the transition between the Old and New Traditional economies

advertisement
1
THE TRANSITION BETWEEN THE OLD AND
NEW TRADITIONAL ECONOMIES IN INDIAa*
J. Barkley Rosser, Jr.
Professor of Economics and Kirby L. Kramer, Jr. Professor
of Business Administration
MSC 0204
James Madison University
Harrisonburg, VA 22807 USA
Tel: 540-568-3212
Fax: 540-568-3010
Email: rosserjb@jmu.edu
Marina V. Rosser
Professor of Economics
James Madison University
March, 2004
JEL Classification: P4, O5
Keywords: old traditional economy, new traditional economy, transition, India
a*
The authors acknowledge useful input from Robert Eric Frykenberg, Jeffrey Miller,
Ajit Sinha, Robert C. Stuart, and two anonymous referees, none of whom are responsible
for any errors or misinterpretations contained in this paper
2
ABSTRACT
We extend Karl Polanyi’s traditional economy concept to modern economies with
advanced technology that are embedded in a traditional socio-cultural framework. This is
the New Traditional economy, seen in parts of the Islamic world and with the Hindu
nationalist movement in India. However, rural India is also the largest repository of the
Old Traditional economy with its Hindu caste and jajmani system of reciprocal labor
relations. The changes in India’s complexly mixed economy, with its increasing market
and strong planned elements, constitute a transition from the Old to the New Traditional
economy. We shall consider this transition both ideologically and systemically.
3
THE TRANSITION BETWEEN THE OLD AND
NEW TRADITIONAL ECONOMIES IN INDIA
INTRODUCTION
Rosser and Rosser (1996, 1998, 1999) introduce the concept of the New
Traditional Economy to the discussion and analysis of economic systems. This idea
derives from the trichotomization between tradition, market, and command made by Karl
Polanyi (1944). For Polanyi and his followers the traditional economy is embedded
within a broader socio-cultural framework.1 They see the traditional economy associated
with backward technology and pre-modern societies, with the rise of the market economy
leading to a "disembedding" of the economy from its socio-cultural framework to come
to dominate that framework rather than the other way around. This was the Old
Traditional Economy.
In the New Traditional Economy there is an effort to re-embed a modern or
modernizing economy within a traditional socio-cultural framework, usually associated
with a religion, but to do so while maintaining or adopting modern technology. The most
well-known example is that of the Islamic economies such as Iran where a reconstructed
view of Islamic economics has been pursued that was developed initially in Pakistan
(Maududi, 1975 [1947]) as part of the anti-colonialist struggle. Eventually this became
part of the search for an independent identity separate from the competing ideologies of
1
This idea that economic behavior may be subordinated to socio-cultural frameworks is
acceptable to most social economists and Old Institutionalists, and in economic anthropology
Polanyi’s position is known as substantivism (Sahlins, 1972; Halperin, 1988). However, this view
is criticized by the formalists who see all behavior as reflecting rational economic decisionmaking,
irrespective of the socio-cultural context. LeClair and Schneider (1974) and Pryor (1977) present
the formalist argument within economic anthropology.
4
capitalism and socialism during the Cold War.2 But it is also seen as emerging in other
socio-cultural frameworks as well.
India presents a special case with respect to this discussion. With the possible
exception of much of rural, sub-Saharan Africa, it remains arguably the site of the most
entrenched and extensive example of an actually existing Old Traditional Economy in the
jajmani system associated with the Hindu caste system in rural India. This system
persists despite markets being established in rural India for a long time and a period of
emphasis on socialist ownership of industry and indicative central planning since India's
independence in 1947 that is still largely in place and with the caste system being
formally outlawed. Although rejecting elements of the system, Mohandas (Mahatma)
Gandhi ("Father of Indian independence") defended the ideal of the rural Indian village
economy with a pre-industrial technology, arguably an Old Traditionalist ideology.
However the reality is that increasingly the forces of modernization are gradually
breaking down the isolation of India’s rural villages and integrating them into the broader
market economy of India with its continuing elements of socialist central planning.
Thus, a consciously constructed ideology of Hindu economics has appeared that
accepts modern technology more than Gandhi did and that seeks integration in the
modern world economy even while attempting to re-embed the economy within the
Hindu socio-cultural system, perhaps expressed earliest and most clearly in the work of
Deendayal Upadhyaya (1965). Currently associated with the ruling Bharatiya Janata
Party (BJP), this ideological movement can be described as New Traditionalist. Thus
India, more sharply than other nations with New Traditionalist movements, has seen a
transition from Old to New Traditionalism take place within a fairly short time period.
2
See Behdad (1989) for a survey of the range of Islamic views of property rights.
5
The nature of this transition, both in economic thought and in its relation to the actual
state of the Indian economy, is the subject of this paper.
Following this introduction, the second section reviews the comparison between
the Old and New Traditionalist perspectives. The third examines this comparison in
relation to the views of Gandhi and Upadhyaya in particular. The fourth considers the
historical development of the Indian economic system and its prospects in light of this
discussion. A concluding section follows.
THE OLD AND NEW TRADITIONALIST PERSPECTIVES COMPARED
The concept of the traditional economy is largely due to Karl Polanyi, with his
views about it evolving over time. In The Great Transformation (1944) he posited three
kinds of traditional economy: household, reciprocal, and redistributive, with an implied
story of historical evolution through these three. Later (1957) he modified his
perspective to accept the more widely held view of economic anthropologists that the
reciprocal form was historically the most primitive form (Stodder, 1995a,b). The
paradigmatic example for such reciprocal exchange is the famous case of the Trobriand
Islanders ritually trading kula within a broad socio-cultural framework, as studied by
Malinowski (1922). The redistributive form is exemplified by the "Big Man" societies
wherein a central leader collects and then redistributes goods. It has been argued that the
ancient empires developed out of this form, and some see it as a precursor of the later
command economic system.
