning companies did not appear. Instead, the law focused on promoting worker participation in public and private companies. This was to be accomplished via the “democratisation of decision-making, participation in management at all hierarchical and organisational levels” and providing workers with “access to all operational, legal and financial documentation”

(UNETE 2005).

Yet, as the government moved to experiment with cogestión on a wider scale in 2005, the issue of ownership gained greater prominence, both in government discourse and in its concrete implementation. This was so much the case that, when a Cuban advisor was invited to Venezuela in 2005 as part of the discussion on cogestión, he concluded that “the central problem in the debate has been the issue of property” (Borrego 2006:75).

29

How did a seemingly secondary issue – that of workers owning shares –come to be

“superimposed” on the original conception of cogestión and dominate the debate over its implementation? (Cibank 2005) The seed of this confusion can be found in the government’s original vision of its new economic model.

Building the social economy

Present in both the new constitution and the first national development plan was the idea of an economic system based on three interrelated sectors: the public, private and social economy.

While the first two were viewed as part of the traditional economy, the social sector was described as “one of the most novel aspects” of the new constitution (MPD 2001:13). Its role was to incorporate unemployed and informal sector workers into the formal economy via the promotion of collectively owned enterprises, cooperatives and small and medium sized companies (MPD 2001:27).

Given these documents were produced half a decade before Chávez proclaimed the socialist character of the Bolivarian revolution, it is perhaps not surprising that this sector was viewed as “alternative and complementary” to the private and public sector, nor that its goal was the

“democratisation of the market and capital” (MPD 2001: 13, 27). At the time, moderate, procapitalist elements had a strong influence over the government and the original constituent assembly, a problem Chávez later acknowledged when proposing a number of radical changes to the constitution (Chávez Frías 2007a:63)

As noted in Chapter 1, neither the constitution nor the national development plan established a direct relationship between cogestión and the social economy with its emphasis on collective ownership. Despite elements of both featuring in early cogestión experiments, a distinction between the two concepts remained. Moreover, the first major experiments in cogestión occurred, not in the social sector, but in state-owned companies: PDVSA and CADAFE.

Workers in these companies saw no contradiction between, on the one hand, introducing cogestión and on the other, promoting the social economy.

Two months after Chávez appointed two unionists to the company board at PDVSA, workers there presented management with a proposal to “create and control the conditions which would allow for the protagonist-based ( protagónica

) participation of workers, communities and the National Armed Forces in the process of the construction and consolidation of the

30

New PDVSA” (Comité Guía 2003). Their proposal also spoke of promoting and strengthening small and medium-sized companies involved in activities with PDVSA. In

CADAFE, the new board of directors began approving resolutions to stimulate cooperatives in service areas while simultaneously encouraging the establishment of comités de gestión throughout the company’s internal structures to facilitate worker participation (Comité de

Refundación 2005:25-6). The question of workers owning PDVSA or CADAFE never emerged as a serious proposal as workers viewed cogestión as a means by which to expand workplace democracy. Nevertheless, a cogestión model involving cooperatives and collective ownership increasingly came to be applied in the majority of cogestión experiments initiated in 2005.

The main contributing factor to this was the change in the government’s orientation towards the social economy. As the process began to radicalise in 2003, Chávez’s increasingly anticapitalist discourse was paralleled by a shift towards viewing the social economy less as a complement and more as an alternative to the logic of capital (Lebowitz 2006:100).

Entrusted with the task of promoting the social economy, the newly established MINEP came to oversee not just collectively-owned enterprises and cooperatives, but also most of the recuperated factories. Although the decree to create MINEP differentiated between cogestión within the state economy and collective ownership in the social economy, MINEP began to fuse the two concepts (Gaceta Oficial 2004:17). This was particularly influenced by the fact that within MINEP, cogestión was seen as a stepping stone towards the greater goal of autogestión (self-management), where workers owned their own means of production

(MINEP 2005:17). The impact of this shift was clear in the cases of INVEPAL and

INVEVAL.

The recuperated factories model

This did not mean that the issue of worker participation disappeared. In fact, in the case of

INVEPAL, Chávez stressed the importance of “transferring power to the workers so that they can transform reality” (Aló Presidente 2005:11). During the same Aló Presidente

, Minister

Iglesias defined cogestión as “shared management of power” and as “taking into the economic sphere that [theme] which runs right through our constitution from start to finish, which is coresponsibility” (Aló Presidente 2005:17).

31

Ratifying the leading role he wanted workers to play within cogestión, Chávez proposed that workers at INVEVAL and INVEPAL should elect their company presidents (Campos 2006;

Lugo, Vessuri & Canino 2008:16). This was despite MINEP being legally entitled to name company presidents. This move also ensured that the worker-cooperatives held a majority on the company boards.

Nevertheless, the shifting emphasis towards workers owning shares was clear. In both

INVEPAL and INVEVAL, the government took the initiative to hand over 49% of company shares to the worker-cooperatives (Mendoza 2006). Workers were also promised 99% ownership of the company further down the track if they demonstrated their capacity to fully manage the enterprises (Azzellini 2009:18). The worker-cooperatives were also entitled to share company profits among themselves, something Chávez described as an important difference between capitalism and the new social economy his government was promoting

(Aló Presidente 2005:18).

The decision to place both companies under the auspices of MINEP was another indication that Chávez saw these companies as part of the social economy. This was particularly true for

INVEVAL which seemed to be an obvious candidate for being placed under the auspices of

MENPET, given its long-standing relationship with PDVSA, (CNV was owned by a former

PDVSA president and exclusively sold its valves to the state oil company) (Janicke 2007).

Hotel Kamarata was another enterprise that was handed over to its workers, this time under autogestión with the worker-cooperative given 100% ownership (MINCI 2005:4). In the case of the textile company Hilanderías Tinaquillo (Tinaquillo Spinners), converted into Industria

Venezolana Endógena Textil (INVETEX, Venezuelan Endogenous Textile Industry), the state took control of 51% ownership of the company, while the original owners held the rest of the shares (Tejero Puntes 2006). The idea was that the workers would gradually obtain the state’s shares (Cormenzana 2005).

With the launch of Fabrica Adentro in August 2005, cogestión’s association with collective ownership deepened. Granting worker-cooperatives shares became a requirement for receiving government loans. In order to encourage owners to give workers a greater stake in the company, the interest rate on the loans decreased as more shares were given to workers.

32

Although many came to question the limited nature of worker participation within these companies, the program seemed to have contributed to the reactivation of the economy and job creation. By the end of 2006, 847 companies had already had their projects approved

(Azzellini 2009:23).

The emphasis on the issue of ownership and profit sharing also became more prominent in

Chávez’s discourse. When launching the Fabrica Adentro program, Chávez suggested that the more shares worker-cooperatives owned, the more such a company could be said to be

“leaving capitalism” (MINCI 2005:36). Three months later, Chávez argued “capital is not bad in and of itself. What is bad is capitalism, which is the degeneration of the use of capital, when capital is concentrated in few hands and is utilised to exploit the rest” (Aló Presidente

2005b:23).

To be fair, this did not represent a fundamental shift in the government’s overall economic policies. The idea of an economic system based on a public, private and social sector was always present, as was the promotion of collective ownership and “democratisation of capital” within the latter. One difference was the increased emphasis on the social economy as an alternative to capitalism; another was that cogestión came to be seen as predominately applicable to this sector comprised of collectively-owned enterprises.

The problems with collective ownership however, soon began to manifest themselves in

INVEPAL, where the cooperative model was forcing workers “to operate in the market and become ‘owners’” (Mather 2006). Shortly after the cogestión experiment began, company executives decided to hire a former VENEPAL board member as “General Manager”

(Trabajadores despedidos de INVEPAL 2006). Entrusted with the daily running of the enterprise, the manager proceeded to convince company executives that rather than expanding the cooperative, a more economically sound decision would be to hire lower paid seasonal labourers for less than six months. This would not only increase profits, but also allow the company to avoid having to incorporate seasonal workers into the cooperative. Under

Venezuelan law, cooperatives could not hire workers for more than six months without incorporating them as members (Gaceta Oficial 2001:5). The result was that just before their six months was up, some 120 workers were fired.

33

For this reason, Venezuelan trade unionists taking part in an international solidarity gathering held in April 2005 came to reject the idea of workers owning shares in companies.

“Experience up until now teach us that it is only possible to develop the knowledge of the running of companies by workers when these belong to the state” read the final declaration approved at the meeting (cited in Lebowitz 2006:105). “The workers rejected any idea of turning workers of the co-managed or managed factories into small proprietors”.

Workers from INVEVAL, INVEPAL and other recuperated factories also began to draw similar conclusions, and in February 2006 took the initiative to form FRETECO, with the principal objective of promoting “the expropriation and nationalisation of Venezuelan industry and its placement under workers’ control” (FRETECO 2006:23). In practice, this meant companies being 100% stated owned, complete workers’ control in the running of the company and production to “satisfy the needs of society” (FRETECO 2007:12-16). The latter was to be accomplished by ensuring that companies were “participating as one more link in the planned economy and complying with the goals that society itself has imposed through such planning.”

By early 2007, Chávez was also convinced that collective property was not the answer. While it could be accommodated within twenty-first century socialism, in essence it remained private property. The proof of this for Chávez was INVEPAL:

What happened there? Well, we established a property regime where some shares were owned by the state, others by the workers. What began to happen there? We ended up [with a situation involving], if we don’t correct this in time, the capitalist state allied with capitalist workers, a capitalist cooperative and the medicine ends up being worse than the illness… (Aló Presidente 2007a:70).

Instead, Chávez began to forcefully insist on the need to promote forms of social property.

This change in position soon became evident in the cases of INVEVAL, INVEPAL and Pío

Tamayo, all of which came to be placed under 100% state-ownership. The same occurred with companies nationalised after 2006. The Fabrica Adentro program, which focused on workers owning shares, was “dragging workers towards an entrepreneurial logic without giving them real participation in decision-making,” and was soon replaced with Plan Fabrica

Socialista (Socialist Factory Plan) (Azzellini 2010:142). Launched in June 2007, the objective

34

of the plan was to create 200 state-owned socialist companies to produce a variety of essential goods.

The concrete realities of attempting to implement cogestión had contributed to a rethink by

Chávez of some of his ideas on building socialism. In place of collective property, Chávez proposed that property should remain in the hands of the state and communities. Rather than promoting a social economy parallel to the state and private economy, Chávez proposed to reform the constitution so that the state’s focus was on building a “socialist economy” within which social property was hegemonic (Chávez Frías 2007a:192-3). The focus though on human development remained, with the goal of the new socialist economy being to guarantee

“the satisfaction of social and material needs of the people, the greatest sum of social and political stability and the greatest sum of happiness possible”.

35

Cogestión and social production

Cogestión had initially been premised on the idea that participation in the workplace was an essential ingredient for ensuring human development. However, serious problems began to emerge in some of the companies under cogestión. These problems contributed to a shift in the government’s position towards cogestión. Reflecting on the turmoil in INVEPAL, Jaua explained that the problem there had been the result of “an incorrect selection of people” and the “absence of political consciousness” among workers (cited in Moreno 2006).

However, some in the labour movement were drawing a different conclusion. The problem was that participation had come to be mistakenly equated with the idea of democratising capital while drifting away from its focus on human development. As an alternative, workers within FRETECO were proposing nationalisation under workers’ control. Others pointed to the example of ALCASA, arguably the most advanced experiment in cogestión.

The initiative to introduce cogestión in ALCASA once again came from Chávez. At the end of 2004, he called upon CVG executive members to come up with proposals for developing cogestión in the basic industry complex. To facilitate its implementation, Chávez created

MIBAM in January 2005 and appointed the Cuban trained economist Víctor Álvarez to head up the new ministry. Álvarez in turn named Carlos Lanz, an ex-guerrilla and long-time supporter of workers’ control, to the presidency of ALCASA, entrusting him with the task of promoting cogestión there. The significance of this experiment can be understood when we consider that aluminium is Venezuela’s second most important basic industry, and that

ALCASA was the nation’s second largest aluminium smelter (Bruce 2008:104). Moreover, the success or failure of cogestión there would determine whether cogestión would be extended to the rest of the CVG complex.

