The Eurobond Proposals, Comments, and Speeches Erik Jones Professor of European Studies SAIS Bologna Center Director Bologna Institute for Policy Research 25 May 2012 The Eurobond: Proposals, Comments, Speeches Erik Jones This packet contains materials that I wrote during the period from February 2010 to April 2012. Most of this material centers on the idea to create a common eurobond with limited drawing rights. Originally, this idea was intended to strengthen fiscal discipline within the eurozone by creating market incentives for highly indebted countries to borrow less. Over time, it has developed as arguably the ‘best’ solution for responding to Europe’s sovereign debt crisis. This intellectual history is important. Right now, the strongest opposition to the eurobond proposal comes from those who think it gives highly indebted countries a free ride. Once you read through this packet, it will be easy to see why such arguments are mistaken. The first piece is a eurobond proposal that I drafted for ISPI in Milan in February 2010. When the proposal came out, it emerged alongside a related proposal by Belgian prime minister Yves Leterme to create a European Debt Agency. And, I later discovered, this proposal echoed the arguments made by John Springford in a September 2009 opinion piece in the Wall Street Journal. Of course all of that was eclipsed by the ‘Blue Bond’ proposal issued by Breugel in April 2010 and updated in March 2011 – which has emerged as the focal point for the eurobond debate. The second piece in the packet reiterates the eurobond proposal and begins to shift the debate toward market stabilization. I drafted that policy memorandum for Opex, which is the economics arm of the Spanish Alternativas think tank. The question-and-answer structure of the memorandum reflects the growing level of confusion and controversy that surrounded the eurobond from the outset. The next two pieces were published as editorials to defend the eurobond against mounting criticism that emerged once the idea was launched politically in December 2010 by Giulio Tremonti and Jean Claude Juncker. The fifth piece criticizes the March 2011 European Council decision to focus on competitiveness in reforming European macroeconomic governance. The remaining pieces reiterate and strengthen the arguments made from the outset. My talk at the ‘Festival of Europe’ conference in Florence last May tries to summarize the debate about eurobonds (and includes references to much of the wider literature). The ‘keynote address’ I gave in Rutgers to a meeting of financial services professionals was an attempt to make these issues comprehensible to an American audience. The two-part series I did for E!Sharp tried to explain why the reform debate keeps moving around in circles and the op-ed with Dan Kelemen for USA Today gives a more optimistic take. The comment for ISPI suggests how Germany could be brought around to support the proposal. The op-eds for Foreign Affairs and Eurointelligence focus on the flight to safety. Finally, the conference paper on five lessons from the crisis and the policy brief I did for the Swedish Institute for European Policy Studies tie it all together. Clearly there is no end to this discussion and my contribution has been only a small one. Nevertheless, I hope that this collection will be of use and look forward to any comments that it may generate. Bologna, 25 May 2012 Erik Jones N. 180 - MARCH 2010 A Eurobond Proposal to Promote Stability and Liquidity while Preventing Moral Hazard* The current crisis in Greek sovereign debt markets has made two things clear. First, any default by the Greek government would be bad for the eurozone as a whole because it would hurt the balance sheets of large banks that are already struggling to raise capital and because it would threaten the liquidity of bond markets for countries that may be in a similar situation. Hence a timely bailout of the Greek government would do a lot to shore up the stability and liquidity of European financial markets. Nevertheless, and this is the second point, no-one is particularly eager to (be seen to) bail out the Greeks. Of course everyone is eager to prevent another major financial crisis but the idea of pumping money into a country that has so obviously lived beyond its means while at the same time cooking the books and conniving with banks to cover its tracks is hard to swallow. Even under the most generous of circumstances, such an action would be seen to create a “moral hazard” – encouraging future governments in Greece and elsewhere to engage similar behavior. Abstract in The current situation in Greece presents precisely the sort damned-if-you-do, damned-if-you-don’t dilemma that the Maastricht Treaty and the Stability and Growth Pact were designed to prevent. The multilateral surveillance, excessive deficits, and early warning procedures were meant to spot and correct these situations in a timely manner; ESA 95 and the newly empowered Eurostat were meant to ensure that fiscal accounting was easy for all to read; the escalating ladder of sanctions provided the incentives for corrective action; and the no bailout clause showed that there was no net on the other side of the precipice. Unfortunately, however, few economic commentators recognized that the Greek situation was a real possibility. Instead they worried that the provisions for macroeconomic policy coordination would leave too little room for fiscal stimulus or policy flexibility. Hence it is hardly surprising that politicians would use this concern to set the stability and growth No-one is particularly eager to bail out the Greeks. Of course everyone would like to prevent another major financial crisis but the idea of pumping money into a country that has so obviously lived beyond its means while providing incorrect information and conniving with banks to cover its tracks is hard to swallow. Even under the most generous of circumstances, such an action would be seen to create a “moral hazard” – encouraging future governments in Greece and elsewhere to engage in similar behaviour. The solution could be a dual bond structure for government financing (including Eurobonds). This would not eliminate the Greek crisis but would help mitigate its systemic importance. Erik Jones is Professor of European Studies at the SAIS Bologna Center of the Johns Hopkins University and author of, inter alia, The Politics of Economic and Monetary Union, Rowman & Littlefield, 2002. (*) Further institutional, juridical and technical details on this proposal will be provided in a future ISPI publication. 2 pact aside at the first sign of inconvenience. The Greek situation is the natural outcome of this lack of restraint1. The question is where to go from here. Two ideas that have been floated are a European stability fund to shore up the financial system and a common issue “Eurobond” to ensure that adequate liquidity is available to all member states2. These ideas have tight synergies and they could even be run together. They also share the same problem: moral hazard. As Otmar Issing insisted in criticizing such proposals: «a common bond is no cure for a lack of fiscal discipline; on the contrary, it would tend to encourage countries to continue on their wrong fiscal course»3. Still the alternatives seem even more unpalatable. The International Monetary Fund could be called in to give a Greek bailout the veneer of international respectability or Greece could be pushed out of (invited to take a holiday from) the eurozone altogether4. 1 J. MATTHES, Why the IMF should be involved in solving imminent fiscal debt crises in Eurozone countries, in «VoxEU», February 27, 2010. 2 D. GROS - S. MICOSSI, A bondissuing stability fund could rescue Europe, in «Europe’s World», Spring 2009; P. DE GRAUWE - W. MOESEN, Gains for All: A proposal for a common Eurobond, CEPS Commentary, April 3, 2009. 3 O. ISSING, Why a common eurozone bond isn’t such a good idea, in «Europe’s World», Summer 2009. 4 J. MATTHES, cit.; M. FELDSTEIN, Let Greece take a eurozone ISPI - Policy Brief Clearly, what we need is the best of both worlds – a proposal that can provide liquidity in a crisis but with the teeth to ensure that governments have an incentive to keep their fiscal situation under control. Such a proposal should also offer advantages to all parties, both those countries that are likely to wind up in difficulty and those who are more likely to do the bailing out. Finally, the proposal should not rely on a nuclear option that lacks credibility because it is too painful or embarrassing to enforce. Eurobonds for Growth and Stability The eurozone needs a common sovereign bond issue to provide liquidity and to avoid market speculation (or a flight to security) from resulting in cross-country financing strains5. Member state governments would authorize bond issues for which they would meet the servicing requirements. Nevertheless, the bonds would come from a central issuing authority and would be both indistinguishable and interchangeable in secondary markets – one bond would be much as another (of the same coupon and maturity) no matter which country “holiday”, in «Financial Times», February 16, 2010. 5 M.G. ATTINASI - C. CHECHERITA - C. NICKEL, What explains the surge in euro-area sovereign spreads during the financial crisis of 2007-2009?, in «VoxEU», January 11, 2010. authorized its issuance. In other words, all eurobonds with the same characteristics would attract the same ratings. To avoid moral hazard, participating governments would have limits on the volume of bonds they can authorize both globally and in any given year. Specifically, they would be constrained from authorizing bonds worth more than 60 percent of their growth domestic product or – after an initial transition period – from authorizing a net increase in their total eurobond responsibilities worth more than 3 percent of their gross domestic product on an annual basis. In this sense, eurobonds would only be available for responsible borrowing. “Excessive” borrowing, as defined by the Maastricht Treaty, would have to take place through national sovereign bond issues which would be characteristically different both from common issue eurobonds and across countries – and so attract a different rating and price from one country to the next. Hence the first incentive to engage in responsible borrowing would be the price differential. Responsible borrowing would be cheaper; excessive borrowing would be more expensive. The major advantage of this arrangement would be the heightened transparency that it would provide both in terms of financial markets and in terms of the countries 3 ISPI - Policy Brief themselves. Market participants would know exactly not only how much “excessive” borrowing a country was engaged in but also which of a country’s debt instruments are most susceptible to the risk of sovereign default. Moreover, the countries that choose to participate in the common bond issuance would have to accept much closer scrutiny of their national statistics and fiscal accounts – just as firms that trade publicly on the stock exchange agree to stricter reporting requirements. If a country was shown to be cooking the books, its authorization privileges could be suspended, forcing it to rely on more expensive forms of borrowing until it could earn the right to authorize common issue eurobonds again. In extremis, this dual bond arrangement suggests a natural procedure for organizing a country’s orderly default. The first stage would be to renegotiate the terms of country-specific obligations – meaning those used for any excessive borrowing – followed if necessary by a suspension of debt servicing payments on the common issue bonds (which could continue to roll-over unaffected by any countryspecific financial situation). Here it is true that the other member states would be required to pick up the defaulting country’s debt servicing obligations. However, this would only be temporary, it would represent far less of a financial exposure than actively bailing the country out, and it could always be repaid with interest once the crisis has passed and the country’s financial situation is on more stable footing. Deeper Markets, Cheaper Liquidity The incentives constraining fiscal policy under this proposal are easy to summarize: countries face a higher price for excessive borrowing; they run the risk of losing their authorization privileges; and they can imagine what it will look like to experience an orderly (and yet still humiliating and painful) default. These incentives do not include an unbelievable nuclear option; there is no need to expel a country from the eurozone, to call in the IMF, or, alternatively, to bail them out. The structure of the system also shores up the procedures of the rest of the eurozone. For example, the European Central Bank is no longer held responsible for certifying all sovereign debt instruments as collateral in open market operations or, reciprocally, for triggering a sovereign debt crisis once eligibility for collateral use in open market operations is withdrawn. Hence, on the disciplinary side, it is a credible arrangement all the way down. But what about the incentives for otherwise responsible countries to participate? These are fairly straightforward as well. To begin with, the common issue eurobond offers a deeper and more liquid market than any country – even Germany – can generate for itself. Hence to the extent that liquidity trades at a discount, it should offer lower borrowing costs for all countries (including Germany) as well. Moreover, because it is larger than any national market, this eurobond market would make it possible for countries to export savings across the eurozone without accepting an implicit sovereign risk. This would make it easier for Germany to continue to run its export-led growth model without exposing its banking system to the need to take on unwanted exposure. A deeper eurobond market would make it more attractive for countries outside the eurozone to diversify their reserve holdings into euros as well. Indeed, since this common issue eurobond would be limited in scope to what we can characterize as responsible fiscal borrowing, it might prove even more attractive than the ever expanding market for government paper in the United States. Getting There from Here If we had this dual bond structure for government financing, the current crisis in Greece would be less pressing and more manageable. It would be less 4 pressing because not all Greek debt would come up for refinancing in nationally specific sovereign bonds. Much of it would come up as eurobonds instead. This would not eliminate the crisis in Greek public financing, but it would mitigate its systemic importance because in effect, investors could fly to safety from one set of Greek obligations to another. This would benefit both Greece and the investors who hold Greek obligations. Meanwhile, the crisis would be more manageable because we could know better how to structure a reorganization of Greek finances transparently, making it clear to all who is exposed to losses and who is not. The trick is to get there from here. It is possible to imagine two alternatives. One is to wait for this crisis to pass, taking the time to organize the institutions for issuing and overseeing the common issue eurobonds and for preparing national fiscal authorities (and their treasury operations) for the necessary transition. That may prove the most rational way forward. However, time is not on our side. Hence it could be possible to imagine a more speedy process, which sets up the institutions for eurobond issuance quickly so that the resources they promise can soon be put into place. This would allow the member states to begin refinancing Greek sovereign obligations with common issue eurobonds almost immediately, stabilizing ISPI - Policy Brief financial markets by pooling those obligations with issues authorized by other member states. Technically this would not be a bailout. Practically, it would take much of the urgency away. Not only would we eliminate the current crisis, but we would create the incentives to avoid the next. La ricerca ISPI analizza le dinamiche politiche, strategiche ed economiche del sistema internazionale con il duplice obiettivo di informare e di orientare le scelte di policy. I risultati della ricerca vengono divulgati attraverso pubblicazioni ed eventi, focalizzati su tematiche di particolare interesse per l’Italia e le sue relazioni internazionali e articolati in: 9 9 9 9 9 9 9 9 9 9 9 9 9 Programma Africa Programma Caucaso e Asia Centrale Programma Europa Programma Mediterraneo e Medio Oriente Programma Russia e Vicini Orientali Programma Sicurezza e Studi Strategici Progetto Argentina Progetto Asia Meridionale Progetto Cina e Asia Orientale Progetto Diritti Umani Progetto Disarmo Progetto Emergenze e Affari Umanitari Progetto Internazionalizzazione della Pubblica Amministrazione ISPI Palazzo Clerici Via Clerici, 5 I - 20121 Milano www.ispionline.it Per informazioni: ispi.policybrief@ispionline.it ispi.policybrief1@ispionline.it © ISPI 2010 OPEX MEMORANDUM No. 147/2010 AUTHOR: ERIK JONES, Professor of European Studies of the SAIS Bologna Centre of the John Hopkins University. He is also a collaborator of Opex. TO: OPEX DATE: 21/07/2010 SUBJECT: A MARKET ALTERNATIVE TO FISCAL DISCIPLINE IN EUROPE; A PROPOSAL FOR A EUROBOND FACILITY Panel: Economía Internacional Coordinator: Manuel de la Rocha Vázquez www.falternativas.org/opex Depósito Legal: M-54881-2008 ISSN: 1989-2845 Director: Nicolás Sartorius Subdirector: Vicente Palacio Coordinadores de Área: Mario Esteban (Asia-Pacífico); Rafael Bustos (Magreb-Oriente Medio); Raquel Montes (Unión Europea); Manuel de la Rocha Vázquez (Economía Internacional y África Subsahariana); Vicente Palacio (Relaciones Transatlánticas); Paulina Correa (Seguridad y Defensa); Kattya Cascante (Cooperación al desarrollo); Érika M. Rodríguez Pinzón (América Latina). Opex Memorandum No. 147/2010: A market alternative to fiscal discipline in Europe; a proposal for a Eurobond facility Why there is a need for a Eurobond Facility? The ongoing reform of European macroeconomic governance is making great strides in improving both multilateral surveillance and fiscal policy coordination. The members of the Task Force headed by European Council President Herman Van Rompuy should be congratulated for the speed and diligence with which they are guiding this reform effort. Nevertheless, the proposal they are developing, based on enhancing the enforcement mechanisms, suffers from the same genetic weakness as the old Stability and Growth Pact and the excessive deficits procedure that underpins it. When faced with a crisis situation where a large and powerful country has to choose between obeying the rules or making politically unacceptable fiscal adjustment, it will always be cheaper and easier to break the rules. Similarly, EU member countries may easily ignore their European commitments when the calculation of costs and benefits for doing so points in that direction. That is why France and Germany suspended the excessive deficits procedure in 2003; that is why 24 of 27 European Union member states find themselves within the excessive deficits procedure today. What the European Union needs is a system for fiscal discipline that can remain credible in times of crisis. This should be a system that allows countries to borrow in moments of extreme economic weakness, but that encourages them to do so in moderation, setting incentives for them to bring their debt back down to sustainable levels once the crisis has passed. Most important, it should be a system where the cost of defection is always higher than the cost of playing by the rules – not just for smaller countries that can be punished by their larger neighbours, but even for the most powerful of European Union member states, France and Germany included. A powerful proposal that would address many of those problems would be the creation of a limited access common Eurobond Facility, through which member states would have limited borrowing rights. Such a Facility has already been put forward by experts. Yet, drawing on the best arguments made in each of the proposals, this Memo seeks to make a strong case for the Spanish Government (which could be an important beneficiary) to advance it in official EU forums. What would be the main features of the Eurobond Facility? Eurobonds would have to be issued by a common authority and supported by the wider architecture of European macroeconomic governance. The precise institutional design is less important than the principles upon which such an authority would operate. The most important features of the proposed Eurobond Facility are the following: • The bonds would be denominated in Euros and could be issued at different fixed maturities in line with the portfolio requirements for treasury operations. • The bonds would be undifferentiated and no individual bond could be associated with a particular member state. The implication here is that every bond will be backed by every member state in a manner similar to the pro rata guarantees provided to the European financial mechanism that was created to fund the European Union’s response to the sovereign debt crisis. • Member States must commit to honour their common Eurobond obligations before any other credit liability. 