The household system is more likely to arise in peasant economies with
independent households. Such systems are likely to be more technologically advanced
6
and more involved in market exchanges than the earlier reciprocal form. But, it is
arguably a common characteristic of all traditional economic systems to emphasize the
role of the household and of familistic groupism, with such a concern often extending
beyond the immediate family to broader groups such as clans, or arguably castes as in
India, or even a nation as a whole as has been argued for modern (and partly New
Traditionalist) Japan (Murakami, 1984).
Few observers appear to advocate the Old Traditional economy as a system in any
of its forms, at least fully. One does find Polanyi and others comparing such economies
at least partly favorably with more market-oriented and dominated economies on the
grounds of the stronger community orientation to be found in the traditional economy,
and the Marxist tradition has long idealized the supposed “primitive communism” of
early human societies. This point has certainly been emphasized in literature, especially
Romantic poetry, with William Blake complaining of the "Satanic mills" of the industrial
revolution in Britain. Indeed, it is easy to dismiss such arguments as merely representing
a misplaced nostalgia or romanticization. But, it can be argued that if one allows a
broader view of the literature then another set of works emerge that can be seen as taking
such a view. These might include Islam’s holy book, the Qur'an, and the Hind Swaraj by
Mohandas Gandhi as will be argued further below. For these works the central issue is
subordinating market forces to the strictures of ethical rules based on religion.
The great divide between the Old Traditional and New Traditional perspectives is
over technology and accepting or advocating the adoption of modern technology.
Accompanying this is the advocacy of a re-embedding of modern or modernizing
economies within some traditional socio-cultural framework, usually based on some
7
religion. Certainly Polanyi accepted the adoption of modern technology, but he appears
to have seen the resolution of the problems of alienation and dislocation associated with
modern market economies in their replacement by some form of socialism. In short, he
accepted the idea that the appearance of modern technology, especially industrial
technology, necessarily brings about the end of the traditional economy and its
replacement by and subordination to either the market or command system.
As Rosser and Rosser (1996, 1998, 1999) argue, New Traditionalism has arisen
largely out of advocates of various religions, especially in countries that faced actual or
threatened political or economic domination from outside by the western industrialized
powers. Most of the major world religions now have persons associated with them who
can be seen as advocating to some degree or other a New Traditionalist perspective,
including even various branches of Christianity and Judaism in the advanced market
economies.3 In the case of Japan, the move arguably came with the Meiji Restoration of
1868 when the leadership chose to open up to outside influences in science and
technology while seeking to preserve Japanese culture. This is symbolized by the phrase
that was emphasized beginning then of Wa-kon Yo-sai, "Japanese spirit and Western
ability." Such a shift would come later in other areas of the neo-Confucian4 zone (Hungchao, 1989; Rozman, 1991; Zhang, 1999).
3
For Protestant Christian movements see North (1987), Wallis (1987), and Innaconne (1993).
For Roman Catholic Christianity see the United States Catholic Conference (1993). For Judaism
see Tamari (1987) and Neusner (1990). Other religions for which New Traditionalist movements
can be identified include Buddhism (Spiro, 1970; Keyes, 1993) and Sikhism (Oberoi, 1993).
4 Although the term “neo-Confucian” is now generally used to describe a revived Confucianism
that supports modern economic growth and development, the term was originally applied to a
synthetic official imperial religion that emerged in China in the eleventh and twelfth centuries.
This religion was anti-commercial and xenophobic and would express itself in the most extreme
form in the isolationist “Hermit Kingdom” of Choson Korea (Nahm, 1988; Cumings, 1997).
8
The important case of Islamic economics was a consciously constructed effort
arising directly out of the anti-colonial struggle in the British Raj. The work of Maududi
(1975 [1947]) combined a search for an Islamic identity in newly independent Pakistan
within the modern world with studies of modern British economic thought whose
influence was felt by thinkers in that area under the British colonial experience. Even
today, a disproportionate number of leading Islamic economists have come from Pakistan
originally (Siddiqui, 1980; Kuran, 1993; Nasr, 1994).
Curiously, it can be argued that the views of the Prophet Muhammed himself
were New Traditionalist in that he did not oppose modern technology or science, per se.
The same might be argued for the great medieval Islamic philosopher, Ibn Khaldun, who
presented fairly sophisticated analyses of economic issues and questions (Issawi, 1987).
But, of course neither of these had to deal with the kind of society that would arise with
the emergence of modern industrial technology and the phenomenon of rapid
technological and social change. This made them de facto and in comparison with the
modern Islamic economists, theorists of the Old Traditional economic system.
Given this array of examples and cases it can be asked at this point if there is any
substantial difference between the concept of the New Traditional economy and that of
“national capitalism” (Rodrik, 2003) that has become especially popular since the
collapse of the command socialist system. This view argues that although now almost all
nations have adopted the market capitalist system, each does so in its own way with its
own local institutional variations that reflect its own national cultural, political, and
historical traditions, including those involving economic practices. Thus, the French
economic system continues to exhibit elements of its long dirigiste tradition from Colbert
9
(if not earlier intellectually), even as it no longer uses formal indicative planning (Kresl
and Gallais, 2002); the German economic system continues to exhibit remnants of its
unique Mitbestimmung system of industrial relations that arguably reflects traditions
dating from the medieval guild system even as this has weakened with the slowdown of
the German economy since its 1990 reunification (Smyser, 1992), and Sweden continues
to have probably the most extensive welfare state system of any essentially market
capitalist economy despite some cutbacks and reforms in the early 1990s, which arguably
reflects a balance of individualism and communalism that dates from the Viking era
(Freeman, Topel, and Swedenborg, 1997). Likewise, the familistic groupism of Japan
discussed above can be seen as simply a holdover of elements of its feudal system.