In ALCASA, the focus of cogestión was clearly on worker participation and direct workplace democracy. “Co-management here” explained ALCASA worker Alcides Rivero “has a lot to do with workers’ control, because it’s really the workers who are taking the decisions” (Bruce

2008:106). Lanz agreed, arguing that “cogestión revolucionaria” was different to the traditional model of cogestión, with its focus on share ownership and worker representatives on company boards; it was “a proposal for transition toward towards socialism, towards

36

another system of production” (Bruce 2008:106). In ALCASA, “workers are to assume control of the plant in an integral manner. From the budget and administration, the technical and productive problems to the labour organisation at the ground level” (Peña Rojas 2006:22)

To achieve this task, Lanz pinpointed six key elements as fundamental to the success of cogestión: the election of all managers, regular report backs by all elected officials, revocability of delegates and managers, rotation of posts, freedom of debate and discussion, democratisation of knowledge and participation in the drafting of the company budget (Lanz

Rodríguez 2005). Taken as a whole, cogestión was not just about participation; it was about fundamental change in the workplace and in the consciousness of the workers. For this reason, Lanz saw cogestión “as a complex process, more political, ideological and cultural in its nature and less technical and administrative” (Peña Rojas 2006:22).

As Bruce notes in his case study of ALCASA, changing the relations of production required more than state ownership and centralised planning. In ALCASA, cogestión aimed “to restore a third, vital component to its proper place in a socialist transition. This was the indispensable question of overturning any monopoly of knowledge and giving all people, in this case all members of the workforce, the power to discuss and decide” (Bruce 2008:110).

The ALCASA model

In January 2005, company managers, labour directors and trade union representatives at

ALCASA signed a commitment to implement cogestión: the Declaración de Macagua

(Macagua Declaration), which represented (Lanz Rodríguez 2009:27). The aim was to introduce “worker participation in the management and administration of the company, in coresponsibility with the state” (Lanz Rodríguez 2009:28).

An emphasis was also placed on the democratización del saber (democratisation of knowledge) where “socialisation of the diverse technical-productive components of the company would allow workers to make conscious decisions, participating in an integral manner in the elaboration of proposals for restructuring production” (Lanz 2009:28). To assist this educative process, the Centro de Formación Sociopolítica Negro Primero (“Negro

Primero” Socio-Political Education Centre) was established in July 2005 (Gerencia de

Asuntos Públicos 2005f).

37

The process of cogestión was developed in two phases. The first involved the election of managers and establishment of mesas de trabajo (work committees) in each department of the factory; the second developed a participatory budget within ALCASA.

Throughout March and April of 2005, the first phase was kicked off with workers voting to elect managers in each department. In place of the traditional set-up where one person filled a management post, three workers were elected in each department in order to make it more difficult for corruption to arise (Gerencia de Asuntos Públicos 2005; Gerencia de Asuntos

Públicos 2005a). Parallel to this process of democratising management structures, efforts towards creating organs of worker decision-making were also undertaken. A bottom-up system for decision-making was established involving teams of five to ten workers electing voceros (spokespeople) in each area of the company. These voceros came together to form departmental-wide mesas de trabajo . In all, 231 voceros were elected to 19 separate mesas de trabajo in ALCASA (Bruce 2008:112). Sitting alongside the voceros were the three elected

“worker-managers.” Their role was to implement the decisions made at the weekly meetings of the mesas de trabajo (Bruce 2008:113).

The mesas de trabajo became a space where voceros would pass on workers’ concerns, and where attempts were made to resolve problems by consensus (although when this was not possible, a simply majority vote was taken). When no agreement could be reached, the issue was referred back to an assembly of all the workers in the department. If an issue affected the entire company, an assembly of the entire workforce had the final say.

While decisions pertaining to the internal structure of ALCASA fitted more neatly within the traditional concept of workers’ control, the “co” element was present as the state, via

MIBAM, played a role in setting “the essential parameters within which ALCASA had to work – financial, industrial, commercial and political” (Bruce 2008:113). According to then secretary of the Sindicato de Trabajadores de CVG ALCASA (SINTRALCASA, CVG

ALCASA Workers’ Union), Trino Silva, workers also proposed that local community representatives sit on the company board (Harnecker 2005a). In November 2005, two members of nearby communities were elected as company executives (Azzellini 2011:390).

38

This internal restructuring shared many similarities, at least on paper, with what workers in

PDVSA and CADAFE were proposing (See Comité Guía 2003; Comité de Refundación

2005:17). However, unlike ALCASA, the election of managers was not seen as a priority in either. Workers in CADAFE instead emphasised the need for appointed managers to be accountable to the deliberations of the comités de gestión (Fuentes 2009:71). In fact, workers within CADAFE elected only one manager. This exception occurred in one of CADAFE’s regional affiliates, the Compañía Anónima de Electricidad de los Andes (CADELA, Los

Andes Electricity C.A). There, in 2004, the president of CADELA granted workers in the state of Merida the opportunity to elect their own statewide manager from a workers’ assembly (Harnecker 2005:20).

Another difference between ALCASA and CADAFE was that workers in the latter played no role in the budgetary process. The idea behind the participatory budget was that by participating in the elaboration of an overall diagnosis of the company, workers would begin to look beyond their immediate surroundings and help develop a company-wide plan for recuperating ALCASA (Gerencia de Asuntos Públicos 2005c). Moreover, as Marivit Lopez explained, this was also the difference between limiting participating to the productive process and expanding it to the overall direction of the company (Bruce 2008:123).

The first preliminary steps involved meetings between company managers and voceros to discuss ways in which costs could be immediately reduced, with all decisions being distributed among workers (Gerencia de Asuntos Públicos 2005d; Gerencia de Asuntos

Públicos 2005e; Gerencia de Asuntos Públicos 2005g). Meanwhile, the mesas de trabajo set about studying and discussing the budget for 2006. During this process, workers were for the first time given access to the company’s accounting books, thus ensuring that “no more commercial, administrative or technological secrets” remained, as Rivero put it (Bruce

2008:115).

By the end of the year, the company board could point to a number of important advances in

ALCASA. These included the payment of debts owed to workers, the election of new managers and voceros , a successful campaign to reduce costs and increase production, plans for a participatory budget, the creation of a worker’s education centre, introduction of new technology, and an internal restructuring of the plant (CVG Alcasa 2005). Furthermore, in

April 2006, the third phase of the cogestión process began, with Lanz inviting workers to

39

debate the option of a workers’ council replacing the company board as the supreme organ for running the company (a feature later incorporated into the collective contract for 2006-2008)

(Gerencia de Asuntos Públicos 2006a; Gerencia de Asuntos Públicos 2006d). The issue of reducing the workday (with no loss in pay), as a means for allowing workers “free time for rest, recreation, study and to share with their family,” was also raised (Gerencia de Asuntos

Públicos 2006b).

Barriers to participation

Nevertheless, the process of introducing cogestión in a variety of companies exposed a number of important barriers that would need to be overcome for workplace democracy to really take hold. One of these was the presence of company managers who feared losing the power they currently held. This was particularly true in CADAFE where many key positions continued to be held by managers appointed prior to Chávez’s election or aligned with moderate chavista forces who “assumed an unfriendly attitude towards Chavista employees”

(Ellner 2006:120). In late 2004, FETRAELEC began publicly denouncing these sectors for waging a systematic campaign against cogestión. The campaign involved the firing of managers and workers who supported cogestión and the promotion of parallel unions so as to undermine the position of the pro-cogestión FETRAELEC leadership (Harnecker 2005:16;

Navas & Osorio 2007:6). Within PDVSA, the comités guías

also denounced the presence of a similar campaign being waged by the new “techno-bureaucracy” that had entrenched itself within management (Comités Guía de la industria petrolera 2004). In both CADAFE and

PDVSA, management counted on the support of MENPET, given the hostility that Minister

Ramirez held towards cogestión.

A further barrier was the old vertical-based structure of these companies, which remained intact within existing laws and company statutes. Designed during the neoliberal era, this legal framework radically inhibited worker participation and, in some cases, opened the door to privatisation (FETRAELEC 2005b:6-7). For this reason, FETRAELEC proposed an overhaul of the laws and regulations governing the electrical sector and the approval of a new law on cogestión that could give this concept some kind of legal framework (FETRAELEC

2005:5-7).

40

Even in places where workers had elected managers, barriers persisted. Venezuela’s basic industry sector had for a long time been home to a network of powerful clientalist networks, comprised of foreign capital, local managers, trade unions and government officials

(Blankenburg 2008:20). It therefore came as little surprise that moves to open company books were vehemently resisted. When the cogestión process in ALCASA threatened to put a halt to some of these shady business dealings, the multinationals struck back. Following a decision by workers to annul an unfavourable memorandum of understanding that the previous management had signed with Glencore, the multinational company responded with a campaign of boycott and sabotage. (Rodríguez 2005; Lanz Rodríguez 2009:37, 62). Trade union leaders who saw cogestión as a threat to both the union’s power, and their personal privileges, also opposed the process (Bruce 2008:125)

Resistance to cogestión did not only come from those that saw it as a threat to their profits or power, but also from workers themselves. One year into the experiment, Lanz believed that workers still remained divided on the issue; with a majority supporting cogestión, but mainly

“with the hope of getting some material benefit out of it” (Peña Rojas 2006:22).

The facts on the ground seemed to back up Lanz’s assessment. By early 2006, the mesas de trabajo were meeting much less frequently, and in some departments had stopped meeting all together (Peña Rojas 2006:26). Union elections in January 2006 ended with strong results for the two main tickets which campaigned almost exclusively on the issues of wages and conditions; supporters of cogestión failed to win more than 6% of the vote (Peña Rojas

2006:22, 30). In June 2006, workers at ALCASA voted to return to a system of single managerial posts, and subsequently elected many of the same managers that had been removed in the previous elections (Gerencia de Asuntos Públicos 2006c; Bruce 2008:126).

When Lanz left the company in May 2007, the cogestión process “suffered a severe setback” with a majority of alcasianos “no longer advocat[ing] cogestión or workers councils”

(Azzellini 2011:391).

A similar resistance was also present among workers in CADAFE, according to union leaders

(Fuentes 2009:65). Concerns were raised that some workers had begun to view cogestión as a vehicle for pursuing their own personal interests rather than for advancing worker participation (Fuentes 2009:66, 71). The worst examples of this occurred in PDVSA, leading to a situation which one UNETE leader from the oil sector described as a “disaster” for

41

cogestión (Riera 2008:53). There, union leaders had reverted to the “deeply rooted practice” of political clientalism, using their positions of power to sell lucrative jobs in one of the highest paying industries in the country (Ellner 2006:120). Undoubtedly this proved to be a key factor in Chávez’s subsequent decision to declare “strategic sectors”, such as PDVSA, off bounds for cogestión (Aló Presidente 2006)

For Edgar Caldera, a labour director at ALCASA, the explanation for all this was that the mentality of clientalism and corruption remained strong even within the minds of the workers

(Bruce 2008:125). Former managers had taken advantage of this to subvert the democratic process for their own ends. For this reason, some workers tended to agree with Jaua’s assessment that the central problem was the lack of political consciousness among workers.

Arguing that a majority of alcasianos had been won over to supporting cogestión through their participation in education courses, one worker stated “we still have to give courses to more than 1000 workers… so that everyone will understand what co-management is and what we want to accomplish with co-management” (Peña Rojas 2006:33). Providing workers with the necessary information and tools with which to fully participate is undeniably a critical ingredient to the success of any cogestión project. For this reason, the idea raised in ALCASA

(and later by Chávez), of reducing the workday in order to allow workers time for study was crucial.

Yet in many ways this argument neatly dovetailed with those put forward by opponents of cogestión. Oil minister Rafael Ramirez also concluded that the Venezuelan working class was not ready for cogestión, given its tendency to behave “in a profoundly conservative manner because it benefits from a set of privileges and fights to maintain them” (Cabieses Donoso

2008). For this reason, Borrego, like Ramirez, argued that in place of worker participation, what was needed was a state that could “exercises its functions responding to the interests of society as owner of all the means at its disposal and in search of greater efficiency, quality and efficacy of social production” (Borrego 2006:78, emphasis in original).

Producing ‘new human beings’

Chávez was clearly concerned by the hold that these deeply entrenched vices had over the workers movement. In his

Aló Presidente

of January 21, 2007, he criticised the economistic outlook of the union movement, and railed against those “workers who work in a state

42

company and believe that it belongs to them” (Aló Presidente 2007:57). Complaining that some workers only wanted to enrich themselves further so that they could live like the “rich class”, Chávez said these attitudes were far removed from those of the “new human being” that he believed were essential for creating socialism.