1 Opex Memorandum No. 147/2010: A market alternative to fiscal discipline in Europe; a proposal for a Eurobond facility • Member state access to bond issues would be limited as a share of their income. The most obvious ceiling would be the 60 percent debt-to-GDP per country threshold set in the Maastricht Treaty, however it would also be possible to introduce intermediate thresholds at lower levels with a graduating scale of charges associated with higher borrowing rates, up to the ceiling of 60 percent. The characteristics described combine to form a very large, uniform, and low risk market capable of rivalling or even surpassing the market for United States Treasury paper in terms of depth and liquidity. What would be the advantages for Member States that participate in the Eurobond Facility? The principal advantages come from the price and stability and that such a Eurobond would offer. • For most Member States, the Eurobond Facility would allow them to borrow funds at a lower cost than the current price they pay in the market; • Eurobonds would be an attractive and safe investment for many non-European countries which would decide to diversify their foreign currency reserves, thus balancing the US as the only reserve currency in the world. In turn, this attractiveness would increase the depth and liquidity of the Eurobond market as compared with existing national bonds, further lowering the price of credit and increasing the incentives for Member States to participate; • The benefits from the Eurobond are also linked to the stronger discipline it will impose on those countries participating in it, which would reduce the risk of defaulting, thus compromising the stability of the whole Eurozone; • Ultimately, the issue of Eurobonds a the EU level would be an step forward in the path to closer European integration and a key pillar of the European economic governance. How would a Eurobond Facility force Member States to maintain more fiscal discipline? Eurobonds would create strong positive incentives for governments to borrow responsibly: • Member States would have to qualify to participate, primarily by meeting rigorous standards for fiscal accounting and budgetary transparency just as firms accept when they list on a stock exchange; • Member states would have to open their fiscal accounts to close scrutiny to qualify for new borrowing and again like firms belonging to a stock exchange, they would risk suspension of their borrowing privileges should they fail to maintain transparent accounts; • The amount Member states could borrow would be strictly limited in proportion to their income and, like homeowners, they could face escalating premiums as they move close to their maximum borrowing threshold to cover the increasing risks that even higher levels of responsible borrowing entails; 2 Opex Memorandum No. 147/2010: A market alternative to fiscal discipline in Europe; a proposal for a Eurobond facility • A Member States’ participation could be suspended – in the sense of suspending the right to raise new money through the common Eurobonds until certain conditions are met – and it can also be revoked. If and when a country would be suspended all new issues will be blocked and the country’s position within the facility will be wound up as existing bonds reach maturation. In summary, participation by the Member States in the common Eurobonds would be both a commitment and a privilege. This combination creates both credible incentives and credible sanctions. Moreover, by varying the period of suspension from the facility, it is possible to graduate the sanctions very precisely to coincide with any problems as they occur. What would be the implications of the Eurobond Facility for national bonds? A common Eurobond Facility would also leave open the possibility for governments to borrow in extremis. Once their right of issue is exhausted, governments can always use national bonds instead of common Eurobonds to raise funds on the market. However, these national bonds will be considerably more expensive to issue than common Eurobonds because: • National bonds will have a weaker claim to repayment – member states will have to commit to service common Eurobonds first; • National bonds will come in smaller issues with thinner markets – the common Eurobonds will be issued in relatively large volumes by every member state, the national bonds will be issued in small volumes and will differ from one member state to the next; • National bonds will have less institutional support to maintain liquid markets – the European Central Bank (ECB) will obviously accept common Eurobonds as collateral in central banking operations, but it will not be constrained to accept national bonds unless they meet fixed rating criteria. At the same time, national bonds would be subject to greater market discipline and will be more expensive than common bonds as a source of funding. This is much like credit card debt when compared to mortgage debt – the governments that issue them will face a powerful incentive to pay them off and so bring their net borrowing back down to responsible levels. Two additional implications should be mentioned as well: • First, national bonds would carry a visibly higher risk of default in terms of payment moratoria, haircuts, term extensions, etc. and so investors in these bonds will have a incentive to know they risks they are undertaking; • Second, countries would be able to default on their national bonds without raising the risk of default across their whole debt profile, which implies that the collateral damage to the banking system of a national fiscal crisis will be less extensive. Hence, national bonds would become an important source of information about when a member states’ debt is becoming too big without at the same time resulting in that member state becoming ‘too big to fail’. 3 Opex Memorandum No. 147/2010: A market alternative to fiscal discipline in Europe; a proposal for a Eurobond facility Which countries would be allowed to join the Eurobond Facility? Participation in the Eurobond Facility should be voluntary and membership should be open to any Member State that is willing and able to meet the reporting requirements and to accept the repayment obligations. Voluntary participation is important for two reasons: • First, some member states may only be able to join on the basis of constitutional amendment and popular referendum. In those countries, political leaders will have to make the case membership and choose an appropriate time for joining. As the experience of Sweden and the eurozone has demonstrated, legal obligations do not improve the prospects of membership. On the contrary, legal requirements may force the pace of decision-making and instead result in curious legal anomalies (like Sweden’s non-participation in the eurozone) and popular distrust and resentment; • Second, voluntary commitments are stronger commitments because they ensure that the debate about participation is grounded in national self-interest and because they offer greater transparency and accountability at the national level. Making membership open to non-eurozone Member States follows established precedent for institutional arrangements designed to support the function of the euro; the Trans-European Automated Real-time Gross settlement Express Transfer system (TARGET and now TARGET2) allows non-eurozone member states to join as well. As in TARGET, the principal distinction is that non-eurozone member state have to accept any exchange rate risk and settlement requirements attached to working in euros. Moreover, the advantages of allowing non-eurozone Member States to join are considerable. • Participation in the Eurobond Facility would strengthen incentives for noneurozone countries to improve their fiscal accounting and consolidate their budgetary positions; • It would allow governments to benefit from a lower cost of financing for responsible borrowing without spreading the low interest rate structure across the society as a whole in an inappropriate or pro-cyclical manner (as happened in Latvia); • It would help non-eurozone member states better manage or restrict their foreign currency debt exposure (as in Hungary). • Finally, non-eurozone participation in a Eurobond Facility would reinforce the process of convergence on eurozone membership by creating an intermediate institutional step from which the advantages of full membership are stronger because only adoption of the euro can eliminate any remaining exchange rate risk. Voluntary and open participation in a Eurobond Facility would not only stabilize the functioning of the eurozone; it would strengthen the process of monetary integration as a whole. 4 Opex Memorandum No. 147/2010: A market alternative to fiscal discipline in Europe; a proposal for a Eurobond facility What would be the implications for Member States of leaving, or being suspended, from the Eurobond Facility? Member states could be suspended or kicked-out of the Eurobond Facility, thus losing the benefits they obtain from it. Yet, it will always be cheaper to stay in the Eurobond Facility than to break the rules, even for the largest and most powerful member states. The logic here is not unlike the arguments used to explain why countries do not exit the Eurozone. • The transition costs for moving from treasury operations based on common Eurobonds to national bonds, both within the government and across the banking system would be significant; • The country’s borrowing costs after the transition would be considerably higher; and, • The symbolic implications both for the individual member state and for the European integration project as a whole would be both obvious and negative. In other words, defecting from the system would always be more expensive than complying with the obligations of membership. The discipline of the system would be much more credible as a result. What are the principal objections to a Eurobond Facility and from whom? Apart from some experts, high profile political figures like Belgian Prime Minister Yves Leterme and European Council President Herman Van Rompuy have made similar proposals as well. Each time, however, they have encountered an immovable obstacle in German Chancellor Angela Merkel and her government. The argument the Germans make is two-fold: • First, such a Eurobond would violate the no-bailout principle according to which neither member states, nor European institutions may assume responsibility for one-another’s debts; • Second, such a proposal would raise borrowing costs for Germany, which is already the first contributor to EU expenses, and there is no willingness on the part of the German people to shoulder this additional burden. The first argument is more concerned with legality than principle. If the principle behind the no bailout clause is to prevent moral hazard in the conduct of government finances, then this proposal meets that goal better than the original Treaty language. None of the Treaty provisions succeeded in preventing Greece from reaching an unsustainable financial situation and none of them prevented the other European Union Member States from coming to Greece’s assistance. The second argument about relative costs is more difficult to dismiss, particularly when German government debt is trading at a significant premium (high price, low yield) to most other member states. Nevertheless, it is important to remember the context. German government debt is expensive in the market and so cheap for the German government because Europe is in an economic crisis. During the pre-crisis period after the start of the single currency, the difference across countries was much less significant. In that pre-crisis setting, the much deeper markets available to a common Eurobond would actually work to Germany’s benefit. 5 Opex Memorandum No. 147/2010: A market alternative to fiscal discipline in Europe; a proposal for a Eurobond facility Germany would benefit from lower interest rates during periods of crisis as well. The comparison across countries misses an essential component. At the moment, the prices attached to national bonds reflect the entire volume of each country’s debt. With a common Eurobond, the only responsible share of borrowing will be reflected in Eurobond prices and the excessive borrowing will be reflected in national bond markets. So long as Germany continues to borrow responsibly, its financing needs will be met by Eurobonds that will be as much a safe haven in the future as German bunds are today. Germany will continue to benefit from favourable financing rates even as the rest of Europe will see the incentives for fiscal discipline enhanced. 6 09/03/2011 Why German opposition to the comm… 16.12.2010 GREEK DEBATE Germany is unfit for the euro By: J oerg Bibow 2 1 .0 4 .1 0 Portents of the Greek Rescue By: Barry E ic hengreen 1 5 .0 4 .1 0 Finally a deal, but I am still sceptical By: Wolfgang M ünc hau 1 3 .0 4 .1 0 Why Greece will default By: Wolfgang M ünc hau 0 7 .0 4 .1 0 Why an IMF solution is most likely By: L aurenc e Boone WHY GERMAN OPPOSITION TO THE COMMON EUROBOND PROPOSAL IS MISTAKEN By: P aul D e G rauwe 1 1 .0 3 .1 0 Greek Competitiveness Is Not the Issue, Fiscal Discipline Is By: E rik J ones 0 4 .0 3 .1 0 Europe in Dire Straits – don’t be Brothers in A rms. By: H enrik E nderlein 0 2 .0 3 .1 0 How should the Eurozone handle Greece? By: D aniela Sc hwarzer and Sebas tian D ullien 0 1 .0 3 .1 0 The Euro A rea's political constraints By: Wolfgang M ünc hau 1 6 .0 2 .1 0 Password: By: Erik Jones There are four things we all want to happen as this crisis in European sovereign debt markets develops. We want borrowers in Greece, Ireland, and elsewhere to learn to live within their means. We want lenders to learn to price risk appropriately and to share in losses when they occur. We want governments and banks to be able to meet their day-to-day requirements. And we want the euro to remain a common currency without the member states having to sacrifice their fiscal sovereignty. Only a common eurobond with limited drawing rights and senior status like that proposed by Giulio Tremonti and JeanClaude Juncker can meet these objectives. 2 4 .0 3 .1 0 The Greek crisis and the future of the Eurozone LOGIN Username: Much of the German opposition to a eurobond comes from the notion that less frugal countries would take advantage of common bonds to borrow beyond their means. That is why it is important to have limited drawing rights. The current system forces the Germans to bail out countries when they cannot pay. A common bond with limited drawing rights would only ask the Germans to put their creditworthiness on the line for other countries when those can pay. At the same time, there is a sharp contrast between the cost of borrowing with a common bond and the cost of borrowing in a national bond that is on top of their rights in the common issue. If we use the Tremonti-Juncker proposal as an illustration, debt raised in common eurobonds up to 40 percent of GDP would be very cheap to finance; the debt raised in national bonds beyond that threshold would be very expensive. There is a strong market incentive for countries not to borrow beyond their means. Lenders would face clear incentives and consequences as well. The challenge is to help investors to differentiate between debt which is more risky and debt which is more secure. A common eurobond with limited drawing rights and senior status would provide the solution. Investors would know that any common eurobond is much like any other insofar as debtors would ensure that it is serviced first. National bonds would have a www.eurointelligence.com/index.php… Stay logged in Login Forgot your password? How to re giste r FAQ EUROINTELLIGENCE BRIEFING NOTE Public finances in 2011 : happy austerity 28.01.2011 By: Raphae l C ottin A close r look at the e ffe cts of auste rity. Is Belgium next? 15.10.2010 By: Susanne Mundschenk and R aphae l Cottin This is the se cond Eurointe llige nce Brie fing note , focusing on the e conom ic im plications on Be lgium 's ongoing political crisis. OUR PARTNERS MUNCHAU'S COLUMNS The ECB's hidden agenda 08.03.2011 By: W olfgang Münchau political. The de cision to pre announce a rate rise is GLOBAL ECONOMIC SYMPOSIUM A repository of solutions to global 1/3 09/03/2011 Why German opposition to the comm… lower standing and would suffer earlier losses. In the Tremonti-Juncker proposal, conversion from national bonds to eurobonds would come at a cost as well. Hence, investors would know that national bonds have higher risk attached and because they would stand to lose first. Meanwhile it is important to note that excessive borrowing and excessive lending are only a small fraction of the activity in bond markets. Governments routinely recycle debt that has matured with new bond issues and banks rely on government securities for their treasury operations. Under the current system whole countries are cut off when their sovereign debt markets run into trouble as national governments struggle to roll over their debt and as banks find themselves subject to widespread losses on their most liquid assets. A common eurobond would limit this dynamic by creating a distinction between the rollover of responsible lending and any excessive increase in borrowing. At the same time it would ensure that national banking systems across the eurozone relied on the same securities in their treasury operations and so eliminate an unnecessary source of counterparty risk. problems 25.06.2010 For two ye ars now, le ading policy m ak e rs, a ca de m ics a nd busine ssm e n have be e n m e e ting for discussions in the Global Econom ic Sym posium to provide concre te solutions for the m ost pre ssing global gove rnance issue s the world will be facing this ce ntury. He re is the re sult of the se discussions: a re pository of concre te policy proposals. Finally, a common eurobond would only reiterate and reinforce the commitments made at Maastricht in 1991 and Amsterdam in 1997. Governments would agree to avoid excessive deficits (that is, borrowing beyond their drawing rights) in the short term and they would strive to achieve fiscal balance over the medium-to-long term. There is nothing in this that implies a transfer from north to south or from Germany to the rest. Moreover, there is nothing to prevent countries from pursuing radically different versions of the welfare state. A common eurobond does not imply a redistributive fiscal union. On the contrary, it ensures that such redistribution does not have to take place. By differentiating between responsible and irresponsible borrowing, a eurobond creates a market incentive for fiscal probity. By distinguishing between senior (European) and junior (national) debt, a eurobond gives clear signals to the markets on how to price risk. By making it easier for governments to rollover existing debt while still making it harder for them to borrow irresponsibly, a eurobond would stabilize both debt markets and interbank lending. The German people are reluctant to accept a common eurobond. That is because they believe they operate only on one side of the relationship. The reality is that Germans are on both sides of the trade. They may not sell the www.eurointelligence.com/index.php… 2/3 09/03/2011 Why German opposition to the comm… bonds but they buy them; hence they risk suffering losses and ultimately might risk a bailout themselves. A common eurobond with limited drawing rights would limit their exposure and not increase it. Everyone in the markets would know where they would risk losses and where they would be bailed out. Such certainty is essential if the euro is to survive and prosper. Erik Jones is Professor for European Studies at the Johns Hopkins University. <- Back to: Eurointelligence about us | c ontac t us | terms and c onditions | privac y | L inks Copyright 2009 Eurointelligence ASBL www.eurointelligence.com/index.php… 3/3 web specials print edition archive contributors In defence of Eurobonds about us email alerts Search It is high time for Berlin to rethink its dogged opposition to common European debt obligations, writes Erik Jones Search March-A pril 2011 Europe : Just abo ut rights? Ba rgaining powe r - and m o ne y End of the Arabia n night? Cartoon: Mike Mosedale When Luxembourg Prime Minister Jean-Claude Juncker and Italian Finance Minister Giulio Tremonti proposed the creation of common “eurobonds” just prior to the December 2010 European Council, their suggestion received a frosty reception. Opponents of the proposal denounced the idea as an attempt to introduce a transfer union – moving money from one group of countries to another – through the back door. Not only would such a common bond facility raise interest rates on responsible borrow ers, the argument ran, but it would also make it easier for less responsible governments to spend their w ay into trouble. What the situation requires, opponents of the eurobond concluded, is more fiscal discipline supported by a permanent facility for crisis management. Moreover, such a facility should support the stability of the European financial system, leaving individual governments to clean up the messes they make on their ow n. This criticism of the eurobond has a broad resonance with voters wary of footing the bill for other countries’ financial mistakes. As an intuitive proposition, what could be worse than underwriting another country’s public debt? Yet such criticism (and such intuition) ignores crucial features of the actual proposal and so misses the point. A eurobond facility like the one proposed by Juncker and Tremonti would ensure that responsible borrowers alw ays pay the lowest possible rate of interest while creating powerful market incentives to curb excessive borrow ing. More important, it w ould shore up the stability of the European banking system while at the same time forcing private-sector investors to set bond prices that are more in line with attendant risks. In this way, a eurobond would better protect taxpayers from having to support yet another major bailout. And should governments insist on behaving irresponsibly, a common eurobond w ould eliminate any systemic justification for other countries – or the European Central Bank (ECB) – to step in. The advantages of a eurobond of this kind w ould stem from three features: conditional participation, limited drawing rights, and senior status. Moreover, each of these could be fine-tuned to make the effects of a eurobond stronger or w eaker. Start with the notion of conditional participation. Countries w ould not have a right to issue common eurobonds any more than they have a right to join the euro. Hence participation w ould be subject to qualification – with criteria like those that firms face when listing on the stock exchange or issuing corporate bonds. Countries would be required to meet rigid accounting standards that would ensure a higher level of transparency and they w ould have to accept more intrusive oversight from the European Union’s accounting watchdog, Eurostat. Of course, governments could resist this intrusion. But then they w ould give up the advantages of issuing eurobonds either as a first instance or in refinancing existing debt. The limited drawing rights w ould ensure that borrow ing was not excessive. Juncker and Tremonti proposed a limit is of 40 percent of gross domestic product (GDP). Other proposals use the Maastricht Treaty’s public debt ceiling of 60 percent of GDP. Whatever the constraint, the implication is the same. Borrow ing below the limit would take place cheaply in eurobonds. Borrow ing above the limit w ould require states to issue more costly national obligations. This w ould create an incentive to limit borrowing in the marketplace, where excessive debt would be increasingly expensive to