However, in our view what distinguishes this viewpoint from ours is that in the
case of the New Traditional economy there is a conscious effort to revive something that
has been perceived to have been lost, and that what has been lost is part of a fully
developed socio-cultural system, usually based on a religion. Ideologically the goal is to
re-embed the modern economy within this system, even if this is ultimately a hopeless
cause. Often, this perceived system has been artificially reconstructed, as with the
example of modern Islamic economics, and arguably with the more extreme (and more
recent) versions of Hindu economics as well. In contrast, the sorts of national variations
described above in Western Europe do not involve efforts to revive some full blown
traditional system. Rather they are simply institutional forms that have evolved in those
economies fully as part of their modernity, but which nevertheless reflect elements of
their past national uniqueness. They exist separately from any effort to reimpose a
presumed former system ultimately based on a non-economic ideological structure.
10
THE TRANSITION FROM GANDHI TO UPADHYAYA
Perhaps more than any other work, Mohandas Gandhi's Hind Swaraj of 1909
(Gandhi, 1958), written well before he became the leader of the Congress Movement in
India (and "Father of Indian independence"), is a clear statement of support for the Old
Traditional economy as an economic system. Indeed, the general public image of
Gandhi's views on economics is based on this work, which takes a more extreme position
than he evolved to later in his life. It calls for a particularly utopian economic model for
India. Central to this work is the concept of swaraj, or "self-rule," achievable for Indians
only by adhering to their traditional civilization. He saw this as corrupted by the
influence of the British colonial rulers who broke down the autarkic autonomy of rural
villages through introducing railroads, through their imposing of laws that undermined
traditional customs, and through doctors who lowered the mortality rate thus triggering a
population explosion that undermined the "Hindu equilibrium" (Lal, 1988-89, 1993),
although it can be argued that the introduction of green revolution technologies into rural
agriculture has more recently played this role. He opposed modern machinery, with
villages to be self-sufficient in producing hand-spun cloth with spinning wheels, with the
latter becoming the symbol of the Congress movement. The caste system and its system
of reciprocal patron-client relations known as jajmani was to be preserved, although
untouchability, the condition of being beneath all caste categories, was to be eliminated.5
Trade protectionism was strongly supported, a position that became a main feature of
post-independence Indian economic policy.
11
However, a more complete overview of the evolution of Gandhi's views shows a
moderation of some of these views as he came to feel the responsibility of leading the
national independence movement. Dasgupta (1996) has documented this evolution by
thoroughly surveying his numerous articles, interviews, letters, and speeches in Hindi,
English, and his native Gujarati. A general theme that emerges is that although Gandhi
favored an ethical approach over that of mere utilitarian economics, he came to
understand that moral values themselves may be in conflict, especially within the context
of economic decisionmaking. This led him to a position of arguing that ethical rules that
imply impractical economics may be invalid. Thus, by the end of his life, Gandhi's views
on many economic issues came to be more nuanced with general positions modified by
exceptions or qualifications derived from the hard practicalities of economic imperatives.
Thus, although the poorest should be materially uplifted, welfare is bad because it
destroys work incentives and the rich should not be dispossessed. Although villages
should be self-sufficient, they may import certain necessary items such as surgical
equipment. Machinery may be allowed to produce certain necessary items, such as
Singer sewing machines to be used in conjunction with spinning wheels. While
supporting the rights of the oppressed (to be asserted nonviolently according to the
doctrine of satyagraha or "truth-force"), he saw rights as tied to duties and opposed the
UN Declaration of Human Rights. While opposing the killing of cows in accordance
with traditional Hindu beliefs, he discussed ways to improve productivity in the leather
goods and other animal parts industries. While supporting cooperation between workers
and capitalists and between tenants and landlords through his theory of "trusteeship," he
5
The evolution of the role of castes can be seen as the central issue in the struggle between
modernity and tradition in India. Rudolph and Rudolph (1967) provide a broad analysis of how
12
supported nonviolent removal by tenants of landlords receiving special privileges from
the British. While opposing contraceptives, he supported slowing population growth
through the "rhythm method" of birth control. He proclaimed the equality of men and
women and supported equal pay for equal work, while declaring it a woman's place to
raise children. While the individual was the foundation of society, the good of the
individual is the good of all. He called the law of supply and demand a "devilish"
concept, yet he supported the use of the market and the ideas of efficiency and
entrepreneurship (Dasgupta, 1996).
Furthermore, he declared himself to be a "socialist" and was the prime force
behind the more strongly socialist Jawaharlal Nehru's coming to the leadership of the
Congress movement, even as he rejected Marxist class struggle and differed with Nehru's
pro-industrialization position. Given the ultimate complexity of his views it is
unsurprising that today nearly all political movements look to Gandhi's writings as a
source of support for their respective ideological positions, from pro-free market to
socialist, and, of course, the new traditionalist Hindu nationalists of the BJP.
For the latter, as well as their predecessors in the Bharatiya Jana Sangh (BJS)
party, how to deal with Gandhi and his legacy has been a profound problem. This is
because historically he was the great opponent of their viewpoint of Hindu nationalism,
supporting general religious tolerance and especially of the Muslims. The history of the
Congress movement included a period when the Hindu nationalists dominated it, notably
after Lord Curzon partitioned Bengal in 1905, leading to the formation of the Muslim
the position of the Untouchables has evolved in law and politics over time in India.
13
League6 and a backlash by the Hindu nationalists. This period continued until Gandhi
came to lead the movement around 1919 and imposed his more tolerant perspective
(Frykenberg, 1993; Pattanaik, vol. 2, 1998).
It was only after they lost control of the Congress movement that the Hindu
nationalists began to form their own separate organizations and political movements.