Earlier in the show, he had referred to this idea of the “new human being”. Quoting a passage from a pamphlet by Lebowitz 4 , Chávez said: “No one articulated better in the twentieth century the importance of developing new, socialist human beings that Che Guevara” (Aló

Presidente 2007:23). According to Chávez, Che had emphasised the need to simultaneously develop the material base of socialism together with creating the “new man, the new woman.”

The way to do this, said Chávez (again reading out a passage from Lebowitz) was through

“the simultaneous changing of circumstances... and self-change (what Marx called

‘revolutionary practice’) [this] is how we build the new society and new human beings” (Aló

Presidente 2007:24).

Others drew the same conclusion. Asked about the problem of flagging participation at

ALCASA, one worker explained that this was due to voceros failing to properly inform workers of what was occurring. This had led to increased “apathy in [sic] part of the

Spokemen and the people that are involved in the process of co-management” (Peña Rojas

2006:31-2). While understanding that “co-management is a long term process”, one in which it was essential “to change the mentality of many workers,” cogestión could only advance through the involvement of “workers directly with [sic] the process of co-management.”

The evidence seemed to support this notion. In CADELA, where cogestión was strongly supported and promoted by both the elected manager and the local union, 80 to 90% of workers were participating in the comités de gestión (Harnecker 2005:20). Through this process, many of those who had initially opposed cogestión began demanding its expansion into other areas as they started to see the positive outcomes of worker participation both for themselves and the company (Fuentes 2009:65-6). High levels of participation were accompanied by improvements in the company’s financial standing and a reduction in labour conflicts and work injuries, among other gains (Harnecker 2005:28-30).

4 See Lebowitz 2006

43

Events in INVEPAL and Pío Tamayo revealed the negative side of reducing worker participation. While it was true that workers had initially selected “incorrect people” to represent them on the company board, they had not been alone in making this mistake. At the state-owned Central Azucarera Ezequiel Zamora (Ezequiel Zamora Sugar Mill), where managers had been appointed by the state, corruption scandals had engulfed the enterprise

(Últimas Noticias 2006). The difference in the case of INVEPAL was that the existence of cogestión meant workers could recall their representatives, which they did in November 2005

(Rodríguez 2006).

Fearful of the “chaos” that had come with the decision to open up spaces for participation, and conscious of the need to avoid a situation were INVEPAL went bust, MINEP gradually reduced the power of the cooperative, beginning with the state reasserting its right to appoint the company president (Vive Tv 2006). Yet reducing participation did not seemed to provide a solution to the problem of corruption. Following the subsequent discovery of US$800,000 worth of unaccounted costs within INVEPAL’s budget, an official government report alleged that no corruption had occurred. Instead, blame lay with “administrative disorder” caused as a result of having handed over the company to the workers (Azzellini 2009:19). Workers however, alleged corruption on the part of management (Ramírez &Trabajadores despedidos de Invepal 2006).

In Pío Tamayo, where workers were protesting a lack of access to financial records and real participation (leading to intense conflict between the union and the company’s workerpresident), the government also responded by appointing a new company president without consulting workers (Lucena 2006:15; Aldana 2010). When the government moved to acquire full ownership of the company, the main concern for workers and cane cutters was receiving the payout for their shares as quickly as possible (Aldana 2010).

Here, the appointment of ‘efficient’ managers, while perhaps helping in some cases to increase productivity, had not necessarily resolved the problems of corruption and backward consciousness among workers. Where workers were denied the right to manage companies and develop their capacities, others had used this ‘right’ to maintain their own privileges. This had helped reinforce divisions between managers and workers, and with it the economistic tendencies present within the workers movement. Only through the process of participating in workplace decision-making, could workers both change their surroundings and develop their

44

own capacities. Cogestión did not require the selection of ‘ideal people’; rather the very process of participation helped create ‘ideal people’.

Yet if democratic participation was necessary in production, it was also essential to ensure that production was aimed at satisfying the needs of the communities. This issue of consumption was perhaps foremost in Chávez’s concerns regarding the whole cogestión project – a concern driven by the serious requirement to address the immediate needs of the poor majority that made up the bulk of his support base. Mészáros idea of a system of communal production and consumption had captured Chávez’s attention, so much so that he progressively came to displace cogestión with the idea of the EPS. This proposal was an attempt to deal with the third side of Chávez’s “socialist triangle”, the satisfaction of social needs, which is the focus of the next chapter.

45

Cogestión and social needs

Increasingly concerned by the prevailing economistic tendencies within the organised working class, Chávez began to shift his focus to the question of how to encourage workers to consider the needs of those excluded from the formal economy and who populated the impoverished communities surrounding their enterprises. The solution to this dilemma,

Chávez argued in his July 17 Aló Presidente

program, was to be found in Mészáros’ idea of a

“communal system of production and consumption” (Aló Presidente 2005b:23) .

In Beyond Capital

, Mészáros had argued that the construction of socialism was predicated on

“instituting a radically new type of exchange relations (Mészáros 1995:758). Whereas capitalism was based on the exchange of commodities, socialism required re-establishing exchange relations on the basis of activities , determined by communal needs and communal purposes ” (Karl Marx cited in Mészáros 1995:750, emphasis in original).

With this is mind, Chávez launched the idea of Social Production Enterprises (EPSs). From the outset, two ideas shaped Chávez’s vision of what an EPS should look like. Firstly, that production had to be geared towards social needs not profit; and secondly, that profits generated by EPSs had to directly contribute to the wellbeing of surrounding communities.

During his November 27, 2005

Aló Presidente program, Chávez read out a definition of EPS.

This definition, he noted, was the result of “an intense debate during the preceding months” among his cabinet members. Stressing that this was to be taken as a guide and not a dogma, he said that EPSs:

… are those economic entities dedicated to the production of goods or services, in which labour has its own significance, is non-alienated, authentic; in which there exist no social discrimination in labour or of any type of labour, no privileges exist in labour associated with a hierarchical position. Those economic entities with substantive equality among their members, based on participatory and protagonist planning, and under a regime of state property, collective property or a combination of both (Aló Presidente 2005b:31).

Chávez added another important characteristic, stating that for any company to “be truly one for social production”, it must distribute profits in a different manner. Chávez proposed that

EPSs should instead reinvest profits back into four funds: a self-sufficiency fund that could

46

ensure the economic viability of the enterprise, a labour fund to cover the needs of workers, a fund for promoting social development programs, and a fund for the promotion of new EPSs

(Aló Presidente 2005b:34).

Various ministries were quick to take up Chávez’s call to build such enterprises, principally

MIBAM, MINEP, MILCO and MINEP (El Troudi & Monedero 2006:176). All of these ministries were involved in some way with the different cogestión projects, and as with cogestión, EPSs came to take on different characteristics depending on the ministry involved.

The EPS models

For MIBAM, the focus of an EPS was on creating a human-centred economy that could satisfy both the material and spiritual needs of workers (MIBAM 2005). More specifically, they were to be geared towards four essential sectors: food, clothing, housing and health.

Communities would collectively own companies with the aim of ensuring that these enterprises responded to the needs of the community. A portion of the profits generated was to go into a fund that would be utilised for the promotion of further such enterprises.

To kick-start the process of creating EPSs, MIBAM and CVG converted their Guayana

Regional Fund into a Social Production Fund. The regulations for accessing finances from the fund were changed to enable the newly emerging EPSs to acquire loans, given that the old rules only took into consideration traditional capitalist firms (MINCI 2006a:13). Further help for nascent EPSs came in the form of providing secure markets for their products. This was achieved by obliging state companies to contract EPSs for any goods or services required.

This was critical, said Minister Álvarez, given the unequal advantage held by “large contractors that had already established themselves” (MINCI 2006a:14).

By the end of 2005, 260 EPSs had been formed in Guayana, producing uniforms, shoes, wheelchairs, furniture and other goods and services. In many ways the charge was led by

ALCASA, with workers previously employed by private contractors being encouraged to establish their own enterprises so that the company could directly contract them (Peña Rojas

2006:27). By 2006, a network of between 11 and 16 cooperatives had come to replace the traditional private contractors responsible for supplying ALCASA’s 3,000 workers with company uniforms (Bruce 2008:121).

47

Problems however soon emerged with the perseverance of the old “capitalist work culture” leading to the reproduction of traditional worker-manager divisions within some EPSs (Peña

Rojas 2006:27). Another important obstacle was the attempts by company management and union leaders to subvert agreements with the EPSs in order to pave the way for a return of the old private contractors, and with them the kickbacks they previously received (Bruce

2008:120).

The focus on replacing previous private contractors with EPSs was also incorporated into

MENPET’s overall plans. A Register of Social Production Enterprises (REPS) was established by PDVSA for this purpose (PDVSA 2006:4). In order to be registered, companies had to designate a percentage of their profits towards a Social Fund and/or directly provide goods or services to the community. The resources accrued in the Social Fund would go towards communal council projects approved by the mobile cabinets established by the government to sort through the countless applications for funding. Another requirement was that these enterprises contribute to the creation of other EPSs. Mention was also made of the need to incorporate cooperative labour and collective ownership as part of these enterprises, with cooperatives “by their very nature” deemed to be EPSs (PDVSA 2006a:2). In November

2005, Minister Ramirez organised an exhibition of 160 EPSs that had dealings with PDVSA in the areas of construction, maintenance, repairs, clothing and manufacturing, among others

(Aló Presidente 2005b:31).

What these changes meant in practice though are debatable, as many of the EPSs came to resemble the same old firms that PDVSA traditionally dealt with, albeit that they now had to contribute to a social fund via a tax on profits (Azzellini 2010:140). Ultimately, it was still

PDVSA management who determined what goods and services were to be produced, while direct community or worker participation was largely absent from many of these projects.

Workers at INVEVAL argued that opposition to worker participation was the main reason behind PDVSA’s continued refusal to commit to purchasing their valves (Janicke 2007).

Elsewhere, MILCO and MINEP were busy reconverting companies under cogestión into

EPSs. Having rebaptised those companies participating in Fabrica Adentro as EPSs, the focus of the program, according to Minster Iglesias, was now not only on “democratising the property of the company among its workers” but also ensuring companies “take up

48

commitments with the community that surrounds them” (Rangel 2006). A similar condition was introduced by MINEP in the process of converting numerous cooperatives and recovered factories into EPSs. Some noted that this conversion meant very little in practice beyond a name change (Azzellini 2009:9, 18). For example, the original decree creating INVEVAL had already included a requirement that the company reinvest no less than 20% of its profits into local communities and promotion of the social economy (Gaceta Oficial 2005:10). This was similarly the case with the Fabrica Adentro program (MINCI 2005:10). The biggest hurdle though for some of the recuperated factories was not compliance with this obligation, but the fact that they were hardly producing any profit at all. By the end of 2006, neither INVEVAL nor INVETEX had restarted operations, and INVEPAL was just breaking even (Alfonso

2008; Tejero Puntes 2006).

Numerically at least, it seemed that EPSs had taken off everywhere except among the recuperated factories that were still struggling to get up and running. In terms of reactivating the country’s productive apparatus and job creation, the government could point to numerous positive economic indicators, partially the result of this government policy: GDP growth was

10.3% in 2005 and again in 2006; the reactivation of already installed capacity, which was running at 85.6% in the first quarter of 2005 but had risen to 92.1% by the last quarter of

2006; and a fall in unemployment of almost 4% during the same period (Álvarez 2009:248,

259; El Troudi 2010:58).

Beyond the magical state

Yet, as Álvarez notes, the reactivation experienced during this period in large part represented a reactivation of the capitalist economy. To back up his claim, Álvarez points to figures from the Banco Central de Venezuela (BCV, Central Bank of Venezuela) that showed the private sector’s share of GDP had grown from 65.2% in 1998 to 70.4% in 2006, outpacing that of the public sector whose share had fallen (Álvarez 2009:254-5). The much touted and promoted social economy – the supposed embryo of the new socialist economic model – represented a paltry 1.8% of GDP.

Even the positive examples of EPSs raised important questions about the overall project.

Many of these provided fertile training grounds for workers in collective organising and had helped in raising consciousness about the necessity of producing for social needs. Yet, there

49

seemed to be serious doubts as to their capacity to provide the foundation of a new socialist economy. Their success had been largely due to their ability to secure contracts with stateowned companies and/or their access to favourable government funds, the latter readily available due to booming oil prices. Under different circumstances, the survival of such enterprises would certainly have been in doubt.