finance. The senior status of eurobonds over strictly national obligations would mean that, in the event of a crisis, the eurobonds w ould alw ays be paid off first. This preference given to the eurobonds would reinforce the incentives to rein in government borrow ing through three subtle yet discrete effects. The first effect is transparency. At the moment, all of a country’s debt is much the same. Hence when Greece experienced a crisis in its bond market, all investors in Greek bonds were equally affected. But if Greece had issued a mix of eurobonds and national obligations, only those investors exposed to national obligations w ould have been under duress. More important, those investors would have know n the higher risks they w ere taking w ell before the crisis occurred – giving them the opportunity to price in that risk before the fact. A second effect operates through bank balance sheets. Currently banks use government bonds as collateral to borrow cash from the European System of Central Banks – the national central banks that are part of the eurozone. In normal times, this means that the market for sovereign debts is very deep and government bond prices reflect that fact. Once sovereign debt markets come under stress, however, the market suddenly dries up. Banks are reluctant to sell what they hold, for fear of taking the write-down on those assets, and they are also reluctant to buy more bonds and so increase their exposure. Prices in government bond markets suddenly become very volatile as a result. This explains w hy the ECB took the decision to begin making purchases in sovereign debt markets – to dampen those volatile price movements. It also explains w hy the ECB had to accept Greek bonds as collateral irrespective of their risk rating – otherw ise it w ould have been cutting off access to liquidity (meaning money) for Greek banks. A eurobond w ould resolve both dilemmas by creating a separate category of assets for use as collateral with central banks. Moreover, the same assets would be used by all banks across the eurozone. Not only would eurobond markets be less vulnerable to distress, but the eurobonds themselves w ould have greater liquidity (they could be more easily converted into money) than any European sovereign debt instrument currently in existence. The cost of borrowing in eurobonds w ould be comparatively lower as a result. The third effect of giving repayment preference (or seniority) to eurobonds is that it w ould limit the systemic implications of sovereign debt restructuring. Should a government need to restructure its obligations, it w ould put all the cost of that exercise onto the strictly national part of its debt. However, since private investors w ould know of that possibility from the start, either they, their creditors or their regulators w ould build their exposure to such obligations into their models for value at risk. Meanwhile, the banking system as a whole w ould have no reason to overexpose itself to risky sovereign debt through the process of routine treasury operations as central banking collateral. Finally, there would be no reason for the ECB to relax its collateral rules or to buy government obligations in secondary markets. A eurobond w ith conditional participation, limited drawing rights and senior status would be anything but a blank cheque. On the contrary, it would be a powerful instrument for restructuring incentives in the market. Governments would save money by opening their accounts and reining in their spending; they would pay extra for borrowing that is excessive; and their creditors would have to accept the consequences of any risks. Moreover, these incentives would operate w ithout any necessary political deliberation. The redesigned stability and growth pact, intended to instill fiscal discipline on eurozone countries, would still require a decision by the EU Council in order to sanction a profligate member state; under a eurobond those sanctions w ould be automatic. The pact also has lengthy procedures for encouraging action; under the eurobond regime like the one described here, the encouragement would be immediate and continuous. Opponents of the Juncker-Tremonti proposal should look more closely at the advantages such an arrangement would offer. It would create a deeper and more liquid market where responsible borrowing is amply rewarded through low interest rates. It w ould make it unnecessary for the ECB to w eaken its balance sheet or to intervene directly in the marketplace. And it would prevent sovereign debt restructuring from triggering a pan-European banking crisis. These advantages are going to be hard to sell to voters – both in Germany and elsew here – w ho are intuitively averse to the idea of having common bonds or fiscal instruments. Nevertheless, it is time for Europe’s leaders to explain to their electorates why the proposed eurobond is in everyone’s best interest. European integration has often lurched forw ard in times of crisis and the EU has emerged much stronger as a result. The present crisis should not be any different. Copyright E!Sharp magazine Why Europe Needs Eurobonds(?) Erik Jones SAIS Bologna Center (ejones@jhubc.it) Remarks prepared for Festival of Europe Conference on ‘State of the Union’ Florence, 9-10 May 2011 Page 1 of 9 Why Europe Needs Eurobonds(?) Erik Jones SAIS Bologna Center Good morning. It is both an honor and a privilege to join a panel with such distinguished participants. I would like to thank the organizers for including me in such an impressive event. I would also like to thank them for giving me a topic that has so much in-built support from my copanelists. Our first speaker, Paul De Grauwe, is rightly credited with restarting the debate on eurobonds in an influential paper that he wrote with Wim Moesen in April 2009.1 For those of you who are interested in a recent synthesis, I would recommend De Grauwe’s latest essay on economic governance in a fragile eurozone.2 As part of that debate, Mario Monti has been a consistent advocate of Eurobonds as a source of solidarity and market discipline;3 Lorenzo Bini-Smaghi threw his weight behind the idea in a speech he made at the IMT in Luca last March;4 and Zolt Darvas has reinforced calls made by his Bruegel colleagues, Jacques Delpla and Jakob von Wiezsäcker to introduce eurobonds as well.5 Hence my goal from their perspective is primarily to give due weight to their insights and contributions. Of course the organizers have been careful to include some more skeptical voices on the panel. I think that is why they put the question mark in the title. Yves Mersch has described the eurobond proposal as both ‘unhelpful’ and ‘premature’, explaining that ‘if you want to Europeanize debt then you have to Europeanize tax collection’ and pointing out that it would be more useful to focus attention on necessary structural reforms.6 As if that were not explicit enough, our moderator, Giancarlo Corsetti, has joined with an impressive array of authors in a recent CESifo report to argue that the emphasis in the debate should be on crisis response and – and I quote – ‘under no circumstances should the eurozone move to Eurobonds as advocated by some European Page 2 of 9 politicians and commentators’ because such ‘Eurobonds [would] do nothing but strengthen incentives for opportunistic behavior on the part of debtors and creditors.’7 My goal in this context is simply to suggest that there are ways to design the Eurobonds that mitigate such objections. The starting point is not the eurobond proposal itself but the challenges that the proposal is meant to address: First, European fiscal policy coordination has not resulted in sufficient discipline or even an adequate level of transparency in fiscal accounting practices. This was true long before the current crisis and implicates France and Germany as well as Portugal and Greece. Moreover, there is little evidence to suggest that the recent reforms to the procedures for European macroeconomic governance – the ‘European semester’ and the ‘Euro-plus Pact’ are going to be enough to make a difference. Second, the rapid pace of nominal interest rate convergence prior to monetary union and the low nominal interest rate differentials charged during the first years of the euro suggest that sovereign debt markets in Europe have significant potential to mis-price underlying default risk. Moreover, this is not simply a function of poor information; it derives from the interaction between financial market integration and monetary union – hence it is likely to recur should politicians succeed in restoring market confidence. Third, the cost of imposing discipline in European sovereign debt markets greatly exceeds the danger of moral hazard at any given point in time. Although there are clear incentives to ‘teach’ market actors not to underestimate sovereign default risk in the future (and sovereign borrowers not to overestimate their access to the markets), the impact of restructuring sovereign debt in the eurozone would be considerable. Moreover, the difference between benefit and cost increases Page 3 of 9 dramatically as member countries get deeper into trouble – which means that some form of bailout under the current arrangements is almost inevitable no matter how much it may be unpopular with one or another member state electorates. The difficult decisions taken with respect to Greece just this weekend reflect that fact. So the challenge is to discipline the member states while stabilizing financial markets and avoiding moral hazard: Governments should borrow responsibly, financial actors should pay attention to risk, and both borrowers and lenders should be accountable for their decisions. I am sure that there is no-one on this panel who would refuse to sign up to this agenda. The question is whether a common eurobond provides the best instrument for achieving those shared objectives. Certainly a bond that allows a country like Greece to borrow as much as or more relative to annual output than a country like Germany without paying higher interest rates until it is too late would not provide an acceptable solution. That is what got us into this mess in the first place – as Giancarlo Corsetti and his colleagues are correct to insist. Therefore it is important that any eurobond proposal come with ‘strict conditionality’: governments who want to raise resources with such an instrument should accept tight restrictions on their borrowing. The eurobond proposal put forward by Jean-Claude Juncker and Giulio Tremonti last December sets the limit at 40 percent of GDP. But that is likely to be too restrictive because too many countries would find significant needs unmet. The Maastricht Treaty provides a higher threshold for responsible borrowing – at 60 percent of GDP. This seems more realistic. For those worried about such a high threshold, it would be possible to charge increasing premia on debt issued ever closer to that limit. This is consistent with the spirit of the original De GrauweMoesen plan and with the synthetic proposal that De Grauwe has made in the more recent publication I mentioned. Page 4 of 9 But the real incentive to avoid excessive indebtedness comes when a government needs to borrow beyond the maximum limit. Such borrowing would not be available through common eurobonds, it would have to be made using strictly national debt instruments, and it would come at a significant market premium because it would provide a clear signal to the markets of a government’s excessive indebtedness; to reinforce that signal, we could also require that borrowing in national debt instruments above the threshold for financing through eurobonds would be ‘junior’ in terms of repayment to the ‘senior’ common debt instruments. This is in line with the Delpla-von Weizsäcker plan. Additional advantages come from the ‘strict conditionality’ for participation. Governments that choose to issue the eurobonds could face much more intrusive auditing of their accounts, just like firms that list on a public stock exchange. They could have much stricter reporting and financial planning requirements, going beyond even the ‘European semester’. And they could face a real administrative sanction in the form of restricted access to common eurobond financing should they refuse to comply with policy recommendations related to fiscal consolidation. Moreover, the strength of the proposal lies in the fact that governments would have to accept such conditionality voluntarily in order to get access to common financing instruments. Mr Mersch believes we should focus on structural reforms – and he is right. But to do so we need larger carrots in addition to larger sticks. A common eurobond offers both measures. This brings us to the market pricing of risk. Part of this story has already been addressed through the limits on borrowing, the improved market signaling, and the higher requirements for transparency. At this point we should also introduce a structural dimension. Sovereign debt is used in liquidity operations between private sector financial institutions and the correspondent institutions of the European System of Central Banks. More simply, banks use sovereign debt as collateral when they Page 5 of 9 need to get access to cash. In turn, this means that there is always some demand for sovereign debt instruments. Bank treasurers responsible for negotiating interest rate swap contracts were very aware of that fact and they took advantage of the solid demand for sovereign debt instruments across the eurozone in designing and implementing their convergence trading strategies in the 1990s. The notional value of these swaps greatly exceeded the volume of sovereign debt instruments in circulation. And bank treasurers I have spoken with are convinced that it was the trade in derivatives rather than the trade in sovereign bonds that brought about the convergence of nominal interest rates. By implication, the derivatives markets and sovereign debt markets are tightly inter-connected. There is considerable direct exposure in the financial system to sovereign debt instruments as well – particularly on the banking books of private sector financial institutions, where assets are supposed to be held to term and so, absent a credit event, are not marked to market. Paradoxically, when these banks come under stress and so require emergency liquidity from the European System of Central Banks, they tend to increase the size of their banking books and so increase their exposure to sovereign debt instruments as well. By the same token, the European Central Bank has little choice but to accept distressed sovereign debt instruments as collateral for bank liquidity operations. The decision of the ECB’s governing council last May to lift any rating requirement for the use of Greek sovereign debt as collateral is one illustration; the decision to lift ratings requirements for Ireland this March is another. The solution to all these concerns is to make common Eurobonds eligible for banks to hold on their banking books to use as collateral for liquidity but to apply strict limits on the eligibility for any other type of sovereign bond. Here again, the eurobond would provide a clear signal to the markets – meaning not only bond traders but bank treasurers and Page 6 of 9 central bankers as well. In turn, that signal will help them better to price in associated risk. This brings me to the final point about moral hazard and bailouts. Right now it is hard to imagine how the eurozone can easily afford a sovereign default. This is the point that many commentators have made repeatedly over the past few weeks. Any credit event would force bank treasurers holding distressed sovereign debt instruments to mark those assets to market and so absorb a significant capital loss. The correspondent institutions of the European System of Central Banks would have to absorb capital losses due to their exposure to distressed sovereign debt instruments as well – and the ECB may have to call for new capital from its members as a result. That is why the pressure to avoid a restructuring is so intense and it is an open question whether so-called ‘soft’ forms of restructuring like a maturity extension would be enough to dodge the bullet. Standard & Poor’s made it clear this past weekend that any soft restructuring would constitute default. A common eurobond could resolve this dilemma and so make it easier for countries to engage in an orderly restructuring. The ‘senior’ eurobonds would continue to rollover even if the national bonds used for excessive borrowing were brought into technical default. In turn this would make it more likely that private sector actors could participate in the losses without any adverse systemic implications; they could take the hit without threatening to bring the whole financial system grinding to a halt. Most important of all, private sector investors would be well-aware of their exposure to this possibility before they made the investments in the first place. As things stand now, there is simply too much systemic risk for politicians to insist on an orderly restructuring of sovereign borrowing in countries like Greece and Ireland. The only recourse is to bail those countries out – and to keep renegotiating the bailout packages until the markets can be convinced that a crisis has been averted. Unfortunately, Page 7 of 9 that is at best a short-term solution and it has significant medium-tolong-term implications. If it fails, the resulting crisis will be harder to manage; if it succeeds, the next crisis will be harder to avoid. Of course there are significant problems with the eurobond proposal – not least those associated with its implementation. Daniel Gros has written persuasively about the difficulty associated with introducing new instruments that have seniority into a pool of debt that is nearing default.8 I think these implementation issues are worthy of discussion and have a few ideas about where that discussion should start. Nevertheless, Mr Mersch is right to insist that we consider ‘first things first’ and so it is worth reasserting the basic objectives. If we agree that countries should be more disciplined and transparent in their fiscal policies; that markets should be more efficient and effective in pricing in risk; and that moral hazard should be avoided so that stability can be maintained without unpopular bailouts; then we must first decide what is the best route to achieve those objectives. Even reformed and reinforced, the current architecture for European macroeconomic governance offers no guarantee of discipline. Given the market opportunities associated with financial integration and monetary union, a crisis resolution mechanism will not improve market pricing of sovereign default risk. And nothing proposed so far promises to deal with the moral hazard emerging alongside the fragility of Europe’s integration financial system. No matter how difficult it may be to implement, a common eurobond offers the prospect of resolving these dilemmas. Hence the first step is to choose whether to embrace that solution or to engineer an equally promising alternative. Thank you for your attention. Page 8 of 9 Notes 1. http://www.ceps.eu/book/gains-all-proposal-common-eurobond 2. http://www.econ.kuleuven.be/ew/academic/intecon/Degrauwe/PDG-papers/Discussion_papers/G overnance-fragile-eurozone_s.pdf 3. http://www.ilsole24ore.com/art/commenti-e-idee/2010-12-22/eurobond-interesse-tedesco-23250 9.shtml?uuid=AYmTi1tC 4. http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2011/html/sp110311.en.html 5. http://ideas.repec.org/p/mkg/wpaper/1002.html 6. http://imarketnews.com/node/23761 7. http://www.voxeu.com/index.php?q=node/6199 8. http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/5891 Page 9 of 9 Keynote Address EU-Business Forum on Financial Services Thursday, 2 June 2011 New Brunswick, New Jersey Erik Jones Professor of European Studies SAIS Bologna Center and Director Bologna Institute for Policy Research Page 1 of 13 Keynote Address Good afternoon and many thanks for allowing me to interrupt your lunch at the close of such an interesting morning conference. It is a real privilege to address this group and to follow the conversation that was started by esteemed colleagues from the private sector, the think tank world, and academe. I am particularly pleased to see a representative of the German government. The worlds of business, research, and policymaking should intertwine more often in such productive ways. If I were to give a proper title for my remarks other than ‘keynote address’, I would probably call the give the talk some hackneyed name like ‘Hobson’s Choice’, ‘Scylla and Charybdis’, ‘Between a Rock and a Hard Place’, or ‘The Devil and the Deep Blue Sea’. Anyone of those cliches would capture the basic message which is that Europeans confront a clutch of problems with no easy or obvious solutions. Worse, as these problems have become ever more tightly tangled together, the stakes have continued to rise. Hence we now face alternatives that were once considered completely unrealistic and yet must be accepted as legitimate prospects. Here I am talking about the possibility of a sovereign default in Europe, the collapse of one or more national banking systems, the exit of one or more countries from the eurozone, and the breakup of the euro as a common currency. Please understand that I do not welcome these possibilities and I am not eager to engage in fearmongering or doom-saying. On the contrary, I have spent most of my professional life explaining why I believe that the European Union’s economic and monetary union is much stronger than most analysts ever imagined it could be, how it is very unlikely to fail or even to splinter, why the eurozone should be larger and not smaller, and how any government would have to be crazy to try and restore its national currency. Page 2 of 13 Nevertheless, I have to admit that Europe’s political, economic, and financial leaders have backed themselves into a corner by refusing to take decisive action early on as this situation developed. Along the way, they have managed to frighten each other, the markets, and their own people. As a consequence they have nurtured opposition to institutional reforms that could not only resolve the crisis but also prevent it from recurring. This indictment is sweeping and I should point out that academics, journalists, and policy analysts – in other words, people like me – share in the responsibility for the mess we find ourselves in today. Our contributing role is to rely too heavily on theory and too little on data or