Probably the most important of these was a technically purely cultural organization, the
Rashtriya Swayamsevak Sangh (RSS) which exists today. It has formed the activist core
of both the BJS and the current ruling BJP, with the current prime minister of India, Atal
Bihari Vajpayee, having come out of it. The RSS has been banned three times in India's
history: first after a Hindu nationalist assassinated Gandhi in 1948 for his tolerant views
of religion, then during the period of direct rule by Indira Gandhi in the mid-1970s, and
in 1992-93 after Hindu nationalists destroyed a mosque on a sacred Hindu site in Ayodha
in northern India, thus triggering widespread communal riots.7
Clearly there are serious difficulties for any Hindu nationalist in invoking the
authority of Gandhi, not only his tolerance of Muslims and other minority religious
groups in India, but his support of equal rights for untouchables and women. And of
course there is the terrible legacy of Gandhi's assassination by a Hindu nationalist, a
continuing embarrassment for them. Nevertheless, given his support of the caste system
6
This partition was along the lines of the current border between India and Bangladesh and
triggered the eventual movement for a more general partition that would occur with independence
in 1947, with the creation of Muslim Pakistan out of the former British Raj as well as of India and
later the predominantly Buddhist nations of Sri Lanka (Ceylon) and Myanmar (Burma).
7 The official view of the RSS is to support Hindutva, the idea developed in the 1920s that
Hinduism is a cultural identity that all Indians share irrespective of their official religious identities.
As current Prime Minister Vajpayee put it in 1968, “Indian Muslims and Christians did not come
from outside. Their ancestors were Hindus. Culture does not change with religion” (Pattanaik,
Vol. 1, 1998, p. 72). Curiously the concept of Hinduism as a well-defined religious identity in India
only came with the British in their 1871 census when they categorized anyone as “Hindu” who
was not Buddhist, Jain, Jewish, Christian, Muslim, Parsi, or Sikh. It was only at the 1893 World
14
and his support of the traditional culture and economy of rural India, the Hindu
nationalists have been strongly attracted to many of his views and have not only adopted
them but have indeed loudly proclaimed his support of these positions. They have even
invoked him regarding the issue of "reservations" of government jobs for members of
lower castes, which they strongly oppose, noting that Gandhi supported equality of
opportunity rather than equality of outcomes.
The key figure in reconciling Hindu nationalism and Gandhiism was Deendayal
Upadhyaya, most notably in his Integral Humanism (1965). Upadhyaya is especially
important in being both a main founder of the BJS as well as being its leading ideologist,
with the successor BJP also looking to him for guidance. He is the figure who took the
more nuanced positions of Gandhi and transformed them into something more closely
resembling New Traditionalism. Although he argued for a "third path" consonant with
the ancient Hindu social order and supported Gandhian decentralization and selfsufficiency, he altered the view of technology to be that of swadeshi. This still implied
the idea of being "home-spun," but now was altered to allow for modern technology. In
conjunction with ideas of several western-influenced economists, Upadhyaya emphasized
the issue of what would now be called "appropriate technology," namely that it be
consistent with the labor-intensive factor conditions of India. Also, he explicitly called
for a "third way" between capitalism and communism, a position even more strongly
stated by Vajpayee, the current prime minister, who led the BJS at the end of the 1960s
(Lal, 1993, p. 419).
Parliament of Relgions in Chicago that Hinduism was generally recognized as a “great world
religion” (Frykenberg, 1993).
15
More recently a variety of Indian economists have followed up on Upadhyaya in
trying to construct a "Hindu economics." Much of this effort consciously imitates the
efforts of the New Traditionalist Islamic economists of Pakistan in attempting to
explicitly reconcile modern economics concepts with traditional Hindu ideas taken from
such ancient texts as the Rig Veda.8 One is Bokare (1993) who claims to subsume all
previous economic thought in his system of thought. He supports a decentralized
(Gandhian) order of "exploitationless" self-employment (socialism), with no taxes and
no interest (Islamic economics), appropriate technology (Upadhyaya), and a general
market context. Arguably this sort of effort reflects more an all-embracing incoherence
than a genuine alternative economic system.
We should be clear about why Old Traditionalism simply cannot fill the bill for
the Hindu nationalists. Even though much of the rural economy continues to fall into that
category, Gandhi was right in noting the breakdown of the autarky of the rural villages
with the spread of railroads. British-based legal codes broke down the authority of the
old traditions, and the rise of population broke down the old economic equilibrium. More
recently since Gandhi’s time this latter has been further accelerated by the introduction of
green revolution technologies into the countryside. Furthermore, this rise in population
has resulted in large-scale migration to the cities9 where the more modern market and
planned socialist sectors of the Indian economy hold sway, with urbanites more able to
escape from the socio-economic strictures of the caste system to some extent. This
8
Ironically, the earliest work on economics or politics in India, the Arthashastra of Kautilya, dating
from the fourth century B.C.E., makes no reference to Hindu concepts at all and presents an
essentially Machiavellian instrumentalist approach to statecraft, urging the use of whatever will
maximize power of the ruler and his ability to conquer the world (Lal, 1993, p. 411).
9 India remains a majority rural in population, although urbanization is accelerating rapidly.
Becker, Williamson, and Mills (1992) argue that the urbanization process has actually been
slowed by the nature of the economic system somewhat.
16
pattern repeats that which emerged in Europe initially in the late medieval period, but
which accelerated dramatically with the Industrial Revolution, of peasants escaping from
the feudalism of the countryside by joining the market economy of the cities. So, the
drive for a New Traditional approach in India depends more on being relevant for those
who live in the more modern economy of the urban areas than on being so for the still
largely Old Traditional rural dwellers, even if this relevance is substantially to provide a
nostalgic identity in a rapidly changing economic and social environment.