Overall, the tendency seemed to point towards a greater dependency on the state, rather than towards a greater level of societal self-organisation within the social economy. With record high oil prices, Venezuela’s state seemed more than ever to be “an incarnation of charismatic powers that appear to be providential” (Coronil 2008a:19-20).

Conscious of this, Chávez confronted it in his November 17, 2005 Aló Presidente

program dedicated to EPSs. Referring to a request made by cooperative members from the

Núcleo

Endógeno Fabricio Ojeda

(Fabrica Ojeda Endogenous Unit) for more machinery, Chávez retorted:

Be careful, be careful, you have badly accustomed yourselves to [the idea that] we have to give you everything. Because when I hear you, I am left worrying inside, as if we have to do everything… You should not get use to [the idea] that we have to give you everything, because there may come a day when we don’t have anymore to give

(Aló Presidente 2005b:19).

He also complained of a similar state of affairs within CADAFE, calling on the company to stop asking the state for help and to instead force big companies and state institutions to pay their bills or otherwise have their electricity cut off.

In recognition of these challenges, Borrego argued social ownership of the means of production was the only way of ensuring that the results of labour were of “entirely social benefit” (Borrego 2006:78). This view was shared by Minister Ramirez, who argued that placing control of the country’s oil wealth in the hands of “the Venezuelan state, as the collective representative of our country, as the representative of the collective interest” was the key to building socialism (Ramirez 2005:9-10). In the absence of a revolutionary proletariat, only the state could ensure that this oil wealth was directed to meeting peoples’ social needs as well as creating the necessary economic foundation upon which to build socialism (Cabieses Donoso 2008).

50

As demonstrated above, Chávez became convinced of the need for social property. However,

Chávez came to see this as only one side of his socialist triangle. Equally important was worker participation in production and community participation in distribution. In the absence of the latter, the only alternatives were the market or state-imposed planning. Neither however provided a path towards integral human development, as they were premised on a system of consumption driven by either individual or state-imposed needs.

Analysing the rise of the EPSs, Lebowitz identified two types of EPSs: those which predominately had relations with state companies and those that were linked to communities

(Lebowitz 2006:111). In the case of the former, worker participation in decision-making had to be promoted across workplaces, thereby allowing workers in state firms and EPSs to base their activities upon relations of solidarity and cooperation, rather than operating as independent entities involved in the exchange of commodities. For those EPS based in the community, “the direct articulation of community needs and productive activities” was only possible to the extent that the communities themselves identified their own needs and priorities. The emergence of communal councils

5

, argues Lebowitz, provided communities with an instrument to begin to take on this task (Lebowitz 2006:112).

“In both cases, the premise is democratic decision making: the development of relations in which the collective producer is both ‘the object and the subject of power’” explained

Lebowitz, borrowing a phrase penned by Chávez in the early nineties during his time in jail

(Lebowitz 2006:111). In such a scenario, people would be the subjects of power within companies and their communities, and exchange could occur not on based of exchanging commodities, but rather worker and community needs.

The reality of the EPS experience however, seemed to point in the opposite direction. For this reason, Social Production Enterprises came to be replaced with Social Property Enterprises, and then Socialist Production Enterprises (Álvarez & Rodríguez 2008:56). By mid-2007, the promotion of further EPSs was put on hold in anticipation of the ultimately unsuccessful changes proposed to the constitution. Subsequently, the term EPS came to be used to refer to a variety of projects but “without the existence of any official defined criteria” to describe exactly what was meant by EPS (Azzellini 2010:141).

5 Communal councils are geographically-based units of community organising, involving 200-400 families in urban areas and 20-50 families in rural areas

51

Cogestión and the ‘socialist triangle’

In attempting to build twenty-first century socialism, the Venezuelan government had to confront many of the same dilemmas that previous socialist experiments encountered in the spheres of ownership, production and distribution. The contradictory nature of the government’s implementation of cogestión was largely the product of attempting to deal with these issues. Moreover, all of this occurred within a context where divergent views on cogestión and socialism existed within the government. Through this process, the practice of cogestión came to resemble something quite different from its initial conception in the constitution. Another consequence was the emergence of Chávez’s “socialist triangle”, which in many ways represented a return to some of the same ideas that had motivated the promotion of cogestión in the first place.

In January 2007, Chávez spoke of his idea of the “socialist triangle” for the first time.

Speaking on

Aló Presidente , he said it was paramount that any future cogestión experiments be “based on the [socialist] triangle… social property, social production and satisfaction of needs” (Aló Presidente 2007a:82). Chávez also went on to develop some general guidelines of what each side of the triangle could look like.

Social ownership

During the same

Aló Presidente , Chávez defined social property as state ownership over the strategic means of production. At the same time, Chávez made it very clear that this was not the same as state capitalism: the key difference was that he was referring to “the social State, not the bourgeois state, not the capitalist state” (Aló Presidente 2007a:49). A state, as Chávez would later explain, built upon communal and worker councils (Chávez Frías 2007:73).

In August that year, Chávez would further refine his ideas on social property as part of a proposal for 33 constitutional reforms aimed at bringing the constitution into line with his socialist project.

6

Addressing the National Assembly, Chávez returned to his idea of the

6 Our focus is on Chávez’s initial proposed reforms as they were penned by him personally and so therefore best reflect his views on what he believed needed to be amended in the constitution. After Chávez’s initial proposal was submitted for discussion in the National Assembly, a further 36 proposed reforms were added and some of

52

“basic economic triangle: property, production and distribution” and suggested that Article

112 of the constitution be modified to focus on the state promotion of social property (Chávez

Frías 2007a: 94, 192-3). A definition of social property was laid out in Chávez’s proposed modification to Article 115:

Social property is that which belongs to the people as a whole and to future generations, and can take two forms: indirect social property, when it is exercised by the state in the name of the community, and direct social property, when the state assigns it, under different forms and within demarcated territorial areas, to one or various communities, to one or various communes, thereby constituting itself as communal property, or to one or various cities, thereby constituting itself as citizen’s property… (Chávez Frías 2007a:197, underline in original).

Chávez referred to PDVSA as an example of indirect social property, whereby the company was “managed by the state, but belongs to all citizens”, adding again that the state he was referring to was “the state we are building, the socialist state” (Chávez Frías 2007a:99). In explaining the concept of direct social property, Chávez used the example of a corn flour processing plant, the ownership of which could be transferred from the state to an organised community with the purpose of attending to peoples’ needs. This conception, he said, differed from collective property (also included in Article 115), whereby a group of people or a cooperative, privately owned an enterprise and shared profits among them. Collective property is the “private property of a group” said Chávez, “it is not social property, let’s not fool ourselves” (Chávez Frías 2007a:100-1).

Here it is worth examining of the some of the ideas of Mészáros and Lebowitz, both of whom, as has been demonstrated in this thesis, came to influence Chávez’s thinking on socialism.

Arguing in favour of social property, Lebowitz says that social ownership of the means of production is a prerequisite for ensuring that they are “used in the interests of society and not for private gain” (Lebowitz 2010:40). While everything around us is the collective result of the social labour of past and present generations, under capitalism, it is capital which accrues the wealth generated by society due to its ownership of the means of production. Given the

“irreconcilable structural antagonism between capital and labour”, the latter had to be excluded from ownership of the means of production “on the grounds of which… the key decisions are made and the manifold partial functions of the social body are combined into a

Chávez’s initial ones were slightly amended. Ultimately, the overall proposal was defeated in a referendum held in December 2007.

53

whole” (Mészáros 2001:71; Mészáros 1995:739). To redress this situation, the fruits of social labour must be placed under social control, thereby ensuring that people can participate in the key decisions affecting their lives and those of future generations. This is only possible when the means of production are socially owned, a prerequisite for social productivity being directed towards “the free development of all rather than used to satisfy the private goals of capitalists, groups of individuals, or state bureaucrats” (Lebowitz 2009:27-8).

Unlike state ownership, where state officials direct production, social ownership requires the involvement of “all those affected by decisions about the use of means of production… deciding upon that use” (Lebowitz 2010:41, emphasis in original). In the case of Chávez’s example of the corn flour processing plant, direct social property could involve the participation not just of the workers within the plant, but also of those working in factories dependent on the corn flour produced there as well as local corn farmers and families living in the local rural community affected by the operations of the plant. In the case of indirect social property, that is property in the hands of the state, Chávez made clear he was referring to a socialist state resting on communal and worker councils as organs of popular power. Thus the people, and not simply state-appointed officials, would decide how the nation’s oil wealth would be used.

Chávez’s emphasis on the need for social ownership was in large part motivated by the dangers he came to see as inherent within collectively owned companies. These dangers – which in some cases became reality – included workers focusing on making more profit in order to enrich themselves, the fostering of competition between workers in different factories and the reproduction of the traditional division of labour within companies between those that work (do) and those that manage (think). To this list, Lebowitz added a further dilemma: the fact that “not everyone has equal access to those means of production owned in common”

(Lebowitz 2010:41). For example, someone living in Venezuela’s industrial heartland,

Guayana, would obviously have more access to the means of production than a peasant farmer living in a rural town in the isolated southern state of Amazonas. Given this, how can the wealth produced by social labour, both past and present, be equally distributed?

Social production

54

For Lebowitz, the answer to this question lies in Karl Marx’s idea that “ real wealth is the development of human capacity

” (cited in Lebowitz 2010:42, italics in original). Production must be understood not simply as producing goods and services to satisfy basic needs but also as an integral part of creating “new human beings”. In the Venezuelan constitution, such integral human development is to be achieved through “the participation of the people in forming, carrying out and controlling the management of public affairs” including in the workplace. This was the focus of the second side of Chávez’s socialist triangle: social production.

The necessity for worker participation is explained by the fact that labour “has as its result a joint product – both the change in the object of labor and the change in the labourer herself”

(Lebowitz 2010:52). In this context, wealth distribution should be understood as ensuring that production meets both the material and spiritual needs of individuals and of society as a whole

(Mészáros 2008:218) The abolition of the “despotism of the workshop” is therefore a necessary prerequisite to ensure that “the consciously self-controlled life-activity of the social individuals could be integrated into a both productively viable and humanly fulfilling whole”

(Mészáros 1995:751). This would require a restructuring of the labour process, so that the traditional division of labour between workers and managers could be replaced by a system in which humans ceased “to play the role necessarily assigned to them by capital” (Mészáros

1995:765).

To deal with this question of social production, Chávez proposed reforming Article 70 of the constitution to replace cogestión with the terms “workers council” and “democratic workers management in any company of direct or indirect social property” (Chávez Frías 2007a:185).

While Chávez also proposed removing reference to cogestión in Article 184, Point 4, he simultaneously proposed expanding workers’ participation beyond services managed by state governments and municipal councils (as was currently the case), to those under the jurisdiction of the national government (Chávez Frías 2007a:221).

Another related reform was the proposed change to Article 90, which would have reduced the workday for eight to six hours. The purpose of this reduction was to allow workers to dedicate part of their workday to learning how to manage companies and ensure they had “sufficient time for their own integral personal development” (Chávez Frías 2007a:189). This was essential given that under capitalism, capital’s control over production and distribution is

55

“protected by [its] expropriation of the knowledge required for the societal reproductive functions” (Mészáros 1995:800).

Social needs

To fully address social needs, participation is not just necessary in production, but also in distribution and consumption. Any socialism focused on human development requires that people “both as producers and as members of society ” determine how the results of social labour are used (Lebowitz 2009:28, emphasis added). Therefore, just as the full participation of workers is a necessary precondition for abolishing the “despotism of the workplace”, the

“tyranny of the market” and the “command economy” (imposed under twentieth century socialism) also had to be replaced with communal consumption, or, what Chávez referred to as the satisfaction of social needs – the third side of his “socialist triangle” (Mészáros

1995:742).

To achieve this, Mészáros proposed shifting from a system of production based on the exchange of commodities towards one based on the exchange of activities “in which the individuals engage, in accordance with their needs as active human beings” (Mészáros

1995:759-60). Recalling Marx’s famous quote “from each according to their ability to each according to their needs”, Mészáros argues that unless individuals are able to contribute in accordance with their abilities, that is “on the basis of the full development of the creative potentialities of the social individual”, distribution on the basis of social needs was impossible

(Mészáros 1995:759). Taking up this same theme, the Primer Plan Socialista de la Nacion

2007-2012 (First Socialist National Plan 2007-2012), which set out the policy framework for the second Chávez administration, argued “the satisfaction of social needs is tied to the system of production-distribution of goods and services, because only when workers in

Venezuela contribute to production of social wealth on the basis of this capacities, with the development of their creative potential, does the probability increase of satisfying social needs” (Republica Bolivariana de Venezuela 2007:29-30)

This would inevitably be a learning process, and not something that could be implemented overnight. However, if the goal is integral human development, “the yardstick of socialist achievements” must be whether the policies and measures implemented point in the direction

56

of consolidating a society based on “overall social control and self-management” in all spheres (Mészáros 1995:739).

As long as production focused on self-interest, humans will continue to view each other as competitors. For this reason, the focus on self-interest and “the individual right to consume things without limit” must be replaced by a focus on human development (Lebowitz 2009:28-

9). Otherwise, self-interest would inevitably remain strong and begin to infect the other sides of the triangle (Lebowitz 2010:81).

This is also a key reason as to why it is essential to move towards implementing all three sides of the “socialist triangle” simultaneously. Social property, worker participation and production for social needs have to be seen as intricately intertwined and indispensable aspects of twenty-fist century socialism, one which had set as its goal integral human development. The struggle to make this goal, enshrined in Venezuela’s constitution, a reality led Chávez to conclude that only socialism could provide a path towards human development.

The pursuit of human development was also a motivating factor behind Chávez’s original support for cogestión. Cogestión’s subsequent drift away from this initial focus not only led to a government rethink of the policy but also played a role in shaping the idea of Chávez’s

“socialist triangle”.

57

Conclusion

Many have argued that early into Chávez’s second administration, the Venezuelan government abandoned its support for cogestión and with that, worker participation. There is much evidence to backup this assertion. While Chávez mentioned cogestión when first presenting his idea of the socialist triangle, this concept soon disappeared from future speeches. Chávez would even go as far as to propose the removal of this term from the constitution. Within the workers movement, cogestión came to be seen as a dirty word

(Fuentes 2009:71). Moreover, during the first year of his second term, many of the different initiatives in cogestión were either transformed, as was the case with the EPSs and Fabrica

Adentro , or were dismantled, as occurred in ALCASA. The evidence of a government retreat on cogestión was so overwhelming, that after a visit to Venezuela in 2007, I had also arrived at the same conclusion (Munckton 2007).

However, this perspective fails to take into consideration that by the end of the first Chávez administration, the various experiments in cogestión had come to resemble something quite different from its original conception. In analyzing the new constitution, the government’s first national development plan and the early experiments in cogestión, the focus on promoting worker participation and co-governance in the economic sphere as a means of ensuring integral human development becomes apparent. By 2006 however, the focus of cogestión had shifted towards workers owning company shares, and a belief among some within the government that workers were not ready to run companies.

This shift was the result of a number of factors. The first was that the lack of a coherent and commonly agreed upon vision of cogestión had contributed to its chaotic development. The form that varying cogestión models came to take was largely shaped by the competing visions emanating from different ministries. This can be seen in the dissimilar approaches taken by different ministries in implementing cogestión and promoting EPSs

Secondly, the government’s pressing need to tackle immediate concerns such as unemployment and lifting the economy out of recession tended to militate against taking

‘risks’ that could put some of these companies in jeopardy. This was a factor in the government’s support for Fabrica Adentro , despite its questionable success in promoting

58

worker participation, and its moves to reduce the power of cooperatives in places such as

INVEPAL and to oppose cogestión in “strategic sectors” such as PDVSA.

Thirdly, the absence of a strong, unified union movement that was only just beginning to throw off the shackles of decades of entrenched right-wing bureaucratic leadership, combined with the prevalent economistic tendencies among workers more generally, also hampered the advance of this project.

Finally, there were the constant attempts by Chávez to deal with some of the very same dilemmas that had presented themselves within twenty-century socialism; specifically, the issues of ownership, production and distribution. Through this process, Chávez began first to identify cogestión with co-governance and participation, then with the social economy and collectively owned companies, and later proposed the creation of Social Production

Enterprises in an attempt to make the idea of “communal consumption” a reality.

The concrete experiences of implementing cogestión made Chávez rethink this issue and his broader ideas regarding twenty-first century socialism. Not only had the various cogestión experiments increasingly come to into conflict with Chávez’s evolving views on socialism but they had also come to resemble something diametrically opposed to its original conception.

The end result of this complex and chaotic process was the development of his socialist triangle based on social property, social production and social needs. Chávez had concluded that unless cogestión experiments were firmly located within this framework the result would inevitably be a regression towards capitalism.

Yet, in many ways, this represented not a rejection of the initial idea of cogestión, but of

‘actually existing’ cogestión. In place of social property, cogestión had come to be associated with collective ownership. While co-participation came to be equated with co-ownership, worker participation was increasingly pushed aside as problems with cogestión emerged.

Meanwhile, attempts to grapple with the third side of the triangle – satisfaction of social needs

– tended to amount to companies paying an additional tax. This was nothing like the original idea of cogestión articulated in the constitution or Chávez’s speeches.

If cogestión represented the promotion of worker participation as a means to ensure integral human development, then there is little doubt that cogestión in practice was vastly different.

59

That is, cogestión was no longer revolution . Yet, the disappearance of the term cogestión cannot necessarily be equated with an abandonment of support for worker participation.

The development of Chávez’s socialist triangle instead, represented a simultaneous return to the original ideas that had inspired the push for cogestión, only this time in a much more radical setting. Regarding social ownership , Chávez’s insistence that the Central Azucarero

Pio Tamayo should be seen as the “property and pride” of the community found its continuation in his idea of direct social property. Similarly, his comments that workers in

PDVSA had to ensure that the state oil company existed “solely to promote the interest of the republic and not the personal interests of anyone” were echoed in his advocacy of indirect social property. The initial focus on co-participation and integral human development shared much in common with the idea of social production being geared towards the creation of

“new human beings.” Finally, the somewhat vague allusions and attempts to incorporate communities in the constitution and in the Pio Tamayo sugar mill experiment respectively, found a more concrete expression, first with the emergence of the communal councils and later with the development of the third side of Chávez’s socialist triangle: producing to satisfying social needs .

The key difference was that through this process, Chávez had shifted from a viewpoint that advocated promoting the social economy as complementary to the capitalist economy, to an anti-capitalist orientation. Nevertheless, the focus on participation “of all sectors, in all spheres and in each moment of the future” and integral human development remained.

The impact of this would become apparent at an October 2007 meeting of representatives from state-owned companies and government ministers convened to debate the idea of

“socialist companies.” There, Chávez argued that it was vital to more clearly define the

Venezuelan socialist model. This involved consideration of three fundamental categories: social property, social production and distribution based on the satisfaction of social needs

(Cormenzana 2009:194).

After his initial presentation, representatives from various companies reported on how they were converting their enterprises into socialist companies. However, it was the intervention by workers from INVEVAL that caught Chávez’s attention (Cormenzana 2009:194).

Representatives from there explained how in January 2007, workers had decided to place

60

administration of the company under the control of a workers’ council, and that all workers received the same salary. They explained that, faced with PDVSA’s refusal to buy their products, the company was working with the community to find alternative markets for their production. Chávez responded that workers at INVEVAL “had understood the objective of this process” and declared the company an example to follow (Cormenzana 2009:195).

Agreeing with the workers’ proposal that INVEVAL should be 100% state-owned with the workers’ council continuing to run the company, Chávez ordered that a decree be prepared to legalise this arrangement.

Subsequently, the government also took the initiative to begin a process of introduction control obrero

(workers’ control) within CVG and the newly created Corporación Eléctrica

Nacional (CORPOELEC, National Electricity Corporation) (Fuentes 2009a; Fuentes 2010). In many respects, these moves shared much in common with the cogestión experiments in

ALCASA and CADAFE, although now on a much bigger scale. For workers in the former

CADELA (now integrated into CORPOELEC), this move represented little more than a name change, as their cogestión continued to function. However, nationally, it represented another opportunity for workers in the electrical sector and in CVG to move forward with their goal of achieving worker participation. The success or demise of control obrero is something that continues to play itself out today. No doubt the biggest challenge will be find ways to convert the ideas present in Chávez’s socialist triangle into reality. That is, twenty-first century socialism still confronts the challenge of overcoming the very same dilemmas that bedevilled the socialist experiments of last century.

Nevertheless, they can count on the lessons learned during the process of implementing cogestión during the first Chávez administration. Importantly, the initial spirit with which workers first took up the call for cogestión remains present. This was left clear to me in the comments of Nestor Rojas, a unionist in the Merida region of CORPOELEC when he told me:

What we want is worker participation in decision-making… The constitution defines this as cogestión, and that definition is nothing more than there should be coadministration between the state and workers. Maybe we have to change the word, but in the end we continue to run this company under cogestión ( cogestiónando )…

(Fuentes 2009:72)

61

It is also this vision that encapsulated the original spirit of cogestión, which today, despite the name change, is present in process of implementing control obrero .

62

Appendix

ALCASA

BCV

CADAFE

CADELA

CNV

CORPOELEC

CVG

CTV

EPS

FEDEINDUSTRIA

FETRAELEC

FRETECO

FSBT

INVEPAL

INVETEX

List of acronyms, key names and Spanish terms

CVG Caroní Aluminium, part of CVG

Central Bank of Venezuela

Electricity Generation and Administration Company, subsequently incorporated in CORPOELEC in 2007

Los Andes Electricity C.A, regional affiliate of CADAFE, which covers the western states of Merida, Tachira, Trujillo and

Barinas, now incorporated into CORPOELEC

National Valve Constructor, valve producing company nationalised in 2005 and renamed INVEVAL

National Electricity Corporation, created in 2007 as part of a process of nationalising and consolidating the electrical sector

Venezuelan Corporation of Guayana, state-owned basic industry complex comprised on 16 steel, aluminium, bauxite and mining companies

Confederation of Venezuelan Workers, main trade union federation prior to the emergence of UNETE

Social Production Enterprise

Venezuelan Federation of Small, Medium and Artisan

Industries

Federation of Venezuelan Electrical Workers

Co-mananged and Occupied Factories’ Worker Revolutionary

Front

Socialist Bolivarian Workers’ Force

Venezuelan Endogenous Paper Industry, previously named

VENEPAL before it was nationalised in 2005

Venezuelan Endogenous Textile Industry, previously named

Hilanderías Tinaquillo

(Tinaquillo Spinners) before the government bought a majority stake in the company

63

INVEVAL

MENPET

MIBAM

MILCO

MINEP

PDVSA

SIDOR

Venezuelan Endogenous Valve Industry, previously named

CNV before it was nationalised in 2005

Ministry for Energy and Petroleum,

Ministry of Basic Industry and Mining

Ministry of Light Industry and Commerce

Ministry for the Popular Economy

Venezuela Petroleum Company, state-owned oil company

Orinoco Steelworks, original part of CVG, privatised in 1998

SINTRALCASA

UNETE

VENEPAL and subsequently renationalised in 2008

CVG ALCASA Workers’ Union

National Union of Workers, largest nation-wide trade union federation in Venezuela, established in 2003

Venezuelan Pulp and Paper, paper factory nationalised in 2005 and renamed INVEPAL

Álvarez, Víctor

El Troudi, Haiman

Iglesias, Maria Cristina

Jaua, Elias

Lanz, Carlos

Ramirez, Rafael

Minister for Basic Industry, 2005-2006

Chief of Staff to President Chávez, 2005

Head of Ministry of Labour (MINTRASS), 2001-2005, Head of

MILCO 2005-2007

Head of MINEP, 2004-2006

President of ALCASA, 2005-2007

Head of MENPET, 2002-present

Alcasiano(s)

Aló Presidente

Refers to worker(s) at ALCASA

President Chávez’s weekly television program

Autogestión Self-management

Barrios

Chavista

Cogestión

Poor neighbourhoods

Chávez supporter

Generally translated as co-management

Cogestión revolucionaria

Revolutionary co-management

64

Comités de gestión

Comités guia

Control obrero

Esperanza Patriótica

Fabrica Adentro

Fabricas recuperadas

Mesas de trabajo

Vocero(s)

Management committees, set up by electrical workers as part of the cogestión process in CADAFE and CADELA

Guide committees, set up by PDVSA workers during the bosses lock-out in December 2002-January 2003

Workers’ control

Patriotic Hope, party which Rafael Ramirez belonged to together with others within PDVSA (e.g. Toby Valderrama).