experience. As a community, we tend to speak in terms of standard concepts and models – fitting the world into abstract packages that we already think we understand. This tendency has not been fruitful for the policy debate. On the contrary, we have managed not only to mis-diagnose the problem but also to prescribe solutions that have made the situation worse. In doing so, we have failed our core ambition to inform effective policy; the world is not a better place for our efforts. Of course I say ‘we’ but that is really just a false modesty. They were wrong and I was right all along. And if only they had listened to me, you would be enjoying your lunch while we talked about more cheerful thinks like global warming or the upcoming Republican primaries. Now let me explain why. My story is structured in five parts. For those of you who like to count, I should caution that each part is longer than the one preceding it. First, the problem – if that is what we really want to call it – is not the single currency. It is financial market integration. And ‘the problem’ is that financial market integration worked better than we could have imagined. Think about it, the goal of financial market integration is to help channel capital from places where it is less productive to places where it is more productive. In plain English, that means that money should flow where it can find the highest rate of return. When this Page 3 of 13 process started in Europe in the early 1990s, the standard deviation across bid yields on ten-year sovereign bonds in the countries that would later form the eurozone was close to 5 percentage points. Between 1993 and 1998, that variation fell to just 1 percentage point. And when the euro started in 1999 it was down to less than one-half of one percent. It didn’t take huge volumes of capital flowing across countries to compress interest rates this way. As one prominent European bank treasurer who was active during the period explained it to me, much of this convergence was achieved through trading in interest rate swap contracts between banks working within the same national markets. And while the notional values of these contracts swelled dramatically, the actual payments made were much smaller and the net payments much smaller still. Second, interest rate convergence in Europe’s integrated financial marketplace increased the significance of very small differences in rates of return. The resulting ‘hunt for yield’ was a question of volume. There is no big surprise there. Nevertheless it had implications that were not fully appreciated before the fact. The most important implication is that you tend to get a lot more bad lending in markets where interest rates fall dramatically than where they remain relatively stable – even if the quantity of potential lending available in both countries increases by equal measure. One of my colleagues, Filippo Taddei, has an elegant formal model that uses information asymmetries to explain why this is the case. In his model, banks flush with cash look to book out loans. Where they have already saturated the market – by which I mean, where they have already loaned out money to everyone willing to borrow money at the prevailing market rate – then there are likely to be few takers for fresh loans. The dodgy investors willing to take a risk on loans at that rate have already been weeded out either by scrupulous bankers or by inexorable market forces. Page 4 of 13 Where interest rates have fallen dramatically, by contrast, there will be many who suddenly want to borrow. Unfortunately, many of these new customers will not be able to repay the money they borrow. The banks in Taddei’s model cannot tell the difference between good potential customers and bad ones – this is the information asymmetry. They will weed out some of the dodgy customers, but many more will slip through the cracks. The implication is that the growth in lending results in an increase in bad assets, even where lending standards remain unchanged. A good illustration of this would be Sean Fitzpatrick’s rapid expansion of the Anglo-Irish bank. Fitzpatrick grew his bank on the principle of quick decision-making. He would charge slightly higher rates of interest than his competitors but he would get you the loan quicker – sometimes even the same day. As interest rates declined across the Irish market, this business practice made it easy for Fitzpatrick to outgrow his competitors. They grew along with the expansion of the market, but he grew faster because he responded more quickly and so led the curve. It also meant that Fitzpatrick wound up with an increasingly problematic asset book. Of course we could blame Fitzpatrick’s low lending standards for his predicament, but that would not be entirely accurate. Fitzpatrick knew his market and his customers, and he did business with some of the best names in Ireland. Even if Fitzpatrick’s standards were relatively high, the odds were stacked against him and so it was inevitable that he would accumulate bad debts. This stacking of the odds or ‘adverse selection bias’ is the essential finding of Taddei’s analysis. The third step in the story is the growing variation across countries in the balance between savings and investment. Some countries will save more than they invest and export the difference to other countries that will invest more than they save. The countries that have historically had low interest rates will become the international lenders; the countries where interest rates were high will borrow. Again that was always the goal of international financial integration – to break the cross-country correlation between savings and investment. Page 5 of 13 The measure of this difference in roles across countries – net savers lending money on the one hand and net investors borrowing money on the other hand – shows up in the flow of goods and services and so is captured in the balance on current accounts. If a country saves more than it invests, it must be exporting more than it consumes and if a country invests more than it saves, it must be absorbing more imports than exports. Put another way, when the capital account is in surplus because money is flowing into the country from abroad, then the current account must show an offsetting deficit for the country’s international payments position to balance. This change in current account performance does not necessarily happen immediately but it will eventually show up during the process of financial market integration and nominal interest rate convergence; it is the balance of payments expression of the hunt for yield across countries; it is the elimination of the Feldstein-Horioka puzzle. Hence if we take the standard deviation across countries of current account balances as a percentage of gross domestic product we will find that it fluctuates between three and three-and-a-half percentage points for the future eurozone countries between 1991 and 1998. Between 1998 and 2000, that variation almost doubled to more than six percentage points where it stayed until the middle of the last decade; between 2005 and 2007, it jumped again from six to eight percentage points. What this means in practical terms is that some countries – like Greece, Portugal, and Spain ran up increasingly large deficits while others like Austria, Germany, and the Netherlands ran large surpluses. The point to keep in mind, is that these changes in relative current account positions had very little to do with relative cost competitiveness – at least for the deficit countries. They were driven by capital flows and not the price elasticity of demand for any given country’s goods and services. You can see this immediately when looking at the correlation, timing, and magnitude of the changes involved. Let me give you an example. Between 1997 and 2001, Greece’s real effective exchange rate relative to the fifteen West Page 6 of 13 European member states of the European Union depreciated by seven percent. In other words, the Greece became more competitive and not less during the five year period. Meanwhile, the country’s current account deficit increased from just under two percent of gross domestic product to between eleven and twelve percent of gross domestic product. Greece became competitive but the impact of its increased net borrowing more than overwhelmed any trade effects. The situation in Austria and Germany reveals the scale of the contrast. Austria’s real effective exchange rate depreciated by four percent and Germany’s real effective exchange rate depreciated by six percent between 1997 and 2001. In other words, both countries gained competitiveness, Austria less than Germany and Germany less than Greece. The change in current account performance nevertheless, went the other way around. Austria’s current account deficit contracted from 2.3 percent of GDP to just under 0.8 percent, and Germany’s current account deficit decreased from 0.5 percent of GDP to very close to balance. We can go deeper into this competitiveness discussion during the question and answer period. My point is that it is ancillary to the problem we face now and I am happy to give you the data to explain why I believe that to be the case. For the moment, though, I’d like to move to the fourth step in the problem. This step is going to be very familiar to those of you working in U.S. financial markets because it looks a lot like the liquidity glut that Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernancke has complained about coming from countries in Asia and the Middle East to the United States. The combination of low interest rates, adverse selection, and huge lending volumes led to asset bubbles that manifested differently from one part of the eurozone to the next. The bubble formed in government paper in Greece, real estate in Spain and Ireland, and consumer credit in Portugal. These were obviously not the only countries to experience asset Page 7 of 13 bubbles. House prices also rose dramatically in the Netherlands and the UK, for example, not to mention the countries of Central and Eastern Europe or the Baltic States. Not all of the bubbles that formed resulted in crises – hence, the Dutch housing market came in for a relatively soft landing. And not every country that experienced bubbles experienced them in all categories of assets. Italy’s housing is expensive, and the cost has risen significantly with the greater accessibility and lower cost of home mortgages, but I would not describe it as a bubble. So my point is only that the combination of factors emerging out of financial market integration was one source of asset bubbles that were also being experienced elsewhere for other reasons. The fact that it is one source, however, is an important concession. If you have one source of a problem that manifests differently in different countries, then you also have a potential source of correlation. If for whatever reason the effects of financial market integration – the reduction in interest rates and the change in the volume or direction of international capital flows – were to be thrown into reverse, then the different bubbles in different parts of the eurozone would suddenly have to deflate and the adverse selection in lending practices within those countries where interest rates fell significantly would suddenly appear in sharp relief. This point about implicit correlation was made in 2002 by a PierreOlivier Gourinchas in his comments on a paper about financial market integration published by Brookings. Gourinchas made it clear then that the Europeans had created a system where countries like Greece, Ireland, Spain and Portugal could find themselves suddenly without access to international credit. Since their capital accounts would lurch into balance, their current account positions would have to balance as well. The net effects of such a shut-down are all around us. You can see it in the rapid rise in unemployment and housing defaults – even in countries like Ireland and Spain where it is very painful and difficult to go through personal bankruptcy. You can see it in the simmering popular discontent as well. The current Greek government Page 8 of 13 was elected to escape austerity and not to impose it. The current Irish government was elected primarily to throw the other bums out. But it is the fifth part of my story that is the most worrying because it connects the process of financial market integration to the wider patterns of European macroeconomic governance. You should note at this point that I have not talked much about fiscal discipline or excessive government borrowing. I talked a bit about the bubble in Greek government paper, but most of the conversation has not been about government debts or deficits. That is not a professional bias. On the contrary, I came to this story because I work on macroeconomic governance. In 2002 and 2003, I wrote a series of papers warning about the real potential for excessive borrowing should European governments relax the rules for fiscal discipline – known collectively as the ‘stability and growth pact’ – and should smaller countries like Greece choose to take advantage of the increased creditworthiness and relaxed current account constraints. Instead, the French and German governments colluded to hold the excessive deficit procedure at the heart of the stability and growth pact ‘in abeyance’. This could be a big ‘I told you so’ moment for me. But the fact of the matter is, I got it wrong. Greece is the exception. So, for that matter, is Hungary. Countries like Ireland, Latvia, Portugal, and Spain are closer to the rule. You see there really is no choice between defaulting on your debts and remaining in the single currency. If a country – like Greece – tries to leave the euro in order to default, it will only make its situation worse and not better. So even if small countries do take advantage of their enhanced creditworthiness to run up huge debts and deficits, ultimately they realize that they will have to pay it all back. That is why successive Greek governments have reluctantly admitted the need for austerity. They know as well as everyone else that they cannot keep borrowing forever. I know there are some doubters on this point – particularly at Moody’s where they have just downgraded Greek sovereign obligations to a level that corresponds with roughly a fifty percent chance of default. But I think it is a fair bet to say that Page 9 of 13 the Greeks would much rather pay back their debts than either leave the eurozone or default. Where my story intersects with macroeconomic governance is not through excessive debts and deficits. Rather it is through the extraordinary mechanisms that member state governments and European institutions are willing to go in order to prevent damage from occurring to systemically important banks or to national banking systems writ large. The Dutch government’s nationalization of Fortis Netherlands is one example, the Belgian government’s rushed bailout of Fortis holding is another. Then there are the spate of bank recapitalizations that started in Britain and spread across the Continent (apart from Italy, where Silvio Berlusconi and Giulio Tremonti shoved UniCredit into the arms of Muammar Ghaddafi and his Libyan sovereign wealth fund). We could also list the ECB’s decisions to suspend the tightening of its collateral rules in September 2008; the relaxation of any rating requirement for Greece in May 2010 or Ireland in March of this year; and the decision to intervene directly in secondary sovereign debt markets. These decisions were all taken for the same fundamental reason: to shore up systemically important banks or national banking systems. And they all contributed to the same basic phenomenon: national governments became more indebted even as the European System of Central Banks became more heavily exposed to sovereign debt. This was fine so long as the markets remained confident in the ability of national governments and European institutions to manage the situation. It stopped being acceptable once that confidence began to evaporate and Europe’s ability to agree on a solution and then implement it effectively came into doubt. This is where the Hobson’s Choice part of the conversation becomes apparent – and so I promise that I am working toward a conclusion. A Hobson’s Choice is a choice with zero degrees of freedom. I worry that we are backing into that situation right now. The European Central Bank cannot continue to increase its exposure to sovereign Page 10 of 13 debt indefinitely and it cannot accept the consequences should one or another sovereign entities go into default. Hence its only choice is to find some way to limit its exposure without experiencing a ‘credit event’. That is why the ECB is so reluctant to accept any re-profiling in Greece. And it is also why it is so worried about further contagion from Greece to Ireland or Portugal, where it faces a very similar situation. The governments of the highly indebted countries cannot accept to pay the interest that would be charged in the market for their debt and yet they cannot risk the consequences of a default for their domestic banking systems either – because they cannot see any alternative to the public sector as a source of banking capital. So if they want to keep their banks alive, they have to maintain access to credit markets and somehow lower the cost of borrowing. The question is whether this will be easier inside or outside the single currency. So long as the ESCB remains committed to providing liquidity to distressed national banking systems, the answer is clearly ‘in’. Should the ECB restrict access to liquidity, the balance could shift to ‘out’. The governments of the net creditor countries have problems of their own. Their own banks are exposed to the consequences of financial market integration and require fresh injections of capital as well. They have to worry that central banking activities will start a round of inflation that could eat into the real value of their savings. And they have all the political problems associated with making sure they get their money back. A comment made by the Luxembourg Central Banker, Yves Mersch, last May helps to put their situation into context. He insisted that the fundamental principle of the market economy is that you pay back your debts. He might have added that you also must accept the consequences of your decisions. That is why the creditor countries are so eager to see Greece meet its obligations or – at a minimum – the private sector absorb any losses. The trick is to find some formula to satisfy all three positions at once. We have to lower the risk associated with central banking activities Page 11 of 13 without jeopardizing the stability of systemically important banks or national banking systems. We have to lower the debt service requirements for highly indebted countries so that they can afford to recapitalize their domestic banks while at the same time paying back their debts. And we have to create a framework that prevents this situation from recurring by avoiding moral hazard. This framework cannot eliminate risk and so it must channel it in such a manner as to clarify the relationship between risk and return. Most important, it must ensure that there is a transparent and equitable distribution of the burdens associated with any loss. This is a tall order and it is where I will leave you to ponder over your desert. As I mentioned at the outset, there is an institutional solution that can resolve this problem. That is the creation of a eurobond with limited drawing rights. This solution flies under a number of different flags, it has been proposed by several think tanks, and it has attracted support from government leaders, central bankers, and the European Parliament. Moreover, it is a solution that works alongside and strengthens the financial market integration that we wanted, that worked better than we expected, and that got us into this mess in the first place. I would be happy to go into the mechanics of the proposal but your coffee is probably getting cold and I have already gone on a bit too long. The basic point is that Europeans are either going to have to look at the bright side of introducing a common eurobond or they are going to have to confront as series of ever more unpalatable alternatives: sovereign debt restructuring, banking system crisis, eurozone exit, or breakup of the euro. The bright side is pretty bright. We can organize a system to make sure that countries like Greece pay back their debts in full an on time. Even if that part doesn’t work, we can at least create the conditions for an orderly restructuring that does not bring down the Greek banking system as a whole. We can insulate the European System of Central Banks from unnecessary losses on its existing assets and we Page 12 of 13 can prevent it from having to loosen its collateral rules again in the future. Finally, we can make it easier for net lending countries to recognize and appreciate the risks they are assuming when sending their money abroad. The arguments against the creation of a eurobond are mistaken if not misleading. Such an instrument would not imply a transfer from rich to poor or from boom to bust. That is what we do through financial market integration in the present system – and with consequences that are now readily apparent. A common eurobond would not raise the cost of sovereign borrowing in the creditor countries either – because borrowing costs are relative, because it would be the single must liquid and creditworthy asset in the eurozone, and because it would offer a real alternative to dollar denominated obligations at a time when the United States is uniquely under challenge. Of course Europeans do not all agree on this eurobond proposal. But they do not agree on any workable alternative either. Moreover, it is not something that they can sweep under the carpet – as the recent show-down between the IMF , the ECB and the ratings agencies makes apparent. Europe is caught between a rock and a hard place, it must sail between Scylla and Charybdis to confront either the Devil or the deep blue sea. Bluntly, Europeans are being asked to face a Hobson’s Choice, which is a choice that is not a choice. It is time for Europeans to start thinking outside the box. Many thanks for your attention. Page 13 of 13 Muddling through the sovereign debt crisis (1) In the first part of a two-part analysis on Europe’s sovereign debt crisis, Erik Jones cautions against the extreme scenarios being advanced by leading commentators A heavy burden to carry: Greek Prime Minister