SYSTEMIC EVOLUTION OF THE INDIAN ECONOMY
Using the Polanyian trichotomization of tradition, market, and command, it can be
argued that India possesses the most compexly mixed economic system in the world, with
all three elements strongly present. We have already noted the ongoing presence
throughout much of rural India of the caste system and its non-monetary set of reciprocal
patron-client jajmani relations involving direct compensation in services and products
(Lal, 1988). This is the deeply entrenched remnant of the Old Traditional economy,
which has largely lost its economic hold in urban areas. We note here that although
traditional Brahminic Hinduism has four broad castes: Brahmin priests, Kshatriya
warriors, Vaisya merchants, and Sudra workers and farmers, the more detailed reality is a
much finer gradation of many specific castes who constitute the elements of the specific
jajmani economies in specific local areas of India.10
10
In the census of 1901, the British counted 2,378 castes, sub-castes, and tribes in the Raj, with
the tribal population being viewed as not properly Hindu by the priestly Brahmin caste members
even though they were so categorized by the British (Edwardes, 1961, p. 72). See also
Frykenberg (1993) and Singh (1993).
17
At the same time, even as it was once one of the "ancient empires," India has from
the depths of history been a major center of international trade throughout the Indian
Ocean. As far back as Mohenjodaro around 2500 B.C.E. there was trade with
Mesopotamia and with Rome from the time of Emperor Tiberius out of the southeastern
port of Arikamedu. Although the earliest exports were precious jewels, from the time of
Tiberius forward cotton cloth would be India's prime export until the industry was
severely reduced under the impact of the industrial revolution in Britain during British
rule in the early 1800s (Tomlinson, 1993). Indeed, during 1200-1300s, India was
arguably the "hinge" of world trade (Abu-Lughod, 1989). There is evidence that prior to
the British conquest in the 1700s, India may even have had a higher standard of living
than Britain as attested by none other than India's conqueror, Robert Clive:
"On entering Murshidabad, the old capital of Bengal in 1757, Clive wrote: 'The
city is extensive, populous and rich as the city of London, with this difference that there
were individuals in the first possessing infinitely greater property than in the last city.'
Similar words were used of Agra, Fatechpore, Lahore and many other Indian towns."
(Goody, 1996, p. 113)11
11
This view of Abu-Lughod and Goody that India and other east Asian nations, especially China,
were better off than Europe until the industrial revolution has been argued vigorously by others,
including Chaudhuri (1990), Blaut (1993), and Frank (1998). Certain basic practices of modern
market economies arose in India such as accounting systems using the number zero in their
arithmetic (Goody, 1996). Landes (1998) criticizes this view of India and Asia more generally,
arguing that they did not have a substantial lead over Europe even in the medieval period.
18
Whatever the actual reality, it was widely perceived in India that the Indian cotton
cloth industry was destroyed by British imperialism and trade policies,12 a fundamental
underpinning of both Gandhi's swaraj ideology of self-sufficiency as well as of the
protectionist trade policies adopted after independence by the Congress Party
governments initially led by Gandhi's pro-socialist protegé, Nehru. Inspired by the
Soviet example, Nehru introduced extensive central planning of the indicative variety
(Mohan and Aggarwal, 1990; Byrd, 1990), and established new state-owned enterprises.
These policies were carried much further by his daughter, Indira Gandhi, in the early
1970s when she carried out a wave of nationalizations and imposed a series of strict
regulations on the remaining privately owned sector and on imports, an ultra-protectionist
system known as the "License-Permit Raj" (Nayar, 1989).
Much of Indian economic policy since, both under her son, Rajiv Gandhi in the
1980s, and especially under a Congress government in 1991, has been to undo her
legacy.13 This has included some lowering of tariffs and loosening of controls on foreign
direct investment, some loosening of the various regulations on firm size14 and firm
entry, sale of stock in state-owned enterprises, and various monetary and fiscal changes
(Bhagwati, 1993; Joshi and Little, 1996; Ahluwalia, 2002). The GDP growth rate has
12
For an argument that this widely accepted damage to the Indian cotton textile industry by the
British has been substantially exaggerated see Tirthankar (2002).
13 The process by which the movement towards full-blown socialism was halted and reversed is
rather complex. According to Nayar (1989), it was Indira Gandhi herself who made the initial
moves as early as 1974 after an outbreak of inflation and her failure to nationalize wholesale
trade in wheat. Kohli (1989) sees her as adopting both a more pro-Hindu and pro-business
stance after the 1977 election when the Congress Party was defeated in the Hindu heartland. He
argues that secular socialism and pro-business Hinduism are competing ideologies, although this
seems overly simplistic given that the harder line Hindu nationalist factions of the BJP tend to
oppose market reforms. In any case, despite reformist moves by both Indira and Rajiv Gandhi,
the government’s share of investment continued to increase all the way through the 1980s, only
clearly declining after the 1991 reforms (Joshi and Little, 1996, p. 38).
14 Regulations on firm size were viewed as fitting in with the Gandhian ideal of small village
enterprises, and such regulations have been especially strict in the cotton cloth industry.
19
risen since the early 1980s, despite a foreign exchange crisis in 1991 (Clark and Wolcott,
2003; Basu, 2004), and has been accompanied by the emergence of a high technology
sector seen to be competing with high income countries such as the United States.
However, along with this increased growth rate has come an apparent increase in income
inequality, both regionally (Drèze and Sen, 1995, 1996) and between rural and urban
areas (Datt and Ravallion, 2002).
Nevertheless, India retains much of its previous socialism, with indicative
planning still in place, if weakened, with continuing state ownership of most firms
previously owned by the central government (even though some state governments are
engaged in full privatization programs), and the continuation of many regulations,
especially in labor markets, and a still higher degree of trade protectionism than in all of
India's trading partners (Ahluwalia, 2002).15 Thus it is that India is a deeply mixed
economy with significant elements of all three of the principal systemic categories
defined by Polanyi, with these elements altering their respective balance over time.
The position of the ideologically pro-New Traditionalism BJP in all of this is
highly equivocal and complex and evolving. Prior to its gaining power at the national
level in the mid-1990s, the BJP and its predecessor BJS only had governing experience at
the state level. Generally the most prominent policies actually implemented were
weakening the favoring of lower castes in state government hiring and imposing strict
rules forbidding the killing of cows. After marketizing and opening to foreign trade and
investment accelerated after 1991 under the Congress Party, state governments under the
BJP opposed certain direct foreign investments that had been approved by the central
15
That eliminating most of the continuing restrictions on trade is advocated by most Indian
economists can be seen by the survey of many of their views in Balasubramanyan (2001).
20
government on cultural grounds, including by KFC and Coca-Cola. The most prominent
such example case came in 1995 in the state of Maharashtra which contains India's
largest city and financial capital, Mumbai (Bombay), when the local BJP-dominated
government cancelled a contract by U.S.-based Enron to build new electricity generating
facilities, a particularly severe need in much of India. This decision was later overturned
by a federal court and the contract reinstated.
However, since achieving power at the national level, the BJP appears to have at
least initially downplayed its Hindu nationalist ideology except for proceeding with
building and testing nuclear weapons in confrontation with neighboring Pakistan over
Jammu-Kashmir and more generally competing with Pakistan over nuclear energy and
space programs. Even so, and despite engaging in military conflict with Pakistan, Prime
Minister Vajpayee visited Pakistan in a peace effort and such efforts have continued
despite ups and downs in the Indo-Pakistani relationship. In power, the BJP has
continued the opening and marketizing reforms initiated by the previous Congress
government, although this has been demanded by the coalition partners in its government,
most of them regionally based parties without whom the BJP would be unable to rule.
Despite this turn of policy, it remains the case that substantial factions within the
BJP (especially those associated with the old RSS) oppose these policies and support a
reimposition of protectionism and other more identifiably New Traditionalist policies.
Some of these views have been manifested in such phenomena as the suppression of
Christian missionaries in some parts of India, and other actions to assert the cultural
supremacy of Hinduism within Indian society. This has accelerated more recently since
21
riots between Hindus and Muslims broke out in Gujarat16 where the BJP-led state
government supported a hard pro-Hindu line and was strongly reelected. In 2003, new
efforts were made to impose restrictions at the national level on the killing of cows by the
BJP, against the wishes of its coalition partners.
The exact balance that the BJP-dominated government will establish between its
marketizing reform policies, the maintenance of its socialist indicative planning, and its
impulses towards New Traditionalism remain unclear. But, it is clearly the case that the
remaining traditional element in Indian economic ideology and reality is increasingly of
the New rather than of the Old variety. That particular transition is fully underway.
SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS
In India the transition between the Old and New Traditional economies, both
ideologically and in fact, has been much closer and immediate than in other areas where
New Traditionalist movements are important. In the Islamic world a much longer gap
existed between the formulation of the Old Traditionalist doctrines in the medieval period
and their replacement by the New Traditionalist ones beginning in the mid-twentieth
century after the experience of European colonialism.17 Similar observations can be
made about most other such movements as well.
16
It should be understood that the variety of cultures and economic systems in India may be
greater than one finds in all of Europe, India being called a “subcontinent” for good reason. Thus
one finds a very free market approach prevailing in high income and partly Sikh-inhabited Punjab
in the northwest, an oppressive version of the Old Traditional system in poverty-stricken and very
Hindu Bihar in the northeast (Drèze and Sen, 1995, 1996), and a highly egalitarian form of
socialism in partly Christian-inhabited Kerala in the southwest (Parayil, 2000).
17 It can be argued that the Taliban movement in Afghanistan represented a revival of a form of
Old Traditionalist Islam, given its apparent rejection of many modern things. Although this may
be the case, many of its strict ideas are not found in traditional Islam and were invented by the
Taliban itself. Thus, it may represent a kind of “neo-Old Traditionalism.”
22
In the case of India, a substantial actually existing Old Traditional economy has
persisted in the villages and countryside, although under pressures to change from
modern transportation and agricultural technologies as well as the increasing influence of
the official legal system. The writings of Mohandas Gandhi early in the twentieth
century represent a strong advocacy of the Old Traditionalist perspective, albeit with
some reformist elements such as equal rights for lower castes, women, and religious
minorities that put him at odds with Hindu nationalists. Many of his ideas, such as trade
protectionism and small village industries, came to have influence on post-independence
economic policy, despite a strong emphasis on heavy industry by the socialist central
planners under the direction of India's first prime minister, Jawaharlal Nehru. The
combination of these socialist-oriented policies with the traditionalist legacy and a deeply
entrenched market economy has left India as one of the most complexly mixed
economies in the world.
Although they were tainted with the assassination of Gandhi in 1948, Hindu
nationalists under the leadership of Deendayal Upadhyaya in the 1960s developed a New
Traditionalist ideology that drew heavily on Gandhi's ideas. However, they accepted
modern technology in "appropriate" forms while differing with Gandhi on such issues as
religious tolerance. While ruling state governments, the Hindu nationalist parties have
opposed programs favoring hiring of disadvantaged castes and have implemented such
laws as forbidding the killing of cows. In the early 1990s, such state governments
opposed foreign direct investments that were being allowed by a reforming central
government. However, leading several central governments since the mid-1990s in
coalition with parties favoring pro-market reforms, the Hindu nationalist BJP has
23
increasingly shifted toward such policies, although continuing to push certain distinctive
policies such as preventing the killing of cows.
Effectively its New Traditionalism in practice may amount to a gradualism that
leaves the major elements of the highly mixed Indian economy in place. Such an
outcome would be consistent with the long expressed admiration for a "third way"
between capitalism and communism by the leaders of this movement in India, and by
supporters of New Traditionalism more generally. Thus, the movement has made its
transition from the old to the new, both ideologically and in policy terms as well.
REFERENCES
Ahluwalia, Montek S. “Economic Reforms in India Since 1991: Has Gradualism
Worked?” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Summer 2002, Vol. 16(3), pp. 67-88.
Abu-Lughod, Janet. Before European Hegemony: The World System A.D. 1250-1350.
New York: Oxford University Press, 1989.
Balasubramanyam. V.N. Conversations with Indian Economists. Basingstoke: Palgrave,
2001.
Basu, Kaushik, Editor. India’s Emerging Economy: Performance and Prospects in the
1990s and Beyond. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2004.
24
Becker, Charles M., Williamson, Jeffrey G., and Mills, Edwin S. Indian Urbanization
and Economic Growth since 1960. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1992.
Behdad, Sohrab. “Property Rights in Contemporary Islamic Thought: A Critical Survey.”
Review of Social Economy, Summer 1989, Vol. 47(2), pp. 185-211.
Bhagwati, Jagdish. India in Transition: Freeing the Economy. Oxford, UK: Clarendon
Press, 1993.
Blaut, James M. The Colonizer’s Model of the World: Geographical Diffusionism and
Eurocentric History. New York: Guilford Press, 1993.
Bokare, M.G. Hindu Economics: Eternal Economic Order. New Dehli: Janati Prakashan,
1993.
Byrd, William A. “Planning in India: Lessons from four Decades of Development.”
Journal of Comparative Economics, December 1990, Vol. 14(4), pp. 713-735.
Chaudhuri, K.-N. Asia Before Europe: Economy and Civilisation in the Indian Ocean
from the Rise of Islam. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1990.
25
Clark, Gregory and Wolcott, Susan.. “One Polity, Many Countries: Economic Growth in
India, 1873-2000,” Rodrik, Dani, Editor, In Search of Prosperity: Analytic Narratives on
Economic Growth. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2003, pp. 53-79.
Cumings, Bruce. Korea's Place in the Sun: A Modern History. New York: W.W. Norton,
1997.
Dasgupta, Ajit K. Gandhi’s Economic Thought. London: Routledge, 1996.
Datt, Gaurav and Ravallion, Martin. “Is India’s Economic Growth Leaving the Poor
Behind?” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Summer 2002, Vol. 16(3), pp. 89-108.
Drèze, Jean and Sen, Amartya. India: Economic Development and Social Opportunity.
Oxford and Dehli: Oxford University Press, 1995.
Drèze, Jean and Amartya Sen, Editors. Indian Development: Selected Regional
Perspectives. Oxford and Dehli: Oxford University Press, 1996.
Edwardes, Michael. A History of India: From the Earliest Times to the Present Day.
New York: Farrar, Straus, and Cudahy, 1961.
Frank, Andre Gunder. ReOrient: Global Economy in the Asian Age. Berkeley: University
of California Press, 1998.
26
Freeman, Richard B., Topel, Robert, and Swedenborg, Birgitta, Editors. The Welfare
State in Transition: Reforming the Swedish Model. Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
1997.
Frykenberg, Robert Eric. “Hindu Fundamentalism and the Structural Stability of India,”
Marty, Martin E. and Appleby, R. Scott, Editors, Fundamentalisms and the State:
Remaking Polities, Economies, and Militance. Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
1993, pp. 233-255.
Gandhi, Mohandas K. The Collected Works of Mahatma Gandhi, volume 10. Dehli:
Government of India, Publications Division, 1958.
Goody, Jack. The East in the West. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1996.
Halperin, Rhoda. Economies Across Cultures. New York: Macmillan, 1998.
Hung-chao, T., Editor. Confucianism and Economic Development: An Oriental
Alternative? Washington: The Washington Institute Press, 1989.
Iannaccone, Laurence R. “Heirs to the Protestant Ethic? The Economics of American
Fundamentalists,” Marty, Martin E. and Appleby, R. Scott, Editors, Fundamentalisms
27
and the State: Remaking Polities, Economies, and Militance. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press, 1993, pp. 342-366.
Issawi, Charles, Translator and Arranger. An Arab Philosophy of History: Selections from
the “Prolegomena” of Ibn Khaldun of Tunis (1332-1406). Princeton: Princeton
University Press, 1987.
Joshi, Vijay. and Little, I.M.D. India’s Economic Reforms, 1991-2001. Oxford, UK:
Clarendon Press, 1996.
Keyes, Charles F. “Buddhist Economics and Buddhist Fundamentalism in Burma and
Thailand,” Marty, Martin E. and Appleby, R. Scott, Editors, Fundamentalisms and the
State: Remaking Polities, Economies, and Militance. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, 1993, pp. 367-409.
Kohli, Atul. “Politics of Economic Liberalization in India.” World Development, March
1989, Vol. 17(3), pp. 305-328.
Kresl, Peter Karl, Gallais, Sylvain. France Encounters Globalization. Cheltenham:
Edward Elgar, 2002.
28
Kuran, Timur. “The Economic Impact of Islamic Fundamentalism,” Marty, Martin E. and
Appleby, R.Scott, Editors, Fundamentalisms and the State: Remaking Polities,
Economies, and Militance. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1993, pp. 302-341.
Lal, Deepak. 1988. The Hindu Equilibrium: Cultural Stability and Economic Stagnation:
India 1500-1980 AD, volume 1. Oxford, UK: Clarendon Press, 1988, volume 2. Oxford
UK: Clarendon Press, 1989.
Lal, Deepak. “The Economic Impact of Hindu Fundamentalism,” Marty, Martin E. and
Appleby, R.Scott, Editors, Fundamentalisms and the State: Remaking Polities,
Economies, and Militance. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1993, pp. 410-426.