Behind the publication of the daily column Un Grano de Maiz

“Inside the Factory” program involving privately owned companies that signed up to the Framework Agreement of Coresponsibility for Industry Transformation

Recuperated factories taken over by workers

Work committees, set up at the departmental level as part of the cogestión process in ALCASA

Spokesperson(s)

65

Timeline of key events related to cogestión during first Chávez administration (1999-2006)

July

March

December

April

July

August

December

1998

Hugo Chávez elected President of Venezuela

1999

Successful referendum held to convene constituent assembly to rewrite

Venezuelan constitution.

Elections held for constituent assembly.

constituent assembly convenes.

New constitution approved by referendum.

2000

Chávez re-elected within context of new constitution.

April

November

2001

First national development plan approved by National Assembly

First cogestión experiment initiated at Central Azucarero Pío Tamayo sugar mill.

FETRAELEC and CADAFE board of directors sign Declaration of

Principles within which the figure of cogestión appears.

Chávez enacts 49 law-decrees covering a range of areas including oil, cooperatives and land reform.

66

April

July

September

October

December

2002

Unsuccessful military coup launched against Chávez.

Rafael Ramirez appointed to head up MENPET.

Meeting of independent and pro-revolution unionists to discuss

‘refounding’ the labour movement.

Live televised meeting between hundreds of union leaders and

President Chávez.

Management lockout at state oil company PDVSA begins, numerous other companies shut down as part of co-ordinated campaign to sabotage Venezuela’s economy.

Pro-Chávez unionists call on the government to issue a decree that would allow workers to take over these companies

February

March

April

2003

Management lockout at PDVSA defeated; company now in firm control of the Chávez government.

Chávez appointed two union leaders to the board of directors at

PDVSA.

Chávez appointed two union leaders to the board of directors at

CADAFE.

Pro-revolution trade union confederation Union Nacional de

Trabajadores (UNETE) is formed.

August

September

November

2004

Chavez wins recall referendum

MINEP created, entrusted with promoting the social economy. Elias

Jaua appointed to head up the new ministry.

Conflict officially starts in CADAFE.

67

January

February

March

April

May

June

July

August

October

November

2005

VENEPAL paper company nationalised, renamed INVEPAL and handed over to workers to run under cogestión.

MIBAM created, Victor Alvarez appointed to head up the new ministry.

Carlos Lanz appointed president of ALCASA.

Agreement signed between state, managers and unions to initiate cogestión process in state aluminium plant, ALCASA.

Workers at ALCASA begin process of electing managers and voceros.

CNV valve producing company nationalised, renamed INVEVAL and handed over to workers to run under cogestión.

Million strong May Day marched organised. UNETE leaders present

Chávez a draft law on cogestión.

Government buys out majority stake in Hilanderías Tinaquillo textile factory, converts it into INVETEX and begins process of cogestión.

Participatory budget process begins in ALCASA.

Chávez calls for the creation of Social Production Enterprises (EPSs).

Reads out a list of over 1000 partial or completely closed down factories, calling on workers to take them over.

“Negro Primero” Socio-Political Education Centre established in

ALCASA

Launched Fabrica Adentro dedicated to introducing cogestión into the private sector.

Process of autogesti

ó n (self-management with workers owning 100% of the enterprise) begins at Hotel Kamarata.

Latin America wide gathering of workers from occupied and recuperated factories held in Caracas.

Two members of nearby communities elected onto company board at

ALCASA.

Workers at INVEPAL vote to revoke mandate of their elected representatives to the company board.

68

December

Exhibition involving 160 EPSs that have dealings with PDVSA hosted.

CVG announced creation of 260 EPS to date.

January

February

April

June

September

December

2006

Union elections at ALCASA see victory of opposition-aligned ticket and ouster of pro-Chávez incumbents.

Chávez comes out against cogestión, at least in ‘strategic sectors’ such as PDVSA.

Workers from INVEVAL, INVEPAL and other recuperated factories create FRETECO.

Third phase of cogestión process begins in ALCASA as workers start discussing issue of workers council and reduction of the workday in context of new collective contract.

Minster of Light Industry, María Cristina Iglesias, appointed as new president of INVEPAL.

Workers at ALCASA vote to return to a system of single managerial posts, and subsequently elect many of the same managers that had been removed in previous elections.

Figure of workers’ Council inserted into collective contract at

ALCASA.

Chávez re-elected as president.

69

Bibliography

Aldana, Claudia E. (2010) “Canicultores y trabajadores exigen liquidación de acciones”

El

Impulso 25/10/2010. Last accessed June 4, 2011 at http://www.elimpulso.com/pages/vernoticia.aspx?id=110389

Alfonso A., Carmen Sofía (2008) “Cogestión fracaso por desconocimiento del modelo”

El

Nacional 14/4/2008, p. 4.

Alonso, Osvaldo (2007)

Nuevas Formas de Propiedad y de Gestión de las Organizaciones de la Transición hacia el Socialismo del Siglo XXI

. ILDIS & FIM Productividad, Caracas.

Aló Presidente (2002) “Aló Presidente No. 92” Aló Presidente

, 13/01/2002. Last accessed

April 12, 2011 at http://www.alopresidente.gob.ve/materia_alo/25/1679/?visual=alo_presidente_89_terminal_d e_pasajeros_de_la_guaira,_vargas_16_de_diciembre_de_2001.pdf

- (2005) “Aló Presidente No. 213”

Aló Presidente

, 20/02/2005. Last accessed May 3,

2011 at http://www.alopresidente.gob.ve/materia_alo/25/1272/?visual=Alo_Presidente_213.pd

f

- (2005a) “Aló Presidente No. 229”

Aló Presidente

, 17/07/2005. Last accessed May 3,

2011 at http://www.alopresidente.gob.ve/materia_alo/25/1286/?visual=Alo_Presidente_229.pd

f

- (2005b) “Aló Presidente No. 241”

Aló Presidente

, 27/11/2005. Last accessed June

13, 2011 at http://www.alopresidente.gob.ve/materia_alo/25/1297/?visual=Alo_Presidente_241.pd

f

70

- (2006) “Aló Presidente No. 244”

Aló Presidente

, 15/01/2006. Last accessed June 13,

2011 at http://www.alopresidente.gob.ve/materia_alo/25/1300/?visual=Alo_Presidente_244.pd

f

- (2007) “Aló Presidente No. 263” Aló Presidente , 21/01/2007. Last accessed April 4,

2011 at http://www.alopresidente.gob.ve/materia_alo/25/1406/?visual=Alo_Presidente_263.pd

f

- (2007a) “Aló Presidente No. 264”

Aló Presidente

, 28/01/2007. Last accessed April 4,

2011 at http://www.alopresidente.gob.ve/materia_alo/25/1415/?visual=Alo_Presidente_264.pd

f

Álvarez R., Víctor (2009) ¿Hacia donde va el modelo productivo?

CIM, Caracas.

Álvarez R. Víctor & Rodríguez A. Davgla (2008) Guía teórico-practica para la creación de

Empresas de Producción Socialista

. La Pupila Insomne, Caracas.

Aponte, Antonio (2007)

¡Hagamoslo, no hay excusa! 100 Granos de Maíz . Misión

Conciencia & Fondo Editorial Fabricio Ojeda, Barcelona.

- (2007a) La hora de los hornos. Otros 100 Granos de Maíz . Misión Conciencia &

Fondo Editorial Fabricio Ojeda, Barcelona.

Asamblea Nacional Constituyente (2003)

Constitución de la Republica Bolivariana de

Venezuela, 1999. Asamblea Nacional, Caracas.

Azzellini, Dario (2009) “Economía solidaria, formas de propiedad colectiva, nacionalizaciones, empresas socialistas, co- y autogestión en Venezuela.” ORG y DEMO , v.10, n.1/2, jan./dez., 2009, pp.5-30.

71

- (2010) “Economía Solidaria y ecosociodesarrollo: la construcción de una nueva percepción de la sustentabilidad” Otra Economía

, Vol. IV, No. 6, 1er semestre, 2010, pp.134-151.

- (2011) “Workers’ Control under Venezuela’s Bolivarian Revolution” in Ness,

Immanuel & Azzellini, Dario (ed) (2011) Ours to Master and to Own: Workers’

Control from the Commune to the Present . Haymarket Books, Chicago, pp.382-399.

Barrios Nieves, Froilán A. (2005) “Congestión obrero chavista ¿Solución revolucionaria o contrabando neocorporativista?”

Analitica.com

, Last accessed on May 17, 2011 at http://www.analitica.com/va/politica/documentos/3491195.asp

Bilbao, Luís (2007) Revolución en Venezuela

. Fundación Editorial el perro y la rana, Caracas.

- (2008)

Venezuela en Revolución: Renacimiento del socialismo

. Le Monde

Diplomatique, Buenos Aires.

Blankenburg, Stephanie (2008) “El Estado y la revolución. Reestatización del Banco del grupo Santander” América XXI

, No. 41, Septiembre 2008, pp.18-21.

Borrego, Orlando (2006)

Rumbo al Socialismo: Problemas del sistema económico y la dirección empresarial

. Editorial de Ciencias Sociales, La Habana.

Bruce, Iain (2008) The Real Venezuela: Making Socialism in the 21 st Century . Pluto Press,

London.

Cabieses Donoso, Manuel (2008) “La dura batalla por el socialismo”

Punto Final , edicion No

666, 11 de Julio de 2008. Last accessed on August 17, 2011 at http://www.puntofinal.cl/666/batalla.php

Campos, Miguel (2006) “Un ano después… ¿Qué ocurre en Invepal?”

Aporrea , 21/03/06.

Last accessed on August 17, 2011 at http://www.aporrea.org/trabajadores/a20447.html

72

Carcione, Carlos (2009) “‘Lo que fue privatizado nacionalícese’” in

Comuna: pensamiento critico en la revolución

, Num. 1, Año 1, oct/nov/dic 2009, pp.13-22.

Cerceau, Guillermo (2007)

Experiencia de Cogestión en CADAFE y el papel del Movimiento

Sindical den dicho proceso. Lecciones aprendidas y estrategias para avanzar.

ILDIS,

Caracas.

Chávez Frías, Hugo (2007) Esta Revolución no tiene vuelta atrás . MINCI, Caracas

- (2007a) Ahora la batalla es por el SI . MINCI, Caracas

Cibank, Rodolfo (2005) “Revolución, desarrollo y formas de propiedad”

Voltarie ,

16/12/2005. Last accessed on May 17, 2011 at http://www.voltairenet.org/Revoluciondesarrollo-y-formas-de

Ciccariello-Maher, George (2007) “The Legacy of Caracazo: The Fourth World War Started in Venezuela”,

Counterpunch , Weekend Edition March 3-5, 2007. Last accessed on

September 2, 2011 at http://www.counterpunch.org/2007/03/03/the-fourth-world-war-startedin-venezuela/

Comité de Refundación (2005)

Resoluciones de la Junta Directiva vinculadas al proceso de refundación de CADAFE y sus empresas filiales . Dirección Ejecutiva de Gestión Social y

Comunicación, Caracas.

Comité Guía (2003) Propuesta del Comité Guía para la construcción de la Nueva PDVSA .

Personal copy.

Comités Guía de la industria petrolera (2004) “Remitido de los Comités Guía de la industria petrolera” Soberanía

, 04/02/04. Last accessed on September 2, 2011 http://www.soberania.org/Articulos/articulo_719.htm

Coronil, Fernando (1997) The Magical State: Nature, Money and Modernity in Venezuela .

University of Chicago Press, Chicago.

73

- (2008) “Chávez’s Venezuela: A New Magical State?” ReVista: Harvard Review of

Latin America , Volume VIII, Number 1, Fall 2008, pp.3-4.

- (2008a) “It’s the Oil, Stupid!!!” ReVista: Harvard Review of Latin America , Volume

VIII, Number 1, Fall 2008, pp.18-20.

Cormenzana, Pablo (2005) “Invetex, la cenicienta de la cogestión”, Aporrea , 20/11/05. Last accessed on May 24, 2011 at http://www.aporrea.org/endogeno/a17941.html

- (2009) La batalla de Inveval: la lucha por el control obrero en Venezuela.

Fundación Federico Engels, Madrid.

CVG Alcasa (2005) “Resumen ejecutivo sobre el proceso de cogestión en CVG Alcasa” in

MIBAM (2006)

Crónica y documentos del proceso de Cogestión en CVG Alcasa (Febrero –

Mayo/Vol. 1, Hojas de Cogestión No 1 a la 42)

. CVG Alcasa, Puerto Ordaz.

- (2006)

Crónica y documentos del proceso de Cogestión en CVG Alcasa (Febrero –

Mayo 2006/Vol. 1, Hojas de Cogestión No 1 a la 42)

. CVG Alcasa, Puerto Ordaz.

- (2007)

Crónica y documentos del proceso de Cogestión en CVG Alcasa (Mayo 2006-

Marzo 2007/Vol. 2, Hojas de Cogestión No 43 a la 196)

. CVG Alcasa, Puerto Ordaz.

Despacho del Presidente (2005) 2002 “Año de la Resistencia Antiimperialista”: Selección de discursos del Presidente de la Republica Bolivariana de Venezuela, Hugo Chávez Frías .

Ediciones de la Presidencia de La Republica, Caracas.

- (2005a)

2003 “Año de la Contraofensiva Revolucionaria y la Victoria

Antiimperialista”: Selección de discursos del Presidente de la Republica Bolivariana de Venezuela, Hugo Chávez Frías

. Ediciones de la Presidencia de La Republica,

Caracas.

- (2005b)

2005 “Año del Salto Adelante”: Selección de discursos del Presidente de la

Republica Bolivariana de Venezuela, Hugo Chávez Frías

. Ediciones de la Presidencia de La Republica, Caracas.

74

EFE (2005) “Los ‘chavistas’ amenazan con paralizar el sector eléctrico”

El Dia , 8 de marzo de 2005. Last accessed on April 29, 2011 at http://www.eldia.es/2005-03-

08/venezuela/venezuela305.htm

El Troudi, Haiman (2006) Nos invitaron a debatir sobre el Socialismo del Siglo XXI . Centro

Internacional Miranda, Caracas.

- (2010)

La Política Económica Bolivariana (PEB) y los dilemas de la transición socialista en Venezuela

. Monte Ávila, Caracas.

El Troudi, Haiman & Monedero, Juan Carlos (2006)

Empresas de Producción Social: La reinvención de la economía rumbo al socialismo del siglo XXI

. Centro Internacional Miranda,

Caracas.

Ellner, Steve (1993) Organised Labor in Venezuela 1958-1991: Behavior and Concerns in a

Democratic Setting . Scholarly Resources Inc., Wilmington.

- (2006) “The Venezuelan Labor Movement Under Chávez: Autonomous Branch of

Civil Society or Instrument of Political Control?” A Contracorriente , Vol. 2, No. 3.

Spring 2005, pp.102-125.

Encuentro Nacional de Trabajadores (2002) “Hacia la refundación del movimiento sindical”

Rebelión , 17/09/02. Last accessed on August 2, 2011 at http://www.rebelion.org/hemeroteca/venezuela/ent170902.htm

Fernández, Germania (2006) “Cuando la clase obrera toma el control”

Rebelion , 13-06-2006.

Last accessed on April 14, 2011 at http://www.rebelion.org/noticia.php?id=32981

FETRAELEC (2005) Pliego conciliatorio cogestiónario . Series de Documentos No. 1.

FETRAELEC, Caracas.

- (2005a)

La cogestión es la madre de todas las reivindicaciones

. Series de

Documentos No. 2. FETRAELEC, Caracas.

75

- (2005b)

Propuesta de reforma de la Ley de Servicio Eléctrico

. Series de Documentos

No. 3. FETRAELEC, Caracas.

- (2005c) Documento para el debate de la cogestión . Series de Documentos No. 4.

FETRAELEC, Caracas.

FRETECO (2006) “Manifestó fundacional del Frente Revolucionario de Trabajadores de

Empresas Cogestiónadas y Ocupadas” in FRETECO (2007)

El FRETECO y la Empresa

Socialista

. Fundación Federico Engels de Venezuela, Los Teques.

- (2007) El FRETECO y la Empresa Socialista

. Fundación Federico Engels de

Venezuela, Los Teques.

- (2007a) “La Asamblea Nacional de Venezuela pide la expropiación de Sanitarios

Maracay”

FRETECO , 1 de junio de 2007. Last accessed on October 1, 2011 at http://www.controlobrero.org/content/view/134/1/

Fuentes, Federico (2009) “Solo con la participación de los trabajadores el sector eléctrico tendrá una salida” in Comuna: pensamiento critico en la revolución , Num. 1, Año 1, oct/nov/dic 2009, pp.56-93.

- (2009a) “Venezuela: 'When the working class roars, capitalists tremble'”, Green Left

Weekly , May 30, 2009. Last accessed on October 1, 2011 at http://www.greenleft.org.au/node/41751

- (2010) “Venezuela: Workers' control to solve power problems” Green Left Weekly ,

April 17, 2010. Last accessed on October 1, 2011 at http://www.greenleft.org.au/node/43647

Gaceta Oficial (2001) “Numero 37.285, Decreto No 1.440” Gaceta Oficial de la Republica

Bolivariana de Venezuela , Caracas, jueves 18 de septiembre de 2001.

76

- (2004) “Numero 38.024, Decreto No 3.125” Gaceta Oficial de la Republica

Bolivariana de Venezuela , Caracas, jueves 16 de septiembre de 2004.

- (2005) “Numero 38.188, Decreto No 3.652” Gaceta Oficial de la Republica

Bolivariana de Venezuela , Caracas, martes 17 de mayo de 2005.

- (2005a) “Numero 38.271, Decreto No 3.895 Desarrollo Endógeno y empresas de producción social” Gaceta Oficial de la Republica Bolivariana de Venezuela , Caracas, martes 13 de septiembre de 2005.

Gerencia de Asuntos Públicos, CVG Alcasa (2005) “Cogestión: Todo el poder para las trabajadores” 2 de marzo de 2005, No. 4 in CVG Alcasa (2006) Crónica y documentos del proceso de Cogestión en CVG Alcasa (Febrero – Mayo 2006/Vol. 1, Hojas de Cogestión No 1 a la 42) . CVG Alcasa, Puerto Ordaz.

- (2005a) “Cogestión: Todo el poder para las trabajadores” 4 de marzo de 2005, No. 6 in CVG Alcasa (2006)

Crónica y documentos del proceso de Cogestión en CVG

Alcasa (Febrero – Mayo 2006/Vol. 1, Hojas de Cogestión No 1 a la 42) . CVG Alcasa,

Puerto Ordaz.

- (2005b) “Cogestión con producción: Todo el poder para las trabajadores” 30 de mayo de 2005, No. 42 in CVG Alcasa (2006)

Crónica y documentos del proceso de

Cogestión en CVG Alcasa (Febrero – Mayo 2006/Vol. 1, Hojas de Cogestión No 1 a la 42) . CVG Alcasa, Puerto Ordaz.

- (2005c) “Cogestión con producción: Todo el poder para las trabajadores” 6 de junio de 2005, No. 44 in CVG Alcasa (2006)

Crónica y documentos del proceso de

Cogestión en CVG Alcasa (Febrero – Mayo 2006/Vol. 1, Hojas de Cogestión No 1 a la 42) . CVG Alcasa, Puerto Ordaz.

- (2005d) “Cogestión con producción: Todo el poder para las trabajadores” 30 de junio de 2005, No. 53 in CVG Alcasa (2006)

Crónica y documentos del proceso de

Cogestión en CVG Alcasa (Febrero – Mayo 2006/Vol. 1, Hojas de Cogestión No 1 a la 42) . CVG Alcasa, Puerto Ordaz.

77

- (2005e) “Cogestión con producción: Todo el poder para las trabajadores” 11 de julio de 2005, No. 54 in CVG Alcasa (2006)

Crónica y documentos del proceso de

Cogestión en CVG Alcasa (Febrero – Mayo 2006/Vol. 1, Hojas de Cogestión No 1 a la 42) . CVG Alcasa, Puerto Ordaz.

- (2005f) “Cogestión con producción: Todo el poder para las trabajadores” 26 de julio de 2005, No. 56 in CVG Alcasa (2006) Crónica y documentos del proceso de

Cogestión en CVG Alcasa (Febrero – Mayo 2006/Vol. 1, Hojas de Cogestión No 1 a la 42) . CVG Alcasa, Puerto Ordaz.

- (2005g) “Cogestión con producción: Todo el poder para las trabajadores” 8 de agosto de 2005, No. 58 in CVG Alcasa (2006)

Crónica y documentos del proceso de

Cogestión en CVG Alcasa (Febrero – Mayo 2006/Vol. 1, Hojas de Cogestión No 1 a la 42) . CVG Alcasa, Puerto Ordaz.

- (2005h) “Cogestión con producción: Todo el poder para las trabajadores” 27 de septiembre de 2005, No. 69 in CVG Alcasa (2006)

Crónica y documentos del proceso de Cogestión en CVG Alcasa (Febrero – Mayo 2006/Vol. 1, Hojas de Cogestión No 1 a la 42) . CVG Alcasa, Puerto Ordaz.

- (2006a) “Cogestión con cambio en la relaciones de producción: Todo el poder para las trabajadores” 25 de abril de 2006, No. 40 in CVG Alcasa (2006) Crónica y documentos del proceso de Cogestión en CVG Alcasa (Febrero – Mayo 2006/Vol. 1,

Hojas de Cogestión No 1 a la 42) . CVG Alcasa, Puerto Ordaz.

- (2006b) “Cogestión con cambio en la relaciones de producción: Todo el poder para las trabajadores” 14 de junio de 2006, No. 66 in CVG Alcasa (2007) Crónica y documentos del proceso de Cogestión en CVG Alcasa (Mayo 2006-Marzo 2007/Vol. II

Hojas de Cogestión No 43 a la 196)

. CVG Alcasa, Puerto Ordaz.

- (2006c) “Cogestión con cambio en la relaciones de producción: Todo el poder para las trabajadores” 21 de junio de 2006, CVG Alcasa (2007) Crónica y documentos del

78

proceso de Cogestión en CVG Alcasa (Mayo 2006-Marzo 2007/Vol. II Hojas de

Cogestión No 43 a la 196)

. CVG Alcasa, Puerto Ordaz.

- (2006d) “Cogestión con cambio en la relaciones de producción: Todo el poder para las trabajadores” 20 de septiembre de 2006, No. 113 in CVG Alcasa (2007) Crónica y documentos del proceso de Cogestión en CVG Alcasa (Mayo 2006-Marzo 2007/Vol. II

Hojas de Cogestión No 43 a la 196) . CVG Alcasa, Puerto Ordaz.

Godio, Julio (1986) 50 anos de la C.T.V. (1936-1986) Historia, Doctrina y Acción . IDLIS,

Caracas.

Gómez, Gonzalo; Tábata, Américo; & Gámez, Nelson (2005) Orlando Chirinos…. Responde

.

Apo-reportajes, Caracas.

Harnecker, Marta (2003) Venezuela: Militares junto al pueblo.

El Viejo Topo, Madrid.

- (2005)

Los desafíos de la cogestión (Las experiencias de Cadafe y Cadela)

. La

Burbuja editorial, Caracas.

- (2005a) “Trabajadores eligen a sus gerentes y aumentan la producción”

Rebelión

, 29-

03-2005, Last accessed on June 4, 2011 at http://www.rebelion.org/noticia.php?id=13176

Hernández, Katiuska (2010) “En la industria azucarera fracaso el modelo socialista de cogestión” El Nacional . Last accessed on May 25, 2011 at http://www.reportero24.com/2010/11/en-la-industria-azucarera-fracaso-el-modelo-socialistade-cogestión/

Janicke, Kiraz (2009) “Venezuela’s Co-Managed Inveval: Surviving in a Sea of Capitalism”,

Venezuela Analysis , July 27th 2007. Last accessed on September 7, 2011 at http://venezuelanalysis.com/analysis/2520?page=1

Jaua Milano, Elías (2005) Nuevo modelo socio-productivo y desarrollo endógeno . MINEP,

Caracas.

79

Lander, Luís. E (ed) (2003) Poder y Petróleo en Venezuela

. FACES-UCV, Caracas.

Lanz Rodríguez, Carlos (2005) “Dossier para la critica de la división social del trabajo” in

CVG Alcasa (2006) Crónica y documentos del proceso de Cogestión en CVG Alcasa

(Febrero – Mayo/Vol. 1, Hojas de Cogestión No 1 a la 42) . CVG Alcasa, Puerto Ordaz.

- (2005a) El socialismo y la cogestión revolucionaria . CVG Alcasa, Puerto Ordaz.

- (2007)

Balance y perspectiva de la Cogestión en CVG Alcasa

. CVG Alcasa, Puerto

Ordaz.

- (2009) “Dossier sobre CVG y las empresas del sector aluminio”. Aporrea , 12/03/09 .

Last accessed on July 14, 2011 at http://www.aporrea.org/media/2009/03/dossier_sobre_cvg_y_las_empresas_del_alumi nio-1.doc

Lebowitz, Michael A. (2004) Lecciones de la autogestión yugoslava.

Centro Internacional

Miranda, Caracas.

- (2006) Build It Now: Socialism for the Twenty-First Century. Monthly Review Press,

New York.

- (2006a) El Socialismo No Cae Del Cielo . MINCI, Caracas.

- (2007) “Venezuela: A Good Example of the Bad Left of Latin America” Monthly

Review , July-August 2007, Volume 59, Number 3, pp.38-54.

- (2009) The Path to Human Development: Capitalism or Socialism?

Socialist Project,

Toronto.

- (2010) The Socialist Alternative: Real Human Development . Monthly Review Press,

New York.

80

López Maya, Margarita (2002) Protesta y cultura en Venezuela: los marcos de acción colectiva en 1999 . CLACSO, Buenos Aires.

Lucena, Héctor (2006) “Empresas recuperadas: posibilidades y limitaciones a partir de la experiencia con INVEPAL” Section on Venezuelan Studies of the Latin American Studies

Association . Last accessed on June 17, 2011 at http://svs.osu.edu/documents/Hector_Lucena_y_HermesCarmona-

EMPRESASRECUPERADASCASOINVEPAL.pdf

Lugo, Iramia; Vessuri, Hebe; & Canino Victoria (2008) “INVEVAL: una experiencia en el desarrollo de las capacidades tecnoproductivas en Venezuela.”

Dpto. de Estudios de la

Ciencia – Instituto Venezolano de Investigaciones Cientificas.

Last accessed April 12, 2011 at http://www.necso.ufrj.br/esocite2008/trabalhos/36023.doc

Mastronardi, Nancy (2011) “Presidente Chávez: El socialismo nuestro debe ser una creación heroica”

Correo del Orinoco , 7 agosto 2011. Last accessed on August 12, 2011 at http://www.correodelorinoco.gob.ve/nacionales/presidente-Chávez-socialismo-nuestro-debeser-una-creacion-heroica/

Mather, Steven (2006) “Conference of Co-managed and Occupied Factories Workers’

Revolutionary Front”

Venezuela Analysis , 25/10/2006. Last accessed on April 2, 2011 at http://venezuelanalysis.com/analysis/2029?page=2

McCaughan, M. (2004) The Battle of Venezuela . Latin America Bureau, London.

Medina, Medófilo; López Maya, Margarita; & Lander, Luis (2007) Chávez: una revolución sin libreto . Ediciones Aurora, Bogota.

Mendoza, Jorge (2006) “¿La Cogestión un paso al reformismo o al Socialismo en el caso de

Invepal?” Rebelión

, 01/07/2006. Last accessed July 7, 2011 at http://www.rebelion.org/noticia.php?id=33823

Mészáros, István (1995) Beyond Capital: Towards a theory of transition. Monthly Review

Press, New York.

81

- (2001)

From the “American Century” to the Crossroads: Socialism of Barbarism

.

Monthly Review Press, New York.

- (2008) The Challenge and Burden of Historical Time: Socialism in the Twenty-First

Century . Monthly Review Press, New York.

MIBAM (2005) Lanzamiento de las Empresas de Producción Social, Ciudad Guayana .

MIBAM, Caracas.

MINCI (2005) “Transcripcion de lanzamiento del Acuerdo Marco de Corresponsabilidad para la Transformación Industrial”

MINCI . Last accessed on April 28, 2011 at http://www.minci.gob.ve/documentos/9/10343/?desc=acuerdo260505.doc

- (2006) Empresas recuperadas . MINCI, Caracas.

- (2006a)

Empresas de Producción Social: Nuevas oportunidades para el desarrollo

.

MINCI, Caracas.

MINEP (2005) Cooperativismo revolucionario: Eje de Formación Sociopolítica . MINEP,

Caracas.

Mommer, Bernard (2003) “Petróleo subversivo” in Lander, Luís. E (ed) (2003)

Poder y

Petróleo en Venezuela . FACES-UCV, Caracas, pp.19-40.

Moreno, Yonie (2006) “Comentarios al articulo aparecido en Ultimas Noticias el 11 de junio de 2006: ‘Las mentiras al presidente: Tomatera cerrada, cogestión estancada y proyectos que no se cumplen”

Aporrea , 15/06/06. Last accessed July 7, 2011 at http://www.aporrea.org/trabajadores/a22713.html

MPD (2001)

Líneas Generales del Plan de Desarrollo Económico y Social de la Nación

2001-2007 . MPD, Caracas.

Munckton, Stuart (2007) “Venezuela: The struggle for workers' power”,

Green Left Weekly ,

July 28, 2007. Last accessed July 7, 2011 at http://www.greenleft.org.au/node/38068

82

Navas, Ángel & Osorio, Joaquín (2007) “Comentarios sobre la Ponencia ‘Experiencias de

Cogestión en CADAFE: Lecciones Aprendidas’”

IDLIS , Last accessed August 17, 2011 at http://www.ildis.org.ve/website/administrador/uploads/ComentarioANavasyJOsorioCogestión

.pdf

Ness, Immanuel & Azzellini, Dario (ed) (2011) Ours to Master and to Own: Workers’

Control from the Commune to the Present . Haymarket Books, Chicago.

Osorio, Joaquín (2005) “La cogestión es poder para los trabajadores y el pueblo”

La Fuerza,

Hoja Informativa de la Fuerza Bolivariana de Trabajadores

. No 4 Año 1 Junio 14 de 2005, pp.6-8.

PDVSA (2006)

Una vía para democratizar la riqueza petrolera

. Series Sobre Empresas de

Producción Social, PDVSA, Caracas.

- (2006a) Preguntas y Respuestas.

Series Sobre Empresas de Producción Social,

PDVSA, Caracas.

Peña Rojas, Gonzalo (2006) “Co-management at work in Venezuela: A field study of the comanagement process in the state owned aluminium plant Alcasa” Lund University,

Department of Political Science. Last accessed July 7, 2011 at http://lup.lub.lu.se/luur/download?func=downloadFile&recordOId=1322089&fileOId=13220

90

Pérez Vigil, Ismael (2005) “Venezuela y la cogestión bolivariana” Analitica.com

, 9 de marzo de 2005. Last accessed April 16, 2011 at http://www.analitica.com/va/politica/opinion/5100849.asp

Piñeiro Harnecker, Camila (2008) “Principales desafíos de las cooperativas en Venezuela” in

Capaya, Revista Venezolana de Economía Social , Año 8, Nº 15, Enero-Junio 2008, pp.37-60.

83

Plan Guayana Socialista (2009) “Plan Guayana Socialista 2010-2019” in Critica de Nuestro

Tiempo. Revista Internacional de Teoría y Política . Año XIX – No 39-30. Octubre 2009 –

Marzo 2010, pp.48-60.

Pollack, Paul (2006) “Building Labor's Revolutionary Voice in Venezuela: The UNT's second national Congress” Upside Down World, 04 June 2006. Last accessed October 30, 2011 at http://upsidedownworld.org/main/venezuela-archives-35/311-building-labors-revolutionaryvoice-in-venezuela-the-unts-second-national-congress

Rangel, Angie (2006) “Trabajadores y empresarios es unen para el desarrollo” MINCI , 24 de marzo de 2006. Last accessed June 17, 2011 at http://www.minci.gob.ve/pagina/1/4451/completa.prnt/

Ramírez, Rafael (2005) Los trabajadores petroleros están al servicio del pueblo

. Serie discursos, PDVSA, Caracas.

Republica Bolivariana de Venezuela (2007)

Proyecto Nacional “Simon Bolivar” Primer Plan

Socialista de la Nacion Republica Bolivariana de Venezuela Presidencia, Caracas

Riera, Miguel (2008) “Profundizar en la Revolución: Entrevista a Orlando Chirinos”

El Viejo

Topo , Num. 249, Octubre 2008, pp. 53-57.

Rodríguez, Carlos (2006) “Entrevista de El Topo Obrero a Ramón Lagartera, Presidente de

Covimpa (Cooperativa de los trabajadores de Invepal)” El Militante , 19 Marzo 2006, p.4.

Rodríguez, Rafael (2005) “La subversión en Alcasa” Aporrea , 06/07/05. Last accessed

February 11, 2011 at http://www.aporrea.org/actualidad/a15209.html

Sanabria, William & Moreno, Yonie (2009) “La batalla de Inveval: UN ejemplo y una fuente de lecciones para todo el movimiento obrero venezolano” in Cormenzana, Pablo (2009) La batalla de Inveval: La lucha por el control obrero en Venezuela

. Fundación Federico Engels,

Madrid, pp.19-26.

84

Tejero Puntes, Suhelis (2006) “Invetex con más sobresaltos”

El Universal , domingo 13 de agosto de 2006. Last accessed on May 10, 2011 at http://www.eluniversal.com/2006/08/13/eco_art_13202A.shtml

Trabajadores despedidos de Invepal (2006) “Hacer socialmente rentable una empresa quebrada por el capitalismo neoliberal” Aporrea , 18/07/2006. Last accessed on July 17, 2011 at http://www.aporrea.org/trabajadores/a23643.html

Ramírez, Luisana & Trabajadores despedidos de Invepal (2006) “Invepal: desorden administrativo o algo mas”

Aporrea , 08/08/06. Last accessed on July 17, 2011 at http://www.aporrea.org/trabajadores/a24269.html

Últimas Noticias (2006) “Corrupción: Van 17 involucrados en estafa a central azucarero”

Aporrea , 02/02/06. Last accessed on July 17, 2011 at http://www.aporrea.org/actualidad/n72623.html

- (2006a) “La cogestión aun no tiene forma” Rebelion , 2/8/06. Last accessed on March

17, 2011 at http://www.rebelion.org/noticia.php?id=35482

UNETE (2005)

Proyecto de ley de participación de trabajadores y trabajadoras en la gestión en empresas publicas y privadas . Personal copy.

Valderrama, Toby (2010) “¿Control obrero, o control de la clase obrera?” Un Grano de Maiz ,

15.6.10. Last accessed on October 15, 2011 at http://www.revolucionomuerte.org/index.php/editorial/1645-icontrol-obrero-o-control-de-laclase-obrera

Valderrama, Toby & Mena, Alejandro (2005) Rumbo al socialismo

. Fondo Editorial “Fabricio

Ojeda”, Misión Ribas & Misión Conciencia, Barcelona

Varios (2002) “Reunión de los dirigentes sindicales autónomos y democráticos” Aporrea ,

31/10/02. Last accessed on August 27, 2011 at http://www.aporrea.org/actualidad/a854.html

85

Vera Colina, Mary A. (2006) “Cogestión de empresas y transformación del sistema economcio en Venezuela: Algunas reflexiones”

Gaceta Laboral , Vol.12 No. 2. Mayo-Agosto,

2006, pp.171-186.

Venpres (2002) “Chávez: Modelo económico pasa por la autogestión y cogestión de los propios trabajadores” Aporrea 10/11/02. Last accessed on June 25, 2011 at http://www.aporrea.org/actualidad/n1399.html

Vitale, Luís (1984)

Estado y Estructura de Clases en la Venezuela Contemporánea . UCV,

Caracas. Last accessed on March 15, 2011 at http://www.archivochile.com/Ideas_Autores/vitalel/2lvc/02lvchistsocal0039.pdf

Vive Tv (2006) “Invepal nombró nueva Junta Directiva”

Vive Tv , 12 de abril de 2006. Last accessed on August 18, 2011 at http://www.vive.gob.ve/imprimir.php?id_not=1379

Wilpert, Gregory (ed) (2003)

Coup Against Chávez in Venezuela

. Fundación Venezolana para la Justicia Global, Caracas.

86

Download