George Papandreou is under intense scrutiny. Photo: Wikimedia Commons Newspaper columnists like the Financial Times' Wolfgang Munchau (FT, 5 and 12 June) and economics commentators like Nouriel Roubini (FT, 13 June) would have us believe that Europe will either emerge from the current sovereign debt crisis as a much more united political and economic union or it will fracture as one or more of the peripheral countries like Greece, Ireland, and Portugal are forced out of the euro. Although there are strong arguments to be made either way, the most likely scenario is less dramatic. Europe is neither going to unify nor founder in the wake of this crisis; instead it will continue to muddle through. The extreme views The points made my Munchau and Roubini (among many others) are worth taking seriously. Munchau claims that there is no way to avoid a crisis that does not lead somehow toward common European fiscal institutions. Greece cannot pay back its debts unless it can convince the markets to accept a reasonable rate of interest; the markets will only reduce the rate of interest they charge to Greece if there is some external guarantee from some other more credit-worthy country - like Germany - that money lent will come back; Germany will only extend that guarantee if it has assurances that the Greeks will pay their taxes; and Greece will only provide those assurances if other countries - including Germany – offer similar guarantees as well. Following the logic of this chain of reasoning, Germany will ultimately face the choice between some basic level of fiscal federalism in Europe or an unstructured sovereign debt default in Greece that could bring the German banking system down as well. The technical requirements for amending the European treaties are easily met and so it is plausible to assume that the Germans will prefer closer European Union to another Lehman-Brothers type of experience. Roubini is less sanguine in his assessment of the prospects for political union and correspondingly more pessimistic about the reasonableness of the Germans. Hence the likelihood is high that Greece will face a sovereign default that could not only damage its domestic banking system but also leave it locked out of credit markets for an extended period of time. The alternative of ever tighter austerity is only marginally more attractive because it means very slow growth in output and incomes for the Greek economy as a whole. Meanwhile, the country suffers from a lack of international competitiveness that cannot be rectified so long as its prices and wages are denominated in euros. Hence Roubini and others argue that it would be easier to accept the inevitable and exit the monetary union: this would do no more damage than an unstructured default and it at least offers the prospect of shortening the period of price and wage adjustments that must be achieved under any circumstances. The more realistic scenario Both perspectives are right and both perspectives are wrong. They are right insofar as they rest on an accurate diagnosis of the market conundrum. Greece can pay its debts but not the cost of servicing them, and those servicing costs are more likely to go up than to go down. This is why the ratings agencies continue to downgrade Greece; it explains how the ratings downgrades feed back into a negative selffulfilling prophecy as well. The lower the rating becomes, the more market confidence in Greece deteriorates, and the less market participants want to trade in Greek sovereign debt. They are right to be pessimistic about popular attitudes in Germany toward a fiscal union as well. The Germans are united in rejecting what they view as a 'transfer union' from North to South - and they are hardly alone in that sentiment. The Austrians, the Dutch, the Finns, the Swedes, and the Slovaks all reject such a possibility as well. More important, such transfers tend to erode political union within countries like Belgium, Italy, and Spain. Hence it is hard to imagine how they could promote political unification at the European level. Where the extreme views are wrong is in their assessment of what a default would entail and how much effort is necessary to organize a bailout. Here the European Central Bank has an important story to tell. ECB members like Lorenzo Bini-Smaghi have been consistent in maintaining that any sovereign default would have unacceptable consequences. The direct effect would be to wipe out the capital of the affected country's own banking system; it would likely make a big dent in the capital of the ECB as well. And indirectly it would impose losses across Europe and North America, further cutting into bank capital at a time when financial institutions are struggling to meet higher requirements for solvency. This would have a chilling effect on confidence in inter-bank markets with long-term implications that are impossible to anticipate. In other words, sovereign debt markets for countries like Greece, Ireland, and Portugal are simply too big to fail. The solution is simply to bail out both those governments that are in trouble and the banks that hold their debt. Ideally, this would be done without creating a 'credit event' - a change in the ratings or related characteristics of sovereign bonds that would implicate technical definitions of default used in derivatives contracts and for prudential oversight. This is essentially what has happened in the successive Greek bailouts, in the European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF), through various changes in ECB collateral rules, and through the ECB's direct purchase of sovereign bonds in secondary markets. It is also what should take place in the planned European Stability Mechanism (ESM). The only debate is about whether the private sector should share in any losses resulting from sovereign debt restructuring and whether such losses would constitute a credit event. The German government says that the banks should pay at least as much as taxpayers; the ECB and the ratings agencies insist that this would be tantamount to default. It was always far easier to imagine Germany backing down on this issue than jumping from the threat of default to the construction of common fiscal institutions. That is in fact what we got with the most recent round of proposals. And that is what muddling through is all about. 06/07/2011 Erik Jones Comments A nna Pichoir Sounds lik e we are all going to m uddle through on a le viatha n vassa l a nd survive as be st we ca n. Don't e x pe ct m iracle s e x ce pt te ctonic change s according to Christine Lagarde , the ne w dire ctor of IMF. 08/07/2011 Share | Muddling through the sovereign debt crisis (2) Erik Jones concludes his analysis by calling for the creation of eurobonds The name is Bond, Eurobond: Italy’s economy and finance minister, Giulio Tremonti, is one of many experts calling for this new instrument. Photo: Wikimedia Commons Muddling through may not be very dramatic and yet it is fraught with risk - which is why writers like Wolfgang Munchau and Nouriel Roubini look hard for some alternative. Europe will face moments of high tension, with severe consequences should European politicians fail to organize an appropriate response. As the ratings agencies continue their relentless downgrades of European sovereign borrowers and warnings of impending default, the pressure will only continue to mount. Nevertheless, the balance of forces is likely to prevent movement toward the extremes of political unification or disintegration. European integration has gone far enough to be too difficult to reverse, and yet Europe's citizens are unwilling to see it progress very much further. Implications The economic implications of muddling through are important. In the short term, muddling through will fuel volatility in financial markets - particularly as key institutions come into conflict with one another at the international level and member state governments face ever more heated opposition at home. The tension between the Council of Economic and Finance Ministers (ECOFIN Council) over private sector participation is one example; the possibility of an unfavourable ruling on the legality of the first Greek bailout by the German Constitutional Court is another. The bottom line is that things could still go very wrong. Negotiations over the precise details of the different bailout agreements could founder. Popular unrest either in the peripheral countries or in the core could undermine necessary reforms. A further slowdown in the United States economy could chip away at market confidence. Violence could spread across North Africa and into the more volatile regions of the Arab world. In other words, just about any strong shock could tip Europe's current strategy for dealing with the sovereign debt crisis out of balance. In the medium-to-longer term, muddling through will strengthen the divergence between Europe's core and its periphery, even as it reduces the pace of economic activity overall. Growth in core Europe will slow as a result of the crisis; growth in the periphery will weaken even further. Meanwhile, the heightened sense that European financial markets could go badly very quickly weakens confidence in the European economy as a whole. The consequences are all around us. They can be found in volatility of sovereign debt prices and in the decline in producer confidence in April and May this year. The risks associated with tragic miscalculation dominate the headlines and they also create caution in the board room. This not only slows the pace of investment but also hinders the prospects for future growth. Imagining a Better World Things do not have to be so fragile. Indeed, there is a proposal floating around that could offer a solution to the sovereign debt problem. This is the proposal for a common European sovereign debt obligation - a Eurobond - that would be jointly issued in order to ensure market confidence but would also provide only limited drawing rights for participating countries to avoid abuse. This proposal was floated most prominently by Giulio Tremonti in an editorial he co-authored with Jean-Claude Juncker last December. In various and subtly different guises, the idea has attracted support from Lorenzo Bini-Smaghi at the ECB and from the European Parliament as well. And it has reemerged most recently in a letter signed by Guy Verhofstadt, Giulio Amato, and a list of other European economic and political heavyweights. Best of all, it does not require excessive European unification in order to function. There is no need for a common fiscal authority and no implicit requirement for north-south transfers. Indeed, the proposal is not so different from the bonds issued by the European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF) and the European Stability Mechanism (ESM). A common eurobond simply offers a more equitable, stable, and transparent mechanism for doing much the same refinancing that is already in existence. Hence if muddling through is the most realistic prospect, there is at least one plausible and superior alternative. Moreover, this alternative is much closer to muddling through than either a dramatic step forward in the process of European integration or an even more dramatic unstructured sovereign default. The question now is whether Europe's heads of state and government have the courage to go down that route. 09/07/2011 Erik Jones Comments Share | 31 August 2011 1 September 2011 Framing the Eurobond Erik Jones(*) German opposition to the Eurobond proposal is intense. Whether you poll public opinion or survey editorials in the popular newspapers, the answer is always the same. The German people do not want to be responsible for the debts of the Greeks, Irish, Portuguese, Spanish, or the Italians. They do not want to run the risk that they could have to pay back the loans taken out by countries that appear to have borrowed irresponsibly. And they do not believe their parliamentarians should be allowed to make a decision that would be too painful to reverse. Joining the single currency was bad enough; Germany will not join a European ‘debt union’. This position is as clear as it is irrational – at least from the perspective of those who support the Eurobond proposal. To begin with, the original idea of having a Eurobond was to create market incentives for highly indebted countries to rein in their spending. The proposal sketched by Italian Economics Minister Giulio Tremonti and Luxembourg Prime Minister Jean-Claude Junker in a December 2010 editorial in the Financial Times offers good illustration. Countries would only be allowed to borrow cheaply in Eurobonds up to a certain share of their gross domestic product (GDP), they would get access to such borrowing under strict conditions, and they would commit to servicing those obligations first. Any additional borrowing would be much more expensive because it would be much riskier for investors. Hence there is an incentive for countries to stay within the limits. More to the point, Germany is already exposed to significant losses in the event of a default by Europe’s highly indebted countries, both directly and indirectly. In direct terms, German banks are the source of much of the lending at risk. German pension funds are heavily investing in now questionable sovereign debt as well. And Germany is a principal stakeholder in the European Central Bank, which holds the largest exposure of all. Indirectly, the German financial system is dependent on banks in other European countries for its funding; if those other banks take losses, German banks will have difficulties too. Finally, the introduction of Eurobonds should lower the risk of default. Right now the highly indebted countries are struggling because they cannot get access to private capital at affordable interest rates. Greece, Ireland, and Portugal have already been pushed out of the market; Spain and Italy are paying dearly to stay in. The more these countries have to pay for their borrowing, the more likely they are to be forced to write down the principal of their debts. Greece spent most of the summer trying to avoid this outcome; now it appears to be inevitable. Market speculators are betting that other countries will soon follow. And that market speculation results in higher interest rates that in turn make some sort of default more likely. In other words, German opposition to the Eurobond proposal is irrational from the perspective of Eurobond-supporters because the introduction of Eurobonds will increase fiscal discipline in highly indebted countries, shield Germany from losses on the borrowing that has already taken place, and weaken the The opinions expressed herein are strictly personal and do not necessarily reflect the position of ISPI. (*) Erik Jones, Professor of European Studies and Director Bologna Institute for Policy Research Paul H. Nitze School of Advanced International Studies (SAIS), Bologna Center, The Johns Hopkins University. 2 ISPI - Commentary influence of speculation in the marketplace. But being irrational from one perspective does not make the German position irrational full stop. On the contrary, German opponents of the Eurobond say they fear such an instrument will force them to accept risks in the future; they would rather simply take their losses now than face that uncertain fate. For supporters of Eurobonds, the losses now appear large and the risks in the future appear smaller; for the Germans themselves the weights are the other way around. This distinction between opponents and proponents of the Eurobond proposal may seem irrational but it is not. On the contrary, it is a fairly standard problem in behavioral economics – as demonstrated by Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky in their Nobel prize-winning research on ‘prospect theory’. [Only Kahneman received the prize in 2002 because the Nobel committee will not recognize scholars postmortem; Tversky passed away in 1996.] Kahneman and Tversky showed that people respond differently to losses and gains, even when the expected value of the outcomes is precisely the same. The idea is simple. When confronted with uncertainty about the risks involved, people will tend to exaggerate losses. In the Eurobond example, the Germans can raise any number of questions. How can we be sure that access to the bonds will be limited? What mechanism will be used to make sure that the highly indebted countries pay back their Eurobonds first? What will happen if investors take fright and stop refinancing these Eurobonds? Such questions give rise to uncertainty which only increases over time. As a consequence, the perceived risk that the Germans will have to cover losses on Eurobonds issued on behalf of Greece, Ireland, Portugal, etc., increases disproportionately. And psychological opposition to the Eurobond proposal increases as well. The Germans would rather cut their losses today than face the prospect of such exposure in an uncertain future. For proponents of the Eurobond, the calculus works the other way around. Faced with precisely the same level of uncertainty, they focus on the concrete advantages in the present and pay less attention to the implications of future conditions. Here we should return to the point about fiscal discipline. Right now it is relatively easy for supporters of Eurobonds to discount the implications of constrained access to cheap bond financing. The most important point is to reduce the cost of debt servicing in the present. That is the immediate gain. The market discipline they will face in future public finances can be dealt with later. The other insight from ‘prospect theory’ is that the emotions surrounding the fear of loss are stronger than those surrounding the prospect of gain. That explains why the Germans are so much more passionate in rejecting Eurobonds than anyone else is about supporting the proposal. It explains why the Germans are easier to mobilize and more vocal in expressing their opinions as well. Editors can sell more newspapers running against Eurobonds in Germany than writing in favor of them in Greece, Ireland, or Spain. Turning this situation around will be a challenge. To begin with, European politicians will have to reframe the German debate to emphasize the gains to Germany from the introduction of Eurobonds and to minimize the uncertainty surrounding potential future losses. This will require concrete concessions from highly indebted countries about their willingness to control spending in the future. The recent move to introduce formal constraints on debts and deficits into national legislation is part of this re-framing effort. Such constraints may not make much sense for a Keynesian economist, but they offer critical psychological support. A more difficult part of the re-framing will be to convince the German people that the introduction of Eurobonds will result in gains. This will require concessions as well. What the Germans want to hear is that the highly indebted countries will fulfil their obligations. They want to see real evidence that existing sovereign debt will be paid back in full and on time. Such re-framing of the argument excludes the possibility for any restructuring – because restructuring means that creditors experience a loss and not a gain. Only a firm commitment to repay can change the terms of the debate. 3 ISPI - Commentary Fortunately, the Eurobond proposals floated by Tremonti and others can meet both sides of this re-framing effort. They create a market discipline that is consistent with formal debt and deficit requirements and they lower the cost of debt servicing enough to make it possible for highly indebted countries to meet their obligations in full. The trick now is for European politicians to strengthen this message. They can change the terms of the debate. And once they do, they will discover that even staunch German opposition can be overcome after all. La ricerca ISPI analizza le dinamiche politiche, strategiche ed economiche del sistema internazionale con il duplice obiettivo di informare e di orientare le scelte di policy. I risultati della ricerca vengono divulgati attraverso pubblicazioni ed eventi, focalizzati su tematiche di particolare interesse per l’Italia e le sue relazioni internazionali. Le pubblicazioni online dell’ISPI sono realizzate anche grazie al sostegno della Fondazione Cariplo. ISPI Palazzo Clerici Via Clerici, 5 I - 20121 Milano www.ispionline.it © ISPI 2011 Searching for the Regional Political and Economic Governance Principles for a Common Currency Erik Jones Bologna Institute for Policy Research SAIS Bologna Center Nuffield College, Oxford (ejones@jhubc.it) comment prepared for Enhancing the Institutional Framework for the Euro Euro 50 Group and European University Institute Brussels, Belgium 23 January 2012 Five Principles for Europe’s Monetary Union This comment is does not develop a single line of thought. Rather it makes five quick observations that might be used as the basis for discussion. These observations touch on old arguments in the study of optimum currency areas and monetary integration. Nevertheless, the current crisis casts them in new light. 