Landes, David S. The Wealth and Poverty of Nations: Why Some Are So Rich and Some
Are So Poor. New York: W.W. Norton, 1998.
LeClair, Edward E. and Schneider, Harold K., Editors. Economic Anthropology:
Readings in Theory and Analysis. New York: Holt, Rinehart, and Winston, 1974.
Malinowski, Bronisław. Argonauts of the Western Pacific. London: Routledge, 1922.
Maududi, Sayyid A.A. The Economic Problem of Man and Its Islamic Solution. Lahore:
Lahore Islamic Productions, 1975. Originally in Urdu [1947].
29
Mohan, Rakesh and Aggarwal, Vandana. “Commands and Controls: Planning for Indian
Industrial Development.” Journal of Comparative Economics, December 1990, Vol.
14(4), pp. 681-712.
Murakami, Yasusuke. “Ie Society as a Pattern of Civilization.” Journal of Japanese
Studies, Winter 1984, Vol. 10(2), pp. 281-263.
Nahm, Andrew C. Korea, Tradition and Transformation: A History of the Korean
People. Elizabeth: Hollym International, 1988.
Nasr, S.V.R. The Vanguard of the Islamic Revolution: The Jama’at-I Islami of Pakistan.
Berkeley: University of California Press, 1994.
Nayar, Baldev Raj. India’s Mixed Economy: The Role of Ideology and Interest in its
Development. Bombay: Popular Prakashan, 1989.
Neusner, Jacob. The Economics of the Mishnah. Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
1990.
North, Gary. Inherit the Earth: Biblical Principles for Economics. Fort Worth: Dominion
Press, 1987.
30
Oberoi, Harjot. “Sikh Fundamentalism: Translating History into Theory,” Marty, Martin
E. and Appleby, R.Scott, Editors, Fundamentalisms and the State: Remaking Polities,
Economies, and Militance. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1993, pp. 265-285.
Parayil, Govindan, Editor. Kerala: The Development Experience. London: Zed Books,
2000.
Pattanaik, D.D. Hindu Nationalism in India, volumes 1 and 2. New Dehli: Deep & Deep
Publications, 1998.
Polanyi, Karl. The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of our
Time. Boston: Beacon Press, 1944.
Polanyi, Karl. “The Economy as an Instituted Process,” Polanyi, Karl, Arensberg, C.M.,
and Pearson, H.W., Editors, Trade and Market in the Early Empires. Glencoe: The Free
Press, 1957, pp. 243-270.
Pryor, Frederic L. The Origins of the Economy: A Comparative Study of Distribution in
Primitive and Peasant Economies. New York: Academic Press, 1977.
Rodrik, Dani, Editor. In Search of Prosperity: Analytic Narratives on Economic Growth.
Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2003.
31
Rosser, J. Barkley, Jr. and Marina V. Rosser. 1996. Comparative Economics in a
Transforming World Economy. Chicago: Irwin, 1996. Second Edition, Cambridge, MA:
MIT Press, 2004.
Rosser, J. Barkley, Jr. and Roser, Marina V. “Islamic and Neo-Confucian Perspectives on
the New Traditional Economy.” Eastern Economic Journal, Spring 1998, Vol. 24(2), pp.
217-227.
Rosser, J. Barkley, Jr. and Rosser, Marina V. “The New Traditional Economy: A New
Perspective for Comparative Economics?” International Journal of Social Economics,
1999, Vol. 26(6), pp. 763-778.
Rozman, G., Editor. The East Asian Region: Confucian Heritage and Its Modern
Adaptation. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1991.
Rudolph, Lloyd I. and Rudolph, Susanne Hoeber. The Modernity of Tradition: Political
Development in India. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1967.
Sahlins, Marshall D. Stone Age Economics. Chicago: Aldine, 1972.
Siddiqui, Muhammed Nejtullah. “Muslim Economic Thinking: A Survey of
Contemporary Literature,” Ahmad, Kurshid, Editor, Studies in Islamic Economics.
Leicester: Islamic Foundation, 1980, pp. 191-315.
32
Singh, K.S. The Scheduled Castes. Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1993.
Smyser, W.R. The Economy of United Germany: Colossus at the Crossroads. New York:
St. Martin’s Press, 1992.
Spiro, Melford E. Buddhism and Society: A Great Tradition and Its Burmese
Vicissitudes. New York: Harper and Row, 1970.
Stodder, James P. “The Evolution of Complexity in Primitive Exchange: Theory.”
Journal of Comparative Economics, February 1995a, Vol. 20(1), pp. 1-31.
Stodder, James P. “The Evolution of Complexity in Primitive Exchange: Empirical
Tests.” Journal of Comparative Economics, April 1995b, Vol. 20(2), pp. 190-210.
Tamari, Meir.“With All your Possessions”: Jewish Ethics and Economic Life. New York:
The Free Press, 1987.
Tirthankar, Roy. “Economic History and Modern India: Redefining the Link.” Journal of
Economic Perspectives, Summer 2002, Vol. 16(3), pp. 109-130.
Tomlinson, B.R. The New Cambridge History of India, III.3: The Economy of Modern
India, 1860-1970. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1993.
33
United States Catholic Conference. Economic Justice for All: Pastoral Letter on Catholic
Social Teaching and the U.S. Economy. Washington: United States Catholic Conference,
1986.
Upadhyaya, Deendayal. Integral Humanism. Dehli: Navchetan Press, 1965.
Wallis, Jim. “The Powerful and the Powerless,” Neuhaus, Richard J. and Cromartie,
Michael, Editors, Piety and Politics: Evangelicals and Fundamentalists Confront the
World. Washington: Ethics and Public Policy Center, 1987, pp. 189-202.
Zhang, Wei-Bin. Confucianism and Modernization: Industrialization and
Democratization of the Confucian Regions. London: Macmillan, 1999.
Download