Introduction to Mergers and Acquisitions

advertisement
XV.
INTRODUCTION TO MERGERS AND ACQUISITIONS: FIRM
DIVERSIFICATION
In the introduction to Section VII, it was noted that firms can acquire assets by either
undertaking internally-generated new projects or by acquiring existing assets of other firms.
Having examined the former there and again in Section XIV, we now turn to the latter.
Under the operational criterion for good management of maximizing current shareholders'
wealth, there are essentially three reasons for considering the acquisition of another company:
1.
Synergy: By combining the two companies, the value of the operating assets of the
combined firm will exceed the sum of the values of the operating assets of the two
companies taken separately. Such synergy will occur if there are economies of scale in
marketing, purchasing of materials, plant size, and distribution system. It can also occur
through the elimination of duplicate efforts in management or research and development.
Such economics are most likely to occur with either horizontal or vertical mergers. In
essence, the value goes up because the factors of production are more efficiently
organized in the combined firm.
2.
Taxes: The market value of the firm reflects its value to the private sector. Of course,
since the firm pays taxes (or may pay taxes in the future), there is an additional "shadow"
value of the firm to the public sector in the form of the present value of its tax payments.
The sum of the market value and this "shadow" value is the value of the firm to society.
In the case of synergy, the value of the firm to society is increased with a corresponding
increase in both the market and shadow values of the firm. However, if a combination of
two firms can reduce the combined present values of these firms' tax payments taken
separately, then the market value of the combined firm can exceed the sum of the values
of the two firms taken separately even if the value of the combined firm to society is just
equal to the sum of the values to society of the two firms. I.e., this combination does not
increase the total value to society, but it does redistribute the total between the
287
Robert C. Merton
shareholders of the firms and the public sector. Two examples are: (a) a more-effective
use of a tax-loss carryover; (b) increased debt capacity for the combined firm which may
reduce taxes if there is a "tax-shield" value to the deductibility of interest [see Section IX
for further discussion].
3.
The Firm to be Acquired is a "Bargain": If the firm to be acquired has a market value
which is less than its "fair" value, then by acquiring the firm, the management of the
acquiring firm can increase its stockholders' wealth. There are two distinct reasons why a
firm could be selling for less than "fair" value. The first is that relative to the acquiring
firm's information set, the stock market is not efficient in the sense to be discussed in
Section XVII.
That is, the management of the acquiring firm believes that it has
information such that if this information were widely-known, the market value of the firm
to be acquired would be higher than its acquisition cost. If this is the principal reason for
the acquisition, then the management's behavior is identical to that of a security analyst
whose job it is to identify mispriced securities. In terms of the CAPM and Section XIII,
the management believes it is purchasing a security with a positive "alpha" (α) . Hence,
all the warnings about being able to "beat the market" given in that section apply equally
well here.
A second reason why a firm could be selling for less than its "fair value" is that the firm
to be acquired is currently being mismanaged.
That is, through either incompetence or
malevolence, the current management is not managing the firm's resources so as to maximize the
market value of the firm. Unlike the first reason, this reason is completely consistent with an
efficient capital market. Indeed, as discussed at length in Section III, from society's point of
view, this reason is probably the most important one for permitting mergers and takeovers.
288
Finance Theory
Firm Diversification
Notable by its absence among the three reasons for acquisitions is diversification: That
is, the acquisition of another firm for the sole purpose of reducing the volatility (variance or
"total" riskiness) of the firm's operations. Although "diversification" is a frequently cited reason
for an acquisition, it is often not the "real" reason. More often than not, it will be for one of the
three reasons already given. However, if diversification is the real reason, then the acquisition
route will in general be an inefficient way to achieve it.
The argument for firm diversification is often presented by analogy with an individual
investor where we have seen that diversification is quite important. However, this type of
argument simply illustrates the pitfalls of treating the firm "as if" it were an individual household
with exogenous preferences rather than as an economic organization designed to serve specific
economic functions.
To show why firm diversification is not an important activity for management and if it is
undertaken, why the acquisition route is inefficient, we begin with an explicit analysis of the
value of the firm under the capital asset pricing model. Let there be two firms where each firm
has a single project as described in the beginning of Section XIV. From formula (XIV.2), the
value of firm i (i = 1,2) is given by
(XV.1)
Vi =
Ii
[ x - λ e νi ρiM ], i = 1,2.
R i
Suppose that firms #1 and #2 merge to form firm #3. In an analogous fashion to firms #1 and #2,
define I3 as the investment in firm #3 and ~x 3 as the random variable end-of-period cash flow of
firm #3 per dollar of investment. If no changes in the investment plans of the firms occur as a result of
the
combination,
then
where
x2
I3 ≡ I1 + I2 and ~
x3 ≡ δ ~
x1 + (1 - δ) ~
δ≡
I 1 . 2 ≡ VAR( ) = 2 2 + (1- δ 2 2 + 2δ (1- δ )Cov( , ).
) ν2
ν3
x% 3 δ ν 1
x% 1 x% 2
I 1+ I 2
289
Robert C. Merton
(XV.2)
ρ3M ≡ V
Cov[~
x 3 , ZM ]
ν3 σM
~
δCov[ x1 , ZM] + (1 - δ)Cov[~
x 2 , ZM ]
=
ν3 σ M
δ ν1 σM ρ1M + (1 - δ) ν 2 σM ρ2M
=
ν3 σM
δ ν1 ρ1M + (1 - δ) ν 2 ρ2M
=
ν3
From Section XIV, (XIV.2), the value of firm #3 will satisfy
V3 =
(XV.3)
I3
[ x - λe ν3 ρ3M]
R 3
Substituting into (XV.3) for ρ3M from (XV.2), we have that
V3 =
(XV.4)
I3
{ x - λe [δ ν1 ρ1M + (1 - δ) ν 2 ρ2M]}
R 3
Noting that x ≡ E[~x 3] = δ x1 + (1 - δ) x 2 , we have that
V 3=
(XV.5)
I3
{ δ [ x1 - λ eν 1 ρ 1M ] + (1- δ )[ x 2 - λ eν 2 ρ 2M ]}
R
But I3δ = I1 and I3(1–δ) = I2 . Hence, from (XV.5), we have that
I1
I
[ x1 - λ e ν1 ρ1M ] + 2 [ x 2 - λe ν 2 ρ2m]
R
R
= V1 + V 2 .
V3 =
(XV.6)
Thus, the value of the combined firm will just equal the sum of the values of the two firms prior
to the merger.
In connection with both mergers and firms possibly undertaking many (independent)
capital budgeting projects, we generalize the above demonstration to a firm with m projects.
290
Finance Theory
Let firm P take on m different projects where physical investment in project i is Ii
m
and the random variable end-of-period cash flow is IP = ∑ Ii , and total firm end-of-period cash
i =1
flow per dollar of physical investment x P , can be written as
m
x P = [∑ Ii x i]/ IP
i =1
m
(XV.7)
= ∑ δi x i
i =1
where δ i ≡ I i / I P and
m
∑δ i = 1 .
i=1
It follows from (XV.7) that
m
(XV.8)
x P = ∑ δi x i
i =1
and
(XV.9)
Var( x P ) ≡ ν 2P =
m m
∑∑δ iδ j Cov( xi , x j ) .
i=1 j=1
It follows also that
Cov( x P , ZM ) = ρPM ν P σ M
(XV.10)
m
= ∑ δi ρiM νi σM .
i =1
291
Robert C. Merton
From (XIV.2), (XV.8), and (XV.10), we have that
VP =
IP
[ x - λe ν P ρPM ]
R P
=
m
IP m
[∑ δi x i - λ e ∑ δi νi ρiM ]
R i =1
i =1
=
IP m
[∑ δi ( x i - λe νi ρiM )]
R i =1
=
∑ Vi
(XV.11)
m
i =1
where Vi = Ii ( x i - λe νi ρiM )/R is the "stand-alone" value of project i .
Hence, diversification does nothing to the market values of the firms and hence,
according to the value-maximization criterion, it is not important. The result shown in (XV.6)
and (XV.10) is called value additivity and can be shown to obtain in quite general structures
(provided that there exists a well-functioning capital market).
An intuitive explanation of why the market values are unaffected even though the
combined firm may have a smaller total risk (variance) than the individual firms is as follows: In
order for investors to be willing to pay a higher price for the combined firm than they were
willing to pay for the two firms separately, the act of combining the two firms must provide a
"service" to the investors which they were previously unable to obtain. However, prior to the
combination, any investor could purchase shares of either or both firms in any mix he wants.
And, in particular, in the case of the merger, the investor could purchase the shares of firm #1 to
firm #2 in the ratio V1 / V 2 which is exactly the ratio implicit in the combined firm. Hence, each
investor could achieve for himself (prior to the merger) the same amount of diversification (of the risks
of the firms #1 and #2) as is provided by the combined firm, and therefore, the merger provides no new
diversification opportunities to investors. For that reason, investors would not pay a premium for the
combined firm.
Although it will not be the case for the capital asset pricing model, it is possible that the
combined firm could sell for less than the sum of the values of the two separate firms, i.e., that
firm diversification could "hurt" market value. The reason is that post-consolidation, investors
have fewer choices for portfolio construction than they did pre-consolidation. For example, prior
292
Finance Theory
to the merger, an investor could hold positive amounts of firm #1 and none of firm #2 or vice
versa. Post the merger, the only way that an investor can hold firm #1 is to invest in the
combined firm #3 which means he must also invest in firm #2.
Indeed, he can only invest in firm #1 if he is willing to invest in firm #2 in the relative
proportion V1 / V2 . The reason that this "loss of freedom" does not have a negative effect on the
combined firm's value is the CAPM is that in that model, it is optimal for all investors to hold firm #1 and
firm #2 in the relative proportions V1 / V 2 which is exactly the proportion provided by the combined
firm #3.
Note that this "negative" aspect of firm diversification applies even in a "frictionless"
world of no transactions costs and where the merger takes place on terms where no premium
above market value is paid for the acquired firm by the acquiring firm. In the real world, the
acquiring firm must usually pay a premium above the market value to acquire a firm. The
premium can range from 5 to more than 100 percent with an average somewhere around 20
percent. A natural question to ask is "Why do the owners of the firm to be acquired demand a
premium for their shares?" While there are several possible explanations, one that is consistent
with our previous analyses is as follows: If the acquiring firm's management is behaving
optimally, then the reason for their making a takeover attempt must be one of the three reasons
discussed at the outset of this section. Since anyone of these three reasons will increase the value
of the acquiring firm's shares, the acquired firm's shareholders are demanding compensation for
providing the means for this increase in value. How this potential increase in value is shared
between the acquiring and acquired firms' shareholders cannot be determined in general (as is the
usual case for bilateral bargaining), but almost certainly, the acquired firm's shareholders will
demand some positive share. Of course, the acquired firm's shareholders do not know what the
acquiring firm's management believes the value of the acquired firm is. Hence, it might appear
that no consolidation could be consummated because whatever price is offered, clearly, the
acquiring firm's management believes it is worth more, and therefore, the acquired firm's
shareholders should demand more. However, the fact that the acquiring firm believes it is worth
more does not mean that it is, indeed, worth more. I.e., their beliefs may be wrong. Hence, at a
293
Robert C. Merton
high enough price above market, the acquired firm's shareholders will take the "sure" premium,
and let the acquiring firm take the risk (and earn the possible reward) that its information is
sufficiently superior to the market's that the acquired firm is still a "bargain."
Whether or not the acquired firm's shareholders or the acquiring firm's shareholders come
out ahead on these takeovers is still an open empirical question. However, it is clear that
acquiring another firm for the sole purpose of diversification is a losing proposition for the
acquiring firm because it must pay a premium for a firm whose acquisition promises no increase
in market value even if it is purchased at market.
While the premium paid over market for the acquiring firm is usually the principal cost of
an acquisition, there are other costs as well which can frequently be substantial.
In an
uncontested merger, there are legal costs and management's time which could be spent on other
activities. There are uncertainties created for the acquired firm's management, suppliers, and
customers which could affect the operations of that firm during the negotiations and subsequent
transition. Of course, if the merger is contested, then litigation costs will be substantial.
Even if it is decided that firm diversification is warranted, then achieving this
diversification through acquisition is very costly. If, because of management risk aversion or
debt capacity or supplier concerns, it is decided that the volatility or total risk of the firm should
be reduced, then this can be achieved much more efficiently (i.e., at lower cost) by simply
purchasing a portfolio of equities and fixed-income securities where no premium must be paid
over market and no significant transactions costs must be paid. If diversification is desired to
provide "cash flow" from these operations to fund growth investments in current operations, then
it is almost certainly less costly to issue securities and raise the funds in the capital markets.
Don't pay $12 to $20 to acquire $10 in cash!
If it is costly for your shareholders to diversify their portfolios by direct purchase of
individual firms' shares, then this service can be provided at less cost by mutual funds,
investment companies, and other financial intermediaries. In summary, there are three types of
reasons for a firm to consider the acquisition of another firm:
294
Finance Theory
1)
Synergy
2)
Taxes
3)
The firm to be acquired is a "Bargain"
They all have in common that the acquisition should increase the value of the acquiring firm's
current stockholders' wealth.
The possibility of a takeover of one firm by another is an important "check" which serves to force
managements to pursue policies which are (at least approximately) value-maximizing.
Diversification by the firm is, in general, not an important objective for the management of the
firm. Hence, if pursued, then a minimum of resources should be used to achieve it. Specifically,
the acquisition of another firm is a costly way to achieve diversification.
Warning:
"diversification" is frequently given as the reason for acquiring a firm by the
acquiring firm's management. If carefully investigated, (most of the time) the meaning of
"diversification" as used is not the one described here, and the real reasons will be one or more of
the three (proper) reasons for making an acquisition.
295
Download