1. Macroeconomic imbalances across countries arise from capital market flows and not divergences in competitiveness. The variation across countries in sovereign bond yields at the long end of the maturity spectrum diminished markedly in the decade prior to the launch of Europe’s economic and monetary union. The standard deviation across ten-year bond yields for the twelve original euro participants (including Greece) fell from a high of 4.86 percentage points in 1993 to just 0.49 percentage points in 1999. Meanwhile, the variation across countries in current account balances expressed as a percentage of gross domestic product (GDP) increased, albeit with a lag. The standard deviation across national current account balances for the same twelve countries was 3.07 percentage points in 1996 and 6.21 percentage points in 2000. See Exhibit 1A. The theoretical mechanism behind this negative correlation relies on the negative influence of nominal interest rates on investment, consumption, and perhaps even government spending. When interest rates are high, they tend to depress activity; when they are low, activity tends to increase. Yet as investment, consumption or government spending expand under the influence of rapidly declining nominal interest rates, they tend to outstrip domestic output and so cause imports to grow at a faster pace than exports. A negative balance on the country’s current account is the result. Greece is a good example. In 1994, Greece has a modest current account surplus worth 1 percent of GDP and nominal long term interest rates of 20.7 percent. These interest rates were already declining from a 1992 high of 24 percent; by 2000 long-term nominal interest rates had fallen to just 6.1 percent. The Greek current account deficit in 2000 was worth just over 12 percent of GDP. See Exhibit 1B. Nominal interest rate convergence is not the only variable that correlates with changes in current account performance; movements in the real effective exchange rate correlate as well. Looking across countries, Germany experienced an improvement in its real effective exchange rates during the period from 2000 to 2007; Germany also managed to run up a significant cumulative current account surplus over the same period. By contrast, the peripheral countries of the eurozone – meaning Portugal, Ireland, Italy, Greece, and Spain – show a deterioration in their real effective exchange rates and an accumulation of current account deficits. See Exhibit 1C. This correlation between real effective exchange rates and current account balances lies at the heart of the claim that macroeconomic imbalances are the result of divergent price 1 developments. The theoretical mechanism supporting this claim rests on the notion that as prices increase in one country relative to its major trading partners, its exports will lose market share and its imports will increase. In turn, this will have negative consequences for manufacturing employment. Given this theoretical mechanism, the data for export market shares and manufacturing employment present significant anomalies. Looking at the eighteen years from 2001 to 2007, both Germany and the eurozone periphery lost market share – but Germany lost more. See Exhibit 1D. Germany also lost significantly more manufacturing employment over the same period. See Exhibit 1E. Of course the selection of the base year is important. The 1990s were difficult for Germany and many German manufacturing jobs were lost in the aftermath of unification. Nevertheless, German manufacturing shed jobs during the single currency as well; meanwhile, the peripheral countries of the eurozone added manufacturing employment. This data is inconsistent with the idea that changes in price competitiveness can explain macroeconomic imbalances. If capital flows from Germany to the eurozone periphery lie at the heart of European macroeconomic imbalances, then these data for export market shares and manufacturing employment are no longer inconsistent with the causal mechanism. Lower interest rates reduce the cost of capital and so enhance the cost-competitiveness of exports from the periphery; higher rates of investment should strengthen productivity growth to compensate for higher costs as well. The claim here is not that all of the capital flowing in peripheral countries was used wisely; rather it is that effective use of capital inflows could explain how peripheral countries were able to sustain both their export market share and their manufacturing employment. 2 2. Divergences in cost competitiveness are the result of macroeconomic imbalances despite the positive influence of monetary integration. The decomposition of real effective exchange rate movements into components reflecting movements in the nominal effective exchange rate, relative GDP price deflators, and the relative ratio of total nominal wages to nominal GDP (also known as relative ‘real’ unit labor costs), makes it possible to trace different areas of influence. It also makes it easier to make inter-temporal comparisons. See Exhibit 2. Four factors stand out: • • • • first, monetary integration resulted in lower levels of relative GDP price inflation across the eurozone periphery with the possible exception of Spain; second, relative real unit labor costs increased after monetary union only in Ireland and Italy – which is unsurprising given how much the governments of these countries sought to compress relative wage growth during the run up to membership in the euro; third, movements in the nominal effective exchange rate tended to be offset by even larger movements in relative GDP price inflation except in larger countries like Italy and Spain – and only Italy saw any benefit from this increase in competitiveness in terms of the current account; and, fourth, German performance under monetary union stands out primarily for its exceptionally low GDP price inflation combined with its low real unit labor costs – the peripheral countries are much closer to the European average. The mechanism underlying this divergence in performance is closely related to the link between capital flows and current account performance. In the capital receiving countries, activity outstrips domestic output and so puts upward pressure on wages and prices. This should tend to increase the relative performance of the GDP price deflator but may not lead to a change in relative real unit labor costs if the influence on the aggregate for nominal wages and nominal GDP is roughly the same. In the capital sending country, the effect is the opposite. Domestic consumption, investment and government spending should run below domestic output, putting downward pressure on wages and prices. The net effect across sending and receiving countries will be a cumulative price competitive divergence over time. The conclusion to this point is that the peripheral countries have good reason to worry about their relative cost competitiveness. Adverse movements in relative prices did not do too much damage to export market shares or manufacturing employment prior to the crisis. But having benefitted from easy access to foreign lending, these countries are in poor shape to compete without relatively low capital costs. The situation would be worse without the euro – particularly if countries like Ireland and Italy cannot repeat the huge wage compression they used to prepare for membership in the single currency. Relative cost competitiveness remains a challenge nonetheless. 3 3. You can force countries to borrow more easily than you can force them to lend. The relationship between lenders and borrowers has a complicated ethics and power dynamic – and the ‘intuitions’ that predominate in a modern market economy are not always appropriate. A bank cannot put money into the pocket of a consumer; by contrast, foreign banks can deposit money freely into domestic banks. This contrast is significant. When a domestic bank attracts foreign deposits, it has no incentive to seek offsetting foreign assets. On the contrary, it has domestic clients who would be eager to use the money if only the bank could offer a more affordable lending rate. The surge in foreign deposits facilitates this transformation. As the supply of loanable funds increases in the domestic banking system under the influence of foreign depositors, the price of lending for domestic uses should be expected to decline. Banks are not the only channel for foreign capital. Sovereign debt markets operate as well. When foreign investors bid up the price of domestic sovereign debt, they price-out domestic investors. The composition of sovereign debt holders changes from domestic to foreign, and the composition of domestic investments changes from high yielding sovereign debt to a mix of lower yielding sovereign debt and other domestic assets. Again this effectively increases the supply of loanable funds on the market, which lowers the cost of borrowing and so expands the demand for the funds made available. Even a country like Italy, with both a relatively conservative domestic banking system and household savings many times greater than government borrowing, is not immune to the influence of this mechanism. Hence during the run-up to monetary union, the decline in nominal interest rates took place as foreign investors bought up an increasing share of the Italy’s public debt. In 1990, Italy’s long-term nominal interest rates were 13.5 percent and foreign holdings of Italian sovereign debt accounted for just 5.3 percent of the total; by 1998, Italian longterm nominal interest rates had fallen to 4.9 percent and foreign holdings of Italian sovereign debt accounted for 25.2 percent of the total. A country’s hold over its foreign lenders is virtually nonexistent. All a foreign investor needs to do is sell their bond holdings or close their accounts. The domestic government cannot compel foreigners to purchase its debt instruments and domestic banks can all too easily find themselves cut off from international capital markets. Both consequences are evident in Greece, Ireland, and Portugal. They show early signs in Spain and Italy as well. And while it is true that the European Central Banks provision of three-year liquidity has prevented a liquidity crisis in the European banking system, it is still not evident that it has encouraged increased cross-border lending. 4 4. The flight-to-safety should not be allowed to move geographically. The asymmetry in the relative power of borrowers and lending shows up at both the domestic and the international levels. Germany cannot stop financial actors from moving their money into its banks and government assets; the peripheral countries of Europe are hard pressed to keep domestic savings at home. This is the defining feature of the flight to safety in Europe; the pattern is geographic. Faced with uncertainty, investors send their money somewhere safe. Moreover, their actions are self-reinforcing. As capital flight raises borrowing costs on the periphery, clearing houses increase the charges they impose when accepting peripheral country assets as collateral and ratings agencies reconsider the creditworthiness of peripheral country borrowers. This pattern is different from the flight-to-quality observed in the United States. U.S. investors tend to move across asset classes rather than geographic boundaries; the flow of funds is from equity to fixed income and government-backed paper and not from one state to the next. Moreover, financial institutions in the U.S. rely on the same high quality assets for their banking transactions. Hence even a marginal decline in the creditworthiness of the U.S. government, like that imposed last August when Standard & Poor’s removed its triple-A rating, has little impact on the usefulness of U.S. government paper as the preferred shelter from unwanted risk. The difference between the European and U.S. patterns is important because of the link between government finances and national banking systems in eurozone member states. Governments tend to market the bulk of their debt to banks domiciled within their country and banks tend to hold disproportionate amounts of their home country’s sovereign debt. Moreover, governments have to issue debt if they need to shore up the domestic banking system and the domestic banking system tends to suffer whenever there is a fall in the price of the home country’s debt. The implication is that the European flight to safety is doubly destabilizing because it undermines national banking systems while at the same time hobbling member state governments. This is why European countries are so prone to country-specific liquidity shocks. It is also why even countries that do not borrow hugely from abroad – like Italy – remain vulnerable. Italy’s cumulative current account deficit is only a small fraction of the country’s GDP and yet both sovereign debt markets and the country’s major banks have experienced acute moments of crisis. 5 5. Neither integrated labor markets nor a federal fiscal system necessarily insulate against a country-specific liquidity shock. U.S. regional economies are less vulnerable to asymmetric shocks but they are not immune. The experience of the Southwest region in the 1980s is a good illustration. The decade started with a Mexican debt crisis that crippled many Texas banks – only to be followed by a decline in world oil prices and a collapse of the savings and loans industry. The impact of these events were concentrated in the Southwest region and the effects were not the same in, for example, New England. Hence while Southwest income per capita was increasing relative to the U.S. average during the 1970s, it suddenly declined at the end of that decade; New England income moved in the opposite direction. See Exhibit 5A. The same is true for employment. A gap in employment rates opened up in the 1980s with the Southwest trailing New England. Both effects – the income gap and the employment gap – are persistent up to the present. See Exhibit 5B. The influence of the federal transfer system has not been to eliminate the difference. On the contrary, transfers per capita are higher than the US average in New England, where both income per capita and employment are superior. Indeed, transfers per capita in New England actually increased shortly after the region experience a positive per capita income shock. By contrast, transfers per capita to the Southwest region are even lower relative to the US average than per capita income throughout the period. See Exhibit 5C. Population flows have not helped to eliminate the gap between New England and the Southwest either. Rather than flowing toward the region with higher income and employment, population growth has concentrated in the Southwest. See Exhibit 5D. Much of this growth may be due to immigration from outside the country and particularly from Latin America; some is still likely to be the result of internal migration from other parts of the U.S. North, like the Great Lakes region. Whatever the origin, the effect of labor flows has been reinforcing rather than countervailing. A better design for federal transfers might improve the situation in the Southwest and the introduction of active labor market policies might result in more efficient matching of Southwest labor and New England job prospects. The point is not that Europe could not benefit from optimally designed systems. Rather it is that the systems operating in the United States are far from optimal in terms of stabilizing regional economic performance in the face of asymmetric shocks and, ultimately, promoting income and employment convergence across regions. Europe does not have to emulate U.S. institutional design to achieve U.S. levels of performance. Indeed, attempting to replicate U.S. federal fiscal institutions or labor market policies may have significant unintended consequences. 6 Concluding Remarks The current crisis in European sovereign debt markets was caused by financial market integration and not by the creation of the single currency. If anything, the existence of the single currency and the European System of Central Banks helped to insulate European countries from some of the worst effects of the economic and financial shock that originated in the United States. This should lead us to consider how we might capture the benefits of financial market integration while avoiding the unintended risks that international capital flows tend to create. The answer should allow for the emergence of macroeconomic imbalances but it should encourage productive investment and discourage the formation of asset market bubbles. Moreover, the answer should channel the flight to safety across asset classes rather than geographic space. Such an answer does not require a great leap forward in European integration. But it does depend upon some mechanism for severing the unhealthy interdependence at the national level between government fiscal accounts and the bank balance sheets. The creation of a shared sovereign debt obligation would meet many of these objectives. Appropriately structured conditionality for participation in the sovereign credit club could take care of the rest. This is not a solution for the current crisis. But it should prevent the next. 7 9.00 Exhibit 1A: Interest Rate Convergence and Macroeconomic Imbalances 8.00 7.00 Stan ndard Deviation ((Percent) 6.00 Long‐term Interest Rates 5 00 5.00 4.00 Current Account Balances 3.00 2.00 1.00 0.00 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 Year 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 AMECO Database 30 4 Exhibit 1B: Long‐term Interest Rates and Current Account Balances in Greece 2 25 ‐2 20 ‐4 15 ‐6 ‐8 10 ‐10 ‐12 5 ‐14 0 ‐16 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 Year Long‐term Interest Rates Current Account Balance AMECO Database Current Account Balancce as Percent GDP ent Long‐term Nominal Interrest Rate as Perce 0 Exhibit 1C: REER Movements and Current Account Performance, 2000‐2007 REER Curr Acct 28.8 14 0 14.0 11.1 8.8 Germanyy Ireland 10.8 6.2 Greece Spain p Italyy Portugal g ‐6.5 ‐12.3 ‐13.0 ‐44.5 ‐63.2 ‐85.1 Source: Ameco Database 110 Exhibit 1D: Relative Performance in World Export Market Share 105 100 Index, 1991 1=100 95 90 85 80 75 70 65 60 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 Year Germany PIIGS AMECO dataset (AXGT) 11000 Exhibit 1E: Employment in Manufacturing 10500 10000 9500 Thousan nds 9000 8500 8000 7500 7000 6500 6000 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 Year PIIGS Germany AMECO Database 2007 Exhibit 2: The Decomposition of Real Effective Exchange Rates Greece Germany 1991-2000 1991-2000 2000-2007 2000-2007 52.9 6.3 4.3 5.3 2.5 REER NEER 16.7 GDP Def 8.8 RULC REER -7.3 NEER -9.1 Italy 2000-2007 1991-2000 3.8 GDP Def REER NEER GDP Def RULC -16.1 -25.3 -26.0 Portugal 1991-2000 Spain 2000-2007 1991-2000 22.4 21.3 REER 1.9 8.9 1.9 NEER -10.0 4.6 GDP Def REER -0.2 RULC 2000-2007 13.9 13.0 11.1 6.2 RULC -10.9 -4.4 -5.2 5.1 3.8 2.0 6.6 NEER 2000-2007 11.5 10.8 15.3 3.5 REER RULC -38.6 Ireland 14.0 GDP Def 2.4 0.5 -5.7 -12.3 1991-2000 7.6 0.7 NEER -13.0 -26.1 GDP Def RULC -0.8 -3.8 120% Exhibit 5A: Salary and Wage Payments per Employee, Relative to US Average 115% 110% 105% 100% 95% 90% 85% 1969 1974 1979 1984 1989 1994 1999 2004 2009 Year New England Southwest Bureau of Economic Analysis 65% Exhibit 5B: Population Share in Employment 60% 55% 50% 45% 40% 1969 1974 1979 1984 1989 1994 Year New England 1999 2004 Bureau of Economic Analysis Southwest 2009 125% Exhibit 5C: Per Capita Income and Transfers Relative to the U.S. Average 120% 115% 110% 105% 100% 1969 1974 1979 1984 1989 1994 1999 2004 95% 90% 85% 80% 75% Year New England Income New England Transfers Bureau of Economic Analysis Southwest Income Southwest Transfers 2009 40,000,000 Exhibit 5D: Population in New England and the Southwest 35,000,000 30,000,000 25,000,000 20,000,000 15,000,000 10,000,000 1969 1974 1979 1984 1989 Year New England 1994 1999 2004 Bureau of Economic Analysis Southwest 2009 European Policy Analysis April . ISSUE 2012:4e p a Erik Jones* Eurobonds, Flight to Quality, and TARGET2 Imbalances Abstract This brief shows how the introduction of eurobonds may provide an effective if still partial solution to some of the fundamental problems that have been raised during the sovereign debt crisis in the eurozone. In a five part analysis, it shows how the structure of European banking collateral and the geographic flight to quality across European financial markets have strong negative interactions in sovereign debt markets. The brief also considers the advantages and disadvantages that eurobonds would present as a potential solution to this underlying dynamic. The brief concludes by focusing on the challenges associated with implementation of any eurobond proposal. Although it makes some possible suggestions, the most important message from this analysis is that implementation should be the focus for debate. The time has come for Europe’s political leaders to take a decision about whether to pursue eurobonds in principle. Introduction The debate over whether member states that have adopted the euro as a common currency should issue common sovereign debt instruments (or eurobonds) has receded into the background. The European Commission published its green paper to solicit comments on three different versions of what it renamed the ‘stability bond’ proposal on 23 November 2011 and then never followed up.1 German political opposition to the idea was categorical, at least within much of the country’s economics establishment and among the governing parties of the center-right.2 Moreover, the Germans were hardly alone. The Dutch, the Finns, and the Slovaks were only among the most prominent in joining German opposition to the eurobond proposal. * 1 2 Opposition to eurobonds is unlikely to soften in the near future. Although many commentators suggest that some manner of commonly issued and jointly underwritten sovereign debt instrument will come about eventually, even ardent supporters of the proposal, like Luxembourg Finance Minister Jean-Claude Juncker and Italian Prime Minister Mario Monti, admit that the moment is not ripe. Meanwhile popular discussion about the eurozone crisis has moved onto more technical matters. Some of these issues are relatively easy to grasp, like concern expressed about the size and composition of the European Central Bank’s (ECB) balance sheet. The ECB has accumulated large stocks of sovereign debt both as collateral against loans given to banks and through the direct purchase Erik Jones is Professor of European Studies at Johns Hopkins SAIS, Director of Bologna Institute for Policy Research and Senior Research Fellow at Nuffield College, Oxford. ‘Green Paper on the Feasibility of Introducing Stability Bonds.’ Brussels: European Commission, COM(2011) 818 final, 23 November 2011. The position taken by the former chief economist of the European Central Bank, Otmar Issing, is illustrative. See Otmar Issing, ‘Why a Common Eurobond Isn’t Such a Good Idea,’ Europe’s World (Summer 2009). More recently, Issing has been quoted as saying that a common eurobond represents the greatest threat to the stability of the eurozone. See the Eurointelligence daily briefing of 30 March 2012 at www.eurointelligence.com. Swedish Institute for European Policy Studies www.sieps.se EUROPEAN POLICY ANALYSIS 2012:4 . PAGE 1 of government debt securities as part of the securities markets program. Others are more complicated, like the debate that has erupted over TARGET2 imbalances – or the relative positions of different national central banks in the real-time gross settlement system that is used to make financial payments across countries within the eurozone. No matter how obscure such issues may seem, however, they are vitally important. The president of the German central bank (or Bundesbank), Jens Weidmann, created a minor scandal when the German daily Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung (FAZ) leaked a letter he wrote to ECB President Mario Draghi to complain about the growth and deterioration in the ECB’s balance sheet and about the exposure of the Bundesbank to the rest of the eurozone through TARGET2 transfers.3 Weidmann’s letter was followed closely by comments from former ECB Executive Board member Jürgen Stark, who argued that Europe’s monetary policy makers risked undermining the stability of the euro through their aggressive extension of credit to banks under the longterm refinancing operations (LTROs) undertaken in December 2011 and February 2012.4 These refinancing operations provided unlimited amounts of liquidity at very low rates of interest for periods of up to three years. In this way, the ECB fulfilled its role as lender of last resort – channelling roughly €1 trillion in new funds into the European banking system. Stark’s concern was that the collateral received in exchange for this lending exposed the ECB to potentially unacceptable losses. Draghi responded to both criticisms directly in his 8 March press conference but he could not silence the debate.5 Even Weidmann’s own attempts to minimize the significance of the controversy in an open letter to the FAZ on 13 March did little to ease concerns.6 Hence Draghi returned to these themes more forcefully in his 26 March speech to the Association of German Banks.7 Such debates appear divorced from the idea of having European governments issue common debt instruments and yet they are not. To a large extent, the expansion of 3 4 7 5 6 the ECB’s balance sheet, the emergence of significant TARGET2 imbalances, and the necessity for the ECB to make extraordinary amounts of credit through the LTROs all stem from the fact that national governments in the eurozone issue national sovereign debt. The purpose of this brief is to suggest how the introduction of eurobonds might provide an effective if still only partial response to these more recent concerns. The brief has five sections. The first explains how the collateral available to national banking systems and the geographic pattern of the flight to quality have influenced the current sovereign debt crisis. The second reintroduces the debate about eurobonds, focusing on the question of market discipline. The third examines some of the criticisms of the eurobond proposal related to moral hazard. The fourth connects this eurobond debate back to the problems of collateral and the flight to quality. The fifth sections concludes with policy recommendations related to the implementation of eurobonds. Two problems The argument about the potential utility of eurobonds hinges on two elements in the financial architecture of the eurozone: banking collateral and the flight to quality. The point about banking collateral touches on the relationship between national governments and their domestic banks; national governments and national banking systems are closely interdependent. Domestic banks offer a captive market for sovereign debt by helping to float new issues and by creating an active secondary market. Meanwhile, sovereign debt offers an essentially ‘risk-free’ asset to facilitate day-to-day banking operations by providing collateral for use in obtaining liquidity from central banks or for clearing transactions either bilaterally or with central clearing houses. However, this interdependence has negative as well as positive implications. When a country’s domestic banks get into trouble, the governments lose access to the markets; when sovereign debt markets get into trouble, the domestic banks suffer disproportionate losses; and when sovereign debt markets get into trouble because the banks are already in trouble to begin with, the problems are self-reinforcing. This third ‘Die Bundesbank fordert von der EZB bessere Sicherheiten,’ Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung (29 February 2012). Ambrose Evans-Pritchard, ‘Germany’s Monetary Doyen Slams ECB’s “Shocking” Balance Sheet,’ The Telegraph (8 March 2012). http://www.ecb.int/press/pressconf/2012/html/is120308.en.html. http://www.bundesbank.de/download/presse/publikationen/20120315.TARGET2_balances.pdf http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2012/html/sp120326_1.en.html. PAGE 2 . EUROPEAN POLICY ANALYSIS 2012:4 scenario where both the banks and the governments are in trouble at the same time is essentially what has happened to the countries of the eurozone periphery. The Greek case offers a good example of the negative interdependence between banks and governments. When private sector investors were forced to accept a reduction in the value of the Greek bonds they were holding, the impact fell disproportionately on the Greek banking sector. As ECB President Mario Draghi explained during his 4 April 2012 press conference, private sector involvement in the Greek debt restructuring not only ‘wiped out’ the capital of the Greek banks but also left them without collateral to use in routine banking operations. Hence it was necessary to arrange a special recapitalization of the Greek banks in order to ensure that at least some of them survived the process.8 The flight to quality is what investors do with their money when faced with a sudden change in the risk environment. They liquidate investments that they perceive to be excessively risky and move the liquidity (or money) into investments that have a lower risk profile. This reaction describes the mechanism behind the crisis. It also explains why Europe is distinctive when compared with other large money unions like the United States. In the United States, the flight to quality runs across asset classes. When investors in the United States take fright, they sell equity to buy fixed income; when the fright is extreme, they move up the fixed-income quality ladder until they end up holding large stocks of U.S. government bonds. The flight to quality in Europe operates across asset classes as well, but it is also geographic. Frightened European investors sell their positions in the more risky or peripheral countries and increase their holdings in stable core economies like Germany. At the extreme, domestic investors from within the peripheral countries join the capital flight and take their money abroad. This geographic dimension of the flight to quality is what has damaged the economies on the periphery. As the money flowed out of the peripheral countries, their economies ground to a halt.9 These two different features of Europe’s financial architecture work closely together. The geographic flight to quality damages both public finances and national banking systems, and any weakness in either public finances or national banking systems is enough to trigger a flight to quality. There is no fixed pattern to this dynamic. Whether the weakness of government finances triggers a capital flight that damages the banking system, as in Greece, or the weakness of the banking system triggers a capital flight that damages public finances, as in Spain, the consequences are the same and both the banks and the governments end up in trouble. Hence the challenge is to solve both structural problems at once. There are two ways to manage the collateral problem. One is to place tight standards on eligibility rules; the other is to improve the quality of the collateral that is available. The first solution is difficult to enforce because of the inherent differences in the quality of assets in different markets. The last time the ECB made a concerted effort to strengthen its collateral rules was just prior to the collapse of Lehman Brothers; the ECB soon found itself loosening restrictions on available collateral instead in order to make sure that banks across the eurozone had ample access to liquidity.10 The same tendency can be seen in the ECB’s treatment of Greece, Ireland, and Portugal. Each time the national governments of these countries experienced a downgrade that could wipe out the eligibility of its debt as collateral, the ECB has made an exception to its collateral requirements so that the national banking systems of those countries could remain solvent.11 The difficulty involved in enforcing collateral rules will not go away easily. The fact that the ECB signalled its intention to tighten its eligibility criteria is no guarantee that it will not find it necessary to loosen them up again.12 http://www.ecb.int/press/pressconf/2012/html/is120404.en.html. Silvia Merler and Jean Pisani-Ferri, ‘Sudden Stops in the Euro Area,’ Bruegel Policy Contribution 2012/06 (March 2012). 10 See Erik Jones, ‘Reconsidering the Role of Ideas in Times of Crisis,’ in Leila Simona Talani (ed.) The Global Crash: Towards a New Global Financial Regime? (London: Palgrave, 2010) pp. 64-66. 11 See press releases from the ECB website (www.ecb.int) for 3 May 2010 (Greece), 31 March 2011 (Ireland), and 7 July 2011 (Portugal). 12 Ralph Atkins, ‘ECB Tightens Banks’ Use of Assets as Collateral,’ Financial Times (23 March 2012). Draghi sought to minimize the significance of this change in his 4 April 2012 press conference. http://www.ecb.int/press/pressconf/2012/html/is120404.en.html. 8 9 EUROPEAN POLICY ANALYSIS 2012:4 . PAGE 3 Improving the quality of collateral available is also difficult. Banks use sovereign debt as collateral because it is the closest thing available to a ‘risk-free’ asset. Hence the challenge is either to come up with a risk-free asset that does not depend upon the national government or to make sovereign debt less risky. This problem cannot be addressed within national boundaries. Either the banks will have to rely on assets from other countries, or other countries will have to absorb some of the risk of sovereign debt. This is essentially the problem that the ECB faces with those countries whose banks are in distress today. Such banks have been allowed to issue bonds with government backing as part of European Union (EU) and International Monetary Fund (IMF) assistance packages. In turn, the banks have been using these governmentbacked bonds as collateral in seeking liquidity from their national central banks. The question is whether other central banks should accept such bonds as collateral as well. On 23 March 2012, the ECB surprised the markets by suggesting that national central banks should approach the matter on a case-by-case basis rather than being expected to share the risks that such bonds necessarily entail.13 The flight to quality problem has only one solution. If the goal is to allow investors to move across asset classes and risk ratings without encouraging them to move across geographic boundaries, then the only way forward is to create a relatively ‘risk-free’ asset that circulates in all jurisdictions. Alternatively, some countries’ risk-free assets will always be less risky than others and investors seeking quality will have to move money across national boundaries to take advantage of the difference. A solution to all of this is to create a sovereign debt instrument that is less risky than existing government bonds and that can flow freely from one country to the next (so that domestic capital can stay put). This is essentially what eurobonds could offer. If European governments issued jointly underwritten eurobonds rather than relying exclusively on national sovereign debt instruments, then the flight to quality in Europe would not have to move geographically even if it continued to flow across asset classes (as in the United States). If European governments issued jointly underwritten common sovereign debt obligations, then governments could gain access to financing from wider markets and banks could rely on assets for collateral that did not depend on their home state. The payoff for restructuring the flight to quality and improving the quality of existing collateral is considerable. If the flight to quality in Europe did not move across countries, there would be less pressure on TARGET2 imbalances to finance sudden gaps in international payments; if governments could rely on pan-European sources of financing, there would be less pressure on the ECB to shore up domestic sovereign debt markets through direct purchases of distressed sovereign debt; and if the aggregate balance sheets of national banking systems were not heavily exposed to losses on holdings of national sovereign debt instruments, there would be less pressure on the ECB to loosen its own collateral rules and provide additional liquidity to banks. The existence of jointly underwritten common sovereign debt instruments like eurobonds would not solve all of Europe’s financial problems. The United States also experienced the crisis – including intra-district imbalances in financial flows across the Federal Reserve System – despite the widespread use of U.S. Treasury bonds.14 Nevertheless, by releasing some of the pressure, eurobonds would help stabilize the European financial system. Even if that is not the end of the problem, it is still a good start. The problem is convincing a reluctant public – most of whom view eurobonds as a way for less creditworthy governments to escape market discipline at the expense of their more creditworthy neighbours. While economic conditions are good, the weaker countries will take advantage of low interest rates to borrow excessively; when economic conditions worsen, the weaker countries will default. In the worst case scenario, Europe’s most creditworthy nations will end up absorbing the losses. The irony, of course, is that this worst case scenario is precisely what happened in the absence of eurobonds; indeed, excessive borrowing is that danger that eurobonds were meant to address. Eurobonds as market discipline Here it is useful to clear up some lexical confusion. Sovereign debt instruments denominated in euros have been around for a long time and the idea of allowing See Draghi at http://www.ecb.int/press/pressconf/2012/html/is120404.en.html. See the 6 March 2012 blog post by Michiel Bijlsma and Jasper Lukkezen of Bruegel (http://www.bruegel.org/blog/detail/article/696-target-2-of-the-ecb-vs-interdistrict-settlement-account-of-thefederal-reserve/). 13 14 PAGE 4 . EUROPEAN POLICY ANALYSIS 2012:4 European institutions to issue their own obligations dates back to the European Commission presidency of Jacques Delors. Both of these things – debt denominated in euros and obligations issued by European institutions – are called eurobonds. Moreover, prominent politicians like former Italian Prime Minister and European Commission President Romano Prodi continue to make proposals to deepen the market for euro-denominated obligations and to expand the issue of debt by European institutions. But such eurobonds are not what the debate is about. The ‘eurobonds’ proposal at the heart of more recent controversy centers around the idea of having national governments issue common and jointly underwritten sovereign debt obligations. Such bonds will be denominated in euros and they will most likely be issued by a European institution. But what makes them distinctive is that they will be used to finance the member states individually and yet they will be backed by the member states collectively. That is what it means to say they are common and jointly underwritten sovereign debt obligations. There is another distinguishing feature. The member states will have only limited access to sovereign debt financing through eurobonds. The reason is to discipline member state indebtedness – much in the same way that credit cards or current account overdrafts have limits. Here it is useful to consider that the original ambition was not to resolve the current sovereign debt crisis; it was to prevent such a crisis from occurring. Governments had already shown little restraint in their borrowing, European institutions did not enforce their own rules and regulations, and market participants failed to price in much of a difference in the cost of borrowing from one country to the next. Hence, the goal of the eurobond proposal was to change the structure of sovereign debt markets in order to enhance market discipline. Unsurprisingly, given this emphasis on market mechanisms, the first proposal to create eurobonds with limited access was introduced on the opinion pages of the Wall Street Journal.15 The idea underpinning the proposal is straightforward and uncontroversial: governments should have limits on what they can borrow responsibly and they should be discouraged from borrowing ‘excessively’. The challenge is to get the markets to distinguish between responsible and excessive borrowing. There are two basic techniques; 15 16 one focuses on the borrower and the other focuses on the borrowing itself. The strategy embedded in the Maastricht Treaty that set the framework for monetary integration focuses on the borrower. Governments are enjoined not to run excessive deficits and they are sanctioned if they fail to comply. Experience has shown, however, that this strategy was unsuccessful for both political and economic reasons. Politically, the Council of Economic and Finance Ministers (Ecofin Council) proved both unable and unwilling to impose sanctions on offending governments. The February 2001 reprimand of the Irish government for failing to rein in its economy was rescinded; the February 2002 decision to ignore excessive deficits in Germany and Portugal turned out to be unjustified; and the November 2003 decision to hold the excessive deficits procedure for France and Germany ‘in abeyance’ was unlawful.16 More recently, the debate about Spanish compliance (or noncompliance) with the new fiscal compact demonstrated that borrowers will resist restraint and lenders are reluctant to impose it. Economically, the markets have showed little interest in differentiating between different countries’ sovereign debts until suddenly the spreads between the most- and least creditworthy countries widened dramatically, precipitating the current crisis. The problem with focussing on the borrower is that it offers an all-or-nothing set of alternatives. The risk rating of a country influences all of its public debt. The price structure will change across different maturities, but within any given maturity both responsible and irresponsible borrowing are treated the same. Moreover, any default on one set of obligations constitutes a credit event for all the rest. This creates an important dynamic in how markets perceive national creditworthiness. The entire stock of a country’s outstanding debt is affected once a country’s solvency or liquidity is called into question. Long-term institutional investors that thought they had purchased virtually risk-free assets when a government appeared to be borrowing responsibly could find themselves taking substantial losses on those assets should the government’s financial position suddenly change. This is the dynamic that has affected banks in countries like Ireland and Spain. The eurobond proposal originally published in the Wall Street Journal offered an alternative approach John Springford, ‘A Bonding Exercise for the Euroland,’ Wall Street Journal (7 September 2009). See Erik Jones, ‘The Politics of Europe 2004: Solidarity and Integration,’ Industrial Relations Journal 36:6 (December 2005) p. 450. EUROPEAN POLICY ANALYSIS 2012:4 . PAGE 5 to differentiating between responsible and excessive borrowing – one that focuses not on the borrower but on the debt. The reason for introducing eurobonds is to create a clear threshold between one type of borrowing and the other. It achieves this distinction by altering the structure of guarantees attached to the debt instruments. All participating countries would underwrite each-other’s responsible borrowing by issuing a common series of obligations, and each country would be able to borrow with these obligations up to a fixed threshold of their gross domestic product (GDP). Any borrowing beyond that threshold would not be jointly underwritten and so the guarantees would vary from state to state. Given the different guarantees attached to the debt, the markets would charge a low price for the jointly underwritten bonds and a higher price for the nationally-specific bonds. Moreover, by eliminating this sudden transformation in the risk-rating of supposedly ‘risk-free’ assets, the eurobond proposal promised to mitigate the onset of any sovereign debt crisis. The threshold effect is only one element in the debate and the eurobond proposals that evolved during the early months of 2010, included a number of different dimensions of distinctiveness between responsible borrowing and excessive borrowing.17 In turn, each of these distinguishing features reinforced the price difference between eurobonds and national bonds, thus strengthening the market disincentive for countries to get excessively into debt. Some of these features are primarily structural. In this sense, they are also implicit in the original proposal. The eurobonds would trade in larger markets than country-specific bonds, and so they would be more liquid. Some of the features are primarily regulatory, in the sense that they depend upon other rules. The eurobonds could be designated as more ‘senior’, giving them a higher status in terms of repayment. Finally, some of the features are structural and yet also subject to regulatory reinforcement. For example, the eurobonds would make good collateral for clearing or for banking transactions because they would come with strong multinational guarantees. It would also be possible to write collateral rules to strengthen this position by imposing large haircuts on national debt used as collateral or by making national bonds ineligible. This would make eurobonds not only more liquid and more senior, but also more useful for the banking community. Moreover, the combination of liquidity, seniority, and utility, should command a significant premium in the markets – reinforcing the price difference between relatively inexpensive eurobonds and relatively more expensive national obligations. Finally, the eurobond proposals emphasized the importance of certification as a means of controlling the borrower as well as the borrowing. Governments would not qualify automatically to participate in the common funding pool. They would have to demonstrate an ability to manage their finances, they would have to accept more intrusive auditing, and they would have to demonstrate the capacity to meet their collective debt servicing requirements. Of course, the original proposal for Europe’s single currency contained a number of similar criteria. The difference is that access to eurobond financing is an ongoing matter for governments and so the incentives for following the rules of membership would be constant; a government would have as much interest in retaining certification to raise funds through common eurobonds as they would in qualifying to issue such bonds in the first place. By contrast, accession to the eurozone was a one-off transformation. It was very hard for many of the candidate countries to meet the criteria for convergence in order to qualify for entry into the eurozone. As the Greek case shows, however, it would be even harder to see them leave. The problem with these original eurobond proposals lay in their implementation: it would be difficult to introduce new senior eurobonds alongside existing national obligations; it would be challenging to enforce the thresholds on borrowing; and it would be hard to get both the ratings agencies and the wider community of market participants to buy into this new arrangement.18 Moreover, these complexities only increase in the context of an ongoing sovereign debt crisis – when trading in the markets is relatively thin, investors are nervous, and any added complexity is likely to push capital out of the European marketplace altogether. The most widely cited of these proposals is Jacques Delpla and Jakob von Weizsäcker, ‘The Blue Bond Proposal,’ Bruegel Policy Brief 2010/03 (May 2010). See also Erik Jones, ‘A Eurobond Proposal to Promote Stability and Liquidity while Preventing Moral Hazard,’ ISPI Policy Brief no. 180 (March 2010). For an early overview of proposals, see Guillermo De La Dehesa, ‘Eurobonds: Concepts and Implications,’ (Brussels: European Parliament, March 2011). 18 For further discussion of some of these issues, see Jacques Delpla and Jakob von Weizsäcker, ‘Eurobonds: The Blue Bond Concept and Its Implications,’ Bruegel Policy Contribution 2011/02 (March 2011). 17 PAGE 6 . EUROPEAN POLICY ANALYSIS 2012:4 Recognition of these implementation concerns led to a second round of debates about potential intermediate solutions – including a shared debt management agency, a common European bailout facility, or a European redemption pact.19 Governments could issue all of their debt through an agency that they guaranteed directly; they could create a strong firewall to help those countries that get in trouble with their own debt management; or they could create a fund to finance all existing excessive borrowing against the promise that governments would not return to further irresponsible behaviour. Such intermediate proposals did alleviate some of the complexity of implementing eurobonds but only by increasing the complexity of their design. These proposals also blurred the market’s ability to perceive the distinction between responsible and excessive borrowing and so weakened the benefits to be had from strengthening market discipline. In short, they offered advantages in the context of the ongoing crisis but at the expense of preventing the next one. The problems of close interdependence between national governments and their domestic banking systems and arising from the geographic flight to quality remain unaddressed. Moral hazard, borrowing costs, and loss provision The intermediate proposals for eurobonds also failed to address the most potent criticisms of the original proposal to encourage member states to issue common, jointly underwritten sovereign debt instruments: Opponents of the proposals expressed concern that eurobonds would increase moral hazard by allowing less creditworthy participants to borrow more cheaply; they worried that eurobonds would create conditional liabilities for more creditworthy borrowers that would lead to lower ratings and higher borrowing costs on even the most responsible participants; and they feared that the withdrawal of individual participants or the spectacular collapse of the system would leave the strongest countries in Europe to cover any losses. In other words, although the original eurobond proposal was designed to increase market discipline, nothing in either the proposal or its intermediate alternatives addressed the concerns that define a large part of public opinion today. Therefore, it is worth considering the logic of these positions more carefully. The concern about moral hazard returns the focus for market discipline to the borrower and not the borrowing. The argument is that eurbonds will create perverse incentives. By lowering the cost of responsible borrowing, eurobonds effectively release resources to service excessive deficits. They also shift the focus for political discipline from the imposition of sanctions to the enforcement of the borrowing thresholds. And yet since European politicians have shown themselves incapable of imposing sanctions, there is little reason to assume that they will be more effective in imposing restrictions on common debt issuance. Finally, eurobonds take pressure off of governments in need of politically painful and yet economically necessary reforms. Without the threat of crisis, such governments are more likely to delay making structural adjustments.20 The concern about conditional liabilities also focuses attention on borrowers. The problem is that while national governments have individual credit ratings, the pool of eurobonds as a whole would be jointly underwritten. Hence the ratings agencies would be justified in looking at the potential losses that any one country could face in the event of a breakdown within the system when making assessments of a country’s creditworthiness. The extent of any likely breakdown is an important factor as well. At a minimum, the stronger countries would have to be able to take on the debt servicing requirements of the weakest. Given that this would effectively increase liabilities for the strongest participants, it should be expected to raise their borrowing costs and put downward pressure on their credit ratings. The German ministry of finance estimates that participation in such a system would cost Germany billions of euros.21 While the liabilities are conditional, the costs to Germany are real. Even if the eurobonds work perfectly as a commonly issued and jointly underwritten sovereign debt instrument, Germany would pay a price for its exposure to the system. The concern about loss provision stems from the possibility that the system will not work perfectly. The question is who will pick up the costs if the eurobond arrangement fails. This is where moral hazard and conditional liabilities come together to create a fear that unscrupulous governments will repudiate their obligations See Alexander Duering and Abhishek Singhania, ‘A Modest Eurobond Proposal,’ Deutsche Bank Fixed Income Special Report (25 August 2011); Hans-Joachim Dübel, ‘Partial Sovereign Bond Insurance by the Eurozone: A More Efficient Alternative to the Blue (Euro-) Bonds,’ CEPS Policy Brief No. 252 (August 2011); Bofinger, Peter, et al. ‘A European Redemption Pact,’ VoxEU (9 November 2011). 20 See Duering and Singhania, ‘A Modest Eurobond Proposal,’ (2011) above. See also ‘Eurobonds: Moral Hazard Ahead,’ Financial Times (23 November 2011). 21 ‘Euro Bonds Would Cost Germany Billions,’ Spiegel Online International (22 August 2011) http://www.spiegel.de/international/germany/0,1518,781524,00.html. 19 EUROPEAN POLICY ANALYSIS 2012:4 . PAGE 7 to the system, thus leaving governments that respect their obligations to carry more than their fair share. These concerns are compelling. They also appear to be happening even without eurobonds. Indeed that is why Jens Weidmann expressed alarm about Germany’s TARGET2 position. Although he claims in his 13 March letter that he does not believe the eurozone will come apart, the only reason for collateralizing TARGET2 imbalances is to have some asset in place to absorb the losses should one or more countries pull out of the system. The concern about conditional liabilities is evident today as well. This is why Jürgen Stark expressed skepticism about the size of the ECB’s balance sheet and why he is so critical of the assets the ECB accepts as collateral. Finally, such concerns explain why the preponderance of German public opinion is so critical of the governments on the eurozone periphery. Here it is useful to cite a speech Stark made while he was still an ECB Board Member: 22 In my view solving the current sovereign debt crisis is primarily in the hands of governments. Its root cause lies in lax fiscal policy rules and associated deteriorating public finances in some euro area countries. Stability criteria were violated, fiscal rules ignored and statistics tweaked. Growth dividends were not used for necessary consolidation in good times. In the same vein, competitiveness positions worsened in many euro area countries, due to a lack of structural reforms. This is a near perfect illustration of moral hazard.23 Full circle Yet if the worst fears of the eurobond’s opponents are already evident, it is worth considering how they came to pass. Many parts of the story are already evident. National governments took advantage of the system and European institutions failed to enforce the rules. Yet such features are ubiquitous. They are as easily found in any of the possible alternatives. Countries outside the eurozone – like Iceland or Hungary – have also been affected. Meanwhile countries like Ireland, Portugal, Spain, Italy, and Greece are more different than they are similar. Somehow the problem is structural and not national; if the question is what caused the crisis, original sin is not the answer. A better analysis looks at the problems of geographic capital movements and collateral rules. Only rather 22 23 than focussing on distress and uncertainty, it looks at opportunity and return. During the run-up to monetary union, investors at the core of the eurozone sought opportunities on the periphery and the most creditworthy banks looked for relatively risk-free assets that offered a higher rate of return. This is why long run interest rates across sovereign debt obligations converged so sharply across European countries during the late 1990s; it is why cross border deposits expanded in the smaller, peripheral markets; and it is why the economies of the eurozone periphery experienced relatively high rates of debtfuelled growth. The result of the process can be seen in the prolonged period of tight interest rate differentials during the first decade of monetary integration and the large cross-border exposures of the national banking systems and sovereign debt markets that built up over the same period. Indeed, it is this prior outward flow of capital from the core to the periphery that explains the depth of the crisis once the flow moved in reverse. Geographic capital flows and collateral rules played as important a role in setting the stage for the current crisis as they did in bringing down the curtain. There is little reason to believe that the cycle will not repeat itself. The impact of capital market integration in times of economic stability is to move savings from countries with relatively low rates of return and scarce opportunities for investment to countries with relatively higher rates of return and more abundant opportunities for investment. The flows during the next cycle do not need to be as great as they were the last time; all that matters is that the stock of cross border exposure builds up over time. The impact of capital market integration in times of economic uncertainty is a rapid unwinding of these accumulated positions. As large amounts of funds flow suddenly back to countries with surplus savings and relatively few opportunities for investment, the net effect will be to slow economic performance across the area of integrated capital markets as a whole. The difference between a eurozone with eurobonds and a eurozone without them is not to be found in the quality of political leadership or its willingness to abide by solemn commitments. Rather it is found in the structure of market incentives and the costs of violating the rules. The strength of the eurobond proposal is that it provides more http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2011/html/sp111202.en.html. Stark’s analysis is obviously inaccurate. Neither Ireland nor Spain had fiscal problems before the crisis. Their problems were more closely related to the growth of private debt. The governments only got into trouble once the private debtors needed to be bailed out. PAGE 8 . EUROPEAN POLICY ANALYSIS 2012:4 opportunities for continuous enforcement than the allor-nothing alternatives offered in the current system. It creates incentives for countries to allow for more intrusive monitoring and it reduces incentives for banks or other financial actors to attempt to arbitrage price differentials within a pan-European framework of rules. Of course such a system will be prone to manipulation, but so is the status quo. On balance, however, the structure of incentives in a eurozone containing eurobonds will bring more stability to the system rather than encouraging oscillations. So long as governments depend upon national obligations, they are likely to suffer further turmoil. Policy recommendations No matter how attractive eurobonds might be as a proposal, there are significant challenges to be tackled before they can be implemented. Hence the basic recommendation is that these implementation challenges should be placed at the forefront of the debate. The time for considering whether eurobonds are justified in principle has elapsed. The European Commission’s green paper should have put an end to that phase of discussion. Now the challenge is to take it further. The first step could be to harmonize and strengthen the collateral available to banks across the eurozone. This could be done by swapping out the banking books of the pan-European banking system at par value, using jointly underwritten sovereign debt instruments. For many of the banks, this will insulate them from potential losses like those experienced in Greece as part of private sector involvement. The ECB’s exposure to sovereign debt instruments – both outright and pledged – should be swapped out as well. This will not increase the contingent liabilities of the participating governments. It is already evident from the ‘open sector involvement’ debate during the second Greek bailout negotiations that these assets are effectively ‘senior’ to those held in the private sector. By swapping them out, the eurozone governments will only make that seniority more explicit. The next step could be to offer distressed countries the opportunity to refinance their debt as it comes due in these new eurobonds in exchange for intrusive auditing and monitoring. This is already happening in those countries that have requested official assistance; it could be made available to all governments in the eurozone on the same conditions. Governments in sound fiscal situations might object that they do not require such supervision; but their demonstration of solidarity would help mollify public opinion in those countries most needing reform. In any event, there would be cost advantages to participating in jointly underwritten sovereign debt issuance, particularly if collateral rules were shaped to privilege these assets for use in obtaining bank liquidity or in clearing. The remaining challenge will be to enforce the thresholds for issuance, particularly for those countries most indebted. The original eurobond proposal was designed to prevent a crisis and not to solve one. Now that it is too late to prevent a crisis, it is probably too soon to unleash market discipline on distressed governments. That said, there is no reason that governments cannot be coaxed back into the markets at some point in the future. Therefore, while it may be necessary to swap out a country’s entire existing stock of debt with eurobonds in the short term, it should be possible to refinance any excess borrowing with strictly national sovereign debt instruments incrementally once the government is able to re-enter the markets. That is essentially what the European bailout mechanisms intend. The financing they provide offers only temporary relief from market pressures and should at some point be paid back as the government regains market confidence. There is no reason that the introduction of eurobonds could not provide similar exceptional and temporary relief. In the final analysis, Europe will have to move to a system that focuses on the borrowing and not the borrower. It will need to stop the geographic flight to quality and it will have to break the strong interdependence between national banking systems and their domestic governments. Otherwise Europe’s policymakers will continue to find themselves periodically descending into crisis. They will overstretch their monetary institutions and may even undermine the eurozone as a whole. These questions are all linked by the structure of the system. The eurozone as a whole needs structural reform. Eurobonds offer a partial if still effective solution. They would make it easier to channel the flight to quality across asset class without necessary forcing capital to flow across national boundaries. They will disconnect sovereign access to borrowing from the solvency and liquidity of national banking systems. They will provide strong guarantees for the assets held on the balance sheets of European monetary institutions. And they will relieve at least some of the pressure that has built up across the European financial system. Of course politicians must still address concerns about moral hazard and abuse of the system. Those problems will EUROPEAN POLICY ANALYSIS 2012:4 . PAGE 9 not go away and critics of the eurobond proposal are right to point at that jointly underwritten and commonly issued sovereign debt instruments are vulnerable. But the point that should be stressed is that the current crisis is a result of moral hazard under the existing system. Moreover, by focusing on the borrower and not the borrowing, the existing framework for reining in excessive deficits puts governments in an unenviable all-or-nothing situation PAGE 10 . EUROPEAN POLICY ANALYSIS 2012:4 where the incentives for ignoring the rules or refusing to enforce them are very hard to ignore. Solemn declarations and inverted decision making procedures are not enough to reshape the structure of these incentives. Europe’s political leaders must look for some more fundamental solution. At least part of that solution will be found in the eurobond proposal. European Policy Analysis available in English 2012 2012:3epa The Hungarian Constitution of 2012 and its Protection of Fundamental Rights Authors: Joakim Nergelius 2012:2epa The EU and Climate Treaty Negotiations after the Durban Conference Author: Katak Malla 2012:1epa The EU’s Cooperation and Verification Mechanism: Fighting Corruption in Bulgaria and Romania after EU Accession Authors: Milada Anna Vachudova and Aneta Spendzharova 2011 2011:14epa Public Services at the Local Level – is a Decentralisation of State Aid Policy Necessary? Author: Jörgen Hettne 2011:13epa Euro Plus Pact: Between Global Competitiveness and Local Social Concerns Author: Karolina Zurek 2011:12epa The EU Strategies for New Climate Treaty Negotiations Author: Katak Malla 2011:8epa Brussels Advocates Swedish Grey Wolves: On the encounter between species protection according to Union law and the Swedish wolf policy Author: Jan Darpö 2011:7epa A New Proportionality Test for Fundamental Rights Authors: Anna-Sara Lind and Magnus Strand 2011:6epa The European Treaty Amendment for the Creation of a Financial Stability Mechanism Author: Bruno de Witte 2011:5epa Comment on the European Commission´s “Green Paper towards adequate, sustainable and safe European pension systems” Author: Conny Olovsson 2011:1epa How Small are the Regional Gaps? How Small is the Impact of Cohesion Policy? A Commentary on the Fifth Report on Cohesion Policy Author: Daniel Tarschys 2010 2010:14epa Mollifying Everyone, Pleasing No-one. An Assessment of the EU Budget Review Author: Iain Begg 2010:11epa Social and Employment Policy in the EU and in the Great Recession Author: Giuseppe Bertola 2010:10epa The Socio-Economic Asymmetries of European Integration or Why the EU cannot be a “Social Market Economy” Author: Fritz W. Scharpf 2010:9epa Strengthening the Institutional Underpinnings of the Euro Author: Stefan Gerlach 2010:6epa The European External Action Service: towards a common diplomacy? Author: Christophe Hillion 2010:2epa Rethinking How to Pay for Europe Author: Iain Begg 2010:1epa Internal and External EU Climate Objectives and the Future of the EU Budget Author: Jorge Núñez Ferrer EUROPEAN POLICY ANALYSIS 2012:4 . PAGE 11 2009 2009:14epa The Eastern Partnership: Time for an Eastern Policy of the EU? Author: Anna Michalski 2009:13epa Out in the Cold? Flexible Integration and the Political Status of Euro Outsiders Authors: Daniel Naurin and Rutger Lindahl 2009:12epa From Zero-Sum to Win-Win? The Russian Challenge to the EU’s Eastern Neighbourhood Policies Author: Hiski Haukkala 2009:11epa The CAP and Future Challenges Authors: Mark Brady, Sören Höjgård, Eva Kaspersson and Ewa Rabinowicz 2009:10epa A Legal Analysis of the Global Financial Crisis from an EU Perspective Author: Sideek Mohamed Seyad 2009:9epa An EU Strategy for the Baltic Sea Region: Good Intentions Meet Complex Challenges Author: Rikard Bengtsson 2009:8epa What to Expect in the 2009-14 European Parliament: Return of the Grand Coalition? Author: Simon Hix 2009:7epa The 2009 Swedish EU Presidency: The Setting, Priorities and Roles Authors: Fredrik Langdal and Göran von Sydow 2009:5epa When Lab Results are not Sufficient: On the Limitations of Science in Tackling Modern Food Regulatory Concerns Author: Karolina Zurek 2009:2epa Democracy Promotion in a Transatlantic Perspective: Reflections from an Expert Working Group Author: Anna Michalski PAGE 12 . EUROPEAN POLICY ANALYSIS 2012:4 2009:1epa Foreign Policy Challenges for the Obama Administration Author: John K. Glenn 2008 2008:14epa The Swedish 2009 Presidency – Possible Policy Priorities Authors: Fredrik Langdal and Göran von Sydow 2008:11epa EU Energy Policy in a Supply-Constrained World Authors: Jacques de Jong and Coby van der Linde 2008:8epa The Potential Impact of the Lisbon Treaty on European Union External Trade Policy Author: Stephen Woolcock 2008:4epa The Lisbon Treaty and EMU Author: Sideek Mohamed Seyad 2008:3epa The Lisbon Treaty and the Area of Criminal Law and Justice Author: Ester Herlin-Karnell 2008:2epa A Better Budget for Europe: Economically Efficient, Politically Realistic Author: Filipa Figueira 2008:1epa The Future of the Common European Asylum System: In Need of a More Comprehensive Burden-Sharing Approach Author: Eiko Thielemann For a full list of publications, see www.sieps.se.