globalizing the policy process

advertisement
GLOBALIZING THE POLICY PROCESS:
FROM >IRON TRIANGLES= TO >GOLDEN PENTANGLES=?
by
Philip G. Cerny
Department of Government
University of Manchester
Dover Street
Manchester M13 9PL, United Kingdom
Tel. +44-161-275-4931
Fax +44-161-275-4925
Email: <philip.cerny@man.ac.uk>
Paper presented at the annual convention of the International Studies Association, New Orleans,
24-27 March 2002. An earlier version was published in Global Governance, vol. 7, no. 4
(October-December 2001), pp. 397-410.
ABSTRACT
Despite increasing scholarly attention devoted to globalization, approaches to the public
policy process have continued to focus primarily on the level of the nation-state. This paper
argues that globalization has become sufficiently generalized in structural terms that it must no
longer be treated as exogenous to public policy. This paper aims to >endogenize= international
and transnational actors and processes within a broadened model of the policy process. It
outlines a five-component model of the policy process (>golden pentangles=) which includes
those domestic political structures and actors that have traditionally been treated as endogenous
to so-called >iron triangles= C i.e., politicians, bureaucrats, and interest groups C but also brings
within the model two major categories of actors previously treated as exogenous: (a) public
intergovernmental institutions and bureaucratic processes; and (b) transnational market and
>civil society= actors. It also argues that the interaction of these components has been altered by
the impact of international variables, thereby modifying the agenda, the menu of available
options, and the range of potential outcomes of the policy process. The key intervening variable
concerns how the actors within each category come to perceive their own interests and goals
differently in a more interdependent world. This redefinition leads them increasingly to build
coalitions around policy options that are perceived to liberalize policy processes and adjustment
mechanisms in issue-areas characterized predominantly by non-specific assets while maintaining
a margin of flexibility for making side-payments to distributional coalitions in issue-areas
characterized predominantly by specific assets.
GLOBALIZING THE POLICY PROCESS:
FROM >IRON TRIANGLES= TO >GOLDEN PENTANGLES=?
I.
The Limits of Traditional Approaches to Public Policy
Most academic discussion of the public policy process treats the international and global
levels of analysis as exogenous. This reflects a general tendency in social science to see domestic
political systems as the paramount playing fields where political actors interact and pursue their
goals. This bias is reinforced by the study of International Relations, which generally treats
domestic actors as subsumed into reified states, deemed to be >unit actors=. A >levels of
analysis distinction= is thereby built into the basic analytical frameworks of social science. This
image of policymaking processes as being constituted predominantly through endogenous
variables C the image of the >inside= C is less and less valid. In this process, the >outside= has
dramatically changed too. However, because this evolution has been extremely uneven, it has not
been at all clear how these complex linkages should be treated in policy analysis. Indeed, given
the democratic deficit of >global governance= C and despite the growing institutionalization of
transnational decision-making processes both public and private1 C the analytical predominance
of the inside continues to be underpinned and reinforced by democratic notions of bottom-up
legitimacy, however frayed.2
Today, however, inside and outside taken together form a complex, uneven and
asymmetric set of multilayered cross-cutting processes and nodes of interaction. Different
economic sectors C not just firms or markets, but economic activities producing distinct types of
goods through distinct asset structures C are now organized formally and informally across
borders. Collective goods too must increasingly be provided in a transnational context.3 At the
same time, non-governmental organizations or NGOs C i.e., transnational interest or pressure
groups C have become much more central to processes of change in a range of issue-areas.4
Finally, government agencies and state actors are increasingly drawn into cross-national or
>transgovernmental= policy networks of various kinds, both institutionalized and ad hoc. These
uneven and often quite divergent processes, however, interact with and cut across not only each
other but also traditional domestic processes, creating interaction effects that alter both the way
policy is made and the outcomes of the policymaking process. These effects vary from issue-area
to issue-area, depending on the structural characteristics of each and on the ways key actors in
each attempt to internalize, manipulate, and orchestrate their responses.
In this context, the politics of the policy process cuts across borders as well as domestic
socio-economic categories, becoming less hierarchical and bureaucratic and more and more
market-like and network-like. Whereas statist, neopluralist, and new institutionalist critiques of
pluralism of the 1970s and 1980s sought to re-insert hierarchical structures into American-style
political science,5 today analysts of transnational markets and globalizing civil society are
suggesting a new multilayered multipolarity, on at least three levels:
$
the emergence of a new, more complex, cross-cutting pecking order to socio-economic as
1
$
$
well as political hierarchies;
a transnational rearticulation of social and political coalitions as actors attempt to cope
with and control the consequences of these changes; and
the development of a more complex and fluid governance structure or quasi-institutional
playing field through which these factors interact.
This new playing field reaches down to regional and local levels too. It increasingly
subsumes domestic-level policy processes themselves and incorporates domestic actors into
wider, cross-cutting arenas. This multilayered >web of governance= is linked and articulated
through a complex of public and private processes and institutions; the exemplar is global
finance, rooted in markets and networks.6 More widely, this web undermines state-embedded
hierarchies and overlays them with new kinds of quasi-pluralist groups, interests, and forms of
political behaviour that often do not fit easily into traditional notions of politics in the domestic
arena. These newer forms of politics and politicking C which are of course not totally new as
such but blends of old and new factors C not only enable new political forces to influence the
policymaking process across borders but also generate innovative combinations of old and new
pressures and interests domestically, from the bottom up.
Broadly speaking, debates on the overall character of global politics focus on whether this
state of affairs reflects a new >highest stage of capitalism= based on a transnational class system
or alternatively creates a more open >transnational opportunity structure=, thereby expanding the
potential for genuine pluralism.7 More importantly, however, it creates differential patterns of
politics in which interest groups, political parties, and political entrepreneurs seek use the policy
process in order to benefit from globalizing trends. Different actors face divergent cost-benefit
calculi. At one level, the policy process becomes a terrain of conflict and coalition-building
between those actors and interests that believe they would benefit on the whole from
globalization, on the one hand, and those that believe they would be disadvantaged. But at
another level, globalization (especially globalization as discourse) becomes a bargaining process
among groups that are characterized by different kinds of payoffs.
II.
The First-Order Problem: Endogenizing the Global
The model outlined here is based on two fundamental propositions. The first is that
mainstream approaches to policy analysis are not inherently limited to the domestic arena. Most
are rooted in methodological assumptions and practices that are quite easily translated onto the
international/transnational level. Pluralism, neo-pluralism, democratic elitism, and some forms
of neocorporatism are common to much of the empirical, taxonomic and model-building
literature in public policy. All can be applied in a transnational context. Within International
Relations too, a range of non->realist= approaches, traditional as well as critical, already put
analogous pluralistic or quasi-pluralistic processes of conflict, competition and coalition-building
at the centre of their analyses.
The second proposition is that globalization develops out of complexity and breeds
further complexity, opening up a widening range of international and transnational playing fields
and arenas. There is not just one >end state= of an integrated, globalized world, but rather a
number of distinct trends involving both convergence and divergence, occurring at a number of
levels, across a range of distinctly organized sectors, issue-areas and social processes.8 Of
2
course, these complex trends do not occur in isolation from each other. They generate interaction
effects in both time and space. To point out a key aspect of this interaction process that has often
been misunderstood by analysts, it can be argued that what Paul Hirst and Grahame Thompson
call >inter-nationalization= (with a hyphen C indicating that they are referring to traditional
interstate or intergovernmental relations)9 amongst states is not so much a separate and distinct
process from transnationalization as a different but that the two are inextricably intertwined
processes which, combined with other cross-cutting structures and processes, together produce
the complex outcome called globalization. Indeed, these interaction effects further alter the
distribution of resources across different groups, sectors, issue-areas, etc.; thereby change the
pecking order or distribution of resources and authority in society; and, in turn, reshape the ways
people interact, make sense of, and attempt to manipulate the world through politics and
policymaking.
In this context, the constraints and opportunities actors face are increasingly in flux C
sometimes tightening structural constraints and creating new constraints, sometimes loosening
them and creating new opportunities for actors to expand the scale and scope of their activities,
even at times allowing actors to alter those constraints themselves, whether by design or as a byproduct of other political activities. Whether we are talking about integration of global financial
markets, internationalization of production, or the emergence of intergovernmental institutions
and transnational regimes, both new and transmogrified constraints and opportunities transform
political action in unanticipated ways. These changes can be brought about in a range of different
ways. Trial and error and tit-for-tat approaches often trump both older embedded patterns and
preconceived proactive strategies. Thus globalization should not be seen merely as creating
closure, but as opening up a wider and more asymmetric transnational opportunity structure.
III.
The Accumulation of Counter-Paradigmatic Findings
Various studies have attempted to cross these boundaries in specific issue-areas,
potentially creating a small Kuhnian revolution.10 One area concerns European public policy,
which focuses on the development of an intermediate institutionalized playing field, the
European Union, and the system of >multi-level governance= it has spawned.11 Another area
involves >epistemic communities= or transnational policy networks, focusing mainly on issueareas where high-level knowledge is a crucial element C e.g., environmental protection (where
scientists, informed intellectuals, and NGOs play a key part), the role of >think tanks,= studies of
the internet and other aspects of technological interpenetration, >policy transfer= (where key
elites copy policy techniques seen in other countries), and the like.12 Furthermore, the study of
>transnational advocacy networks= and other interest and pressure groups capable of a kind of
>variable geometry= in seeking out points of access at a variety of levels has grown rapidly,
reflecting the flexibilization of interest group politics in a globalizing world.13 Perhaps most
salient is the development of International Political Economy in general in issue-areas like trade,
production, money, financial services, central banking, immigration, some aspects of
macroeconomic policy, and the like. None of these specialized fields of study, however, has yet
led to the development of an overall analytical framework for the policy process.
Probably the most robust (if often criticized as limited) concept in the policy literature is
that of iron triangles. These lie at the heart of wider and more complex notions of issue
networks, policy networks, policy communities, and the like.14 Iron triangles are not
3
unproblematic. As Anthony King has written: >Within the federal government in Washington,
the old Airon triangles@ ... have given way to much more amorphous issue networks, to the
description of which a simple Euclidian geometry is no longer appropriate.=15 Nevertheless, the
image they convey is still much clearer than those of the wider if still domestically rooted
frameworks they spawned. The notion that relatively narrow coalitions of actors, both in and out
of governments, linked around specific issues and distributions of resources, and brought
together by regularized professional (and often personal) contacts, would settle many ongoing
and outstanding issues (especially routine issues) and negotiate potential conflicts through
bargaining amongst themselves is a common sense one.
In iron triangles, the policy process consists mainly of three broad categories of actors:
(4)
relevant elected officeholders C members of legislatures, party officials, ministers in
parliamentary governments, etc., as well as those in key lower-level institutions such as
American states, provincial governments and the like C whose policymaking
responsibilities and clout in terms of resource allocation are concentrated in specific
issue-areas (e.g., membership of congressional or parliamentary committees);
(5)
bureaucrats employed in agencies that regulate, control resources for, propose and
implement policy towards, or otherwise deal with those same issue-areas; and
(6)
non-officeholding actors, mainly in the business and voluntary sectors (and those that cut
across the public/private divide), who have (a) particular objectives they wish to pursue
with regard to those same issue-areas, whether as unorganized interests or as organized
groups, and (b) some combination of relevant mobilizable resources, including
specialized knowledge, direct economic interest, elite network contacts, financial and
other material resources, a popular or group base, ideological affinity, etc., which can
enable them to influence government policy through their regularized interactions with
(1) and (2).
Of course, actors in each of these categories are conceived as operating first and foremost within
a national playing field. There are several reasons for this.
In the first place, politicians in liberal democratic systems are widely seen to be primarily
concerned with staying in office and managing sufficient institutional and material resources and
prestige to gain not only regular re-election but also promotion on the basis of existing career
ladders within institutions like legislatures and executives as well as hierarchies of elected
offices. Their priorities, even if dealing with transnational issues, are to play to their colleagues
and electors. Secondly, bureaucrats are seen to be concerned primarily with expanding the scope
and scale of their empires (turf, prestige, and pay), as well as rising in the bureaucratic hierarchy;
at the same time, they want a >quiet life= and not to be continually conflicting with politicians,
private sector actors, or their colleagues in other agencies. And finally, relevant nongovernmental actors C whether those with direct material interests in the outcomes of particular
policy processes (from individuals or firms to highly organized special interest groups) or other
sorts of pressure groups (whether pursuing sectional interests or causes), or even informally
linked groups of electors with connections to the issue-areas in question C are seen to be
concerned primarily with maximizing outputs from the governmental system. Of the four main
4
types of public policy C regulatory, productive, distributive, and redistributive16 C national
governments are still the main providers of immediate material outputs.
Nevertheless, these actor categories are particularly useful to our model. Indeed, two of
them can be directly translated. The main exception concerns elected political officeholders; it is
highly problematic to extrapolate their roles onto the global or transnational plane. In liberal
democratic systems, such officeholders will always see themselves first and foremost as beholden
to domestic voters and interests or as embodying the state in international affairs. Even when
operating on an international or quasi-diplomatic plane and attempting to find cooperative ways
to tackle international and global issues, they will fiercely avoid acting in ways which might be
seen by their domestic constituencies as contrary to national interests or, indeed, to the interests
of key groups of voters or special interest groups that put them into office. Of course, this
incentive structure can shift significantly where elected officeholders C especially legislative
officeholders C must deal on a regular basis with transnationally cross-cutting interests and/or
transgovernmentally linked bureaucrats; in such cases, however, their actions can be seen as
predominantly dependent variables. Normally their international and transnational roles are
highly circumscribed by their embedded state locations, whether as domestic policy players or
traditional foreign policy actors.
In contrast, however, domestically appointed bureaucratic actors are frequently in a
position relative to their agencies= concerns and to the interests of their main sectoral
constituencies C particularly with regard both to transnationally linked economic interests and to
advocacy coalitions (cause groups) C that they will internalize vital international and
transnational dimensions into their evaluation of a range of policy issues and potential solutions.
Furthermore, they also become enmeshed in transgovernmental networks around specific issueareas. This is particularly true where they are part of a bureaucratic hierarchy C for example, an
independent central bank or a securities regulator C relatively insulated from direct political
pressures, or where a relevant and relatively autonomous domestic policy network or epistemic
community exists to support transnationally innovative approaches. Finally, increasing linkages
at private sector and NGO levels continually draw interest group and advocacy coalition actors
into the international and transnational arenas, often interacting with both domestic and
international or transnational bureaucratic actors on a regularized basis. The iron triangles of the
past are being overlaid, supplemented and even replaced by golden pentangles.
However, while the image of iron triangles symbolically represents giant Second
Industrial Revolution steel industries with their national markets and close corporatist
relationships with the state (and often with trade unions), that of golden pentangles evokes global
financial markets and international financial institutions. The growth of international capital
flows, cross-border price sensitivity, and related technological developments have driven
economic globalization and shaped policy responses along more market-oriented lines, leading to
the emergence of an embedded financial orthodoxy in public policymaking.17 Golden pentangles
represent in highly stylized fashion a five-sided policy process analogous to the three-sided iron
triangles. The first three sides of the former consist of the same three categories represented in
iron triangles: politicians, bureaucrats, and interests, broadened by the endogenization of
international and transnational actors and cross-cutting structural factors.
This image is apt. The abstract, non-specific character of financial markets C the
5
fungibility of money across economic sectors and socio-economic categories as well as its
increasingly dematerialized, electronic infrastructure C creates structural pressures for actors to
accept the rules of the game and conform to the imperatives of embedded financial orthodoxy.
Their global scope and their ability to bypass and constrain state actors create pressure for
liberalizing and marketizing a whole range of sectors beyond the financial sector per se. Thus the
fourth of our five sides or actor categories involves those more formalized or highly
institutionalized public or quasi-public activities undertaken by the International Monetary Fund,
the World Bank, the World Trade Organization, the Bank for International Settlements, the
International Organization of Securities Commissions, the G7, the G20, and many more. Finally,
the fifth category is made up of the universe of interlocking >webs of governance= constituted by
mixed public/private sector quasi-institutions (markets in the active sense) and non-state actors.
As with interest groups or pressure groups in the traditional pluralist literature of American
political sociology, increasing weight in a globalizing world must be accorded to cross-border
non-governmental structures and actors, from transnational markets to civil society.
IV.
How the Policy Process is Changing
Although such inside/outside linkages have existed since time immemorial,18 the pace,
density and complexity of change today are unprecedented. Furthermore, globalization is not
merely an economic process but a political process. It involves building coalitions and
developing institutional strategies for coping with and controlling the globalization process
around criteria such as justice, fairness, and the effective provision of public goods.19 Such
developments are intermediated through a range of salient issue-areas which present unfamiliar
challenges and opportunities, as well as creating new constraints, for policy actors. These issueareas run the gamut of different types of public policy, both domestic and international,
traditional and emerging, as indicated in this brief provisional list.
$
Foreign economic policy is perhaps the most obvious area where a range of cooperative
intergovernmental practices, institution-building processes, transgovernmental networks,
and transnationally linked sectional interest groups have led to new arrangements
practices on a trial-and-error, often ad hoc, basis. These new arrangements have been
seen as necessary in order to cope with and promote such innovative policy trends as
trade liberalization, financial deregulation and harmonization, energy policy,
environmental policy, aid policy, and the like. National economic interests are
increasingly impossible to disentangle from the interdependencies of the contemporary
world. It must also be emphasized that many aspects of security policy too have been
impacted by globalization, leading to a >New Security Dilemma.=20
$
Macroeconomic policy is also increasingly intertwined with international and
transnational processes. Fiscal, interest rate setting, money supply control, and other
measures to >fine-tune= the domestic economy must increasingly be adjusted in ways
which take into account the interests of transnationally linked producers, investors,
consumers, and the like, as well as international economic institutions and other
governments.
$
Domestic regulatory policy, especially deregulation and other forms of market-friendly
regulatory reform, is conceived and implemented today not merely through domestic
6
policy processes but increasingly through transgovernmental networks, institutions and
informal governance processes. Sometimes government officials take the lead in
marketizing regulatory regimes in order to benefit from greater international openness,
and sometimes they are pushed and pulled towards change by the rapid growth of
international capital mobility, cross-border price sensitivity, and various forms of
arbitrage, both economic political, engaged in by private sector actors across a range of
relevant issues, most notably financial liberalization.
$
Patterns of microeconomic and mesoeconomic policymaking are also changing in
response to global marketizing pressures. Political actors and governments no longer
stress taking whole issue-areas out of the market (>decommodification=), as they once
did in the past with regard not only to the welfare state but also to the promotion of
particular industrial sectors, the pursuit of domestic self-sufficiency in sectors like energy,
the subsidized provision of >patient capital=, etc. Declining sectors are increasingly
allowed to run down rather than be protected, and welfare and other public services
increasingly are meant to work according to quasi-market principles C the >new public
management= or >reinventing government=. Winners are no longer directly >picked=
through traditional forms of industrial policy; rather, governments prioritize the creation
of a market-friendly and competitive regulatory environment applicable to all firms rather
than a selected few. Although domestic political conditions still retain a range of options
for >domesticating= globalization, those options are both narrower and in some issueareas quite different from earlier periods. Social democracy, for example, is increasingly
challenged to find alternatives to traditional options of state-led policies of redistribution
and public service provision without sacrificing its traditional goals of social justice.21
$
Moreover, key patterns of coalition-building are changing. Political actors are led more
and more to adopt approaches that prioritize capturing the benefits of globalization.22
This potentially allows the creation of new material and political resources for rebuilding
decaying bases of support and attracting new constituencies, mass as well as elite, in a
period of shifting identities, allegiances, and class structures in a globalizing world.
Conservative coalitions pioneered this form of realignment in advanced industrial
countries in the 1970s and 1980s, through Thatcherism and Reaganism in particular,
while on the center-left, the notion of the >Third Way= that has been adopted in the
1990s by the New Democrats in the U.S., >New Labour= in the United Kingdom, and the
Social Democrats= >Neue Mitte= in Germany, is explicitly conceived as a response to
globalization.
V.
How the Policy Process Works in a Globalizing World
Just as with iron triangles, some issue-areas will be dominated by only a subset of the
basic actor categories. Rarely will an issue-area be characterized by an ideal-type, balanced fivenode policy process as such. A number of more specific hypotheses can be suggested in this
regard.
(1)
With regard to foreign economic policy, for example, traditional foreign policy actors
(diplomats and foreign ministry officials, members of national executive branches and
their advisors, etc.) and those involved in intergovernmental processes are likely to
7
benefit from their positions in the domestic state hierarchy to exercise disproportionate
influence. Furthermore, such actors are more likely to be able to resist pressures from
some kinds of domestic interests and see their primary role in a traditional, somewhat
insulated diplomatic context; they still often resemble the category of >cosmopolitan
elites.=23
(2)
With regard to macroeconomic policymaking, economic experts, central banks, treasury
departments, and actors closely connected with particular phases of the legislative process
and legislative-executive bargaining, such as members of budget or banking committees
in the United States, will benefit from similar advantages; they are increasingly likely to
see their roles, however, as an attempt to lead or to respond to international market
conditions, privileging such criteria as market confidence and stabilization.
(3)
With regard to regulatory policy, close links between particular regulatory bodies with
transgovernmental links, specialized private sector interests often with transnational links,
elected officials with particular expertise in such fields, and international institutions will
form a complex system of ongoing bargaining and reform, especially with regard to socalled >regulatory arbitrage= between different national regulatory systems.
(4)
In microeconomic policy, domestic economic interests, especially producer and consumer
interests, have a much greater role to play. However, increasing interpenetration of
transnational markets for a widening range of goods and assets can dramatically alter the
perceptions of such actors and lead to a partial internationalization from below along with
demands for compensation for losers.
(5)
And finally, coalition-building strategies are likely to involve a much wider range of
latent and manifest groups. While class, regional, sectional, and other patterns of voting
and interest group behavior still exist, they are increasingly cross-cut and rearticulated
into competing >associations of consumers= in that even more >multinucleated= political
system that is created in the process of globalization.24
Therefore a number of different networking patterns or subsets C dyads, triads, quads, or
even full-blown pentangles C are likely to develop within different issue-areas, although the
development of a full-blown theory of how this will happen is premature. The literature is likely
to be built from the bottom up as empirical case studies are carried out and compared.
Nevertheless, the substantive content of the policy process in different issue-areas is likely to vary
in relatively systematic ways. In particular, adapting the framework applied to demands for
protectionism developed Jeffrey Frieden and Ronald Rogowski, it can be hypothesized that the
relative concentration and diffusion of costs and benefits for different groups of actors in
constrasting issue areas will lead to substantively different outcomes.25 Patterns of action are
likely to vary substantially, as Eric Helleiner, for example, has shown in his contrast between the
politics of trade and that of finance. Trade openness depends on multilateral action, over which
state actors and domestic interests may have a veto, whereas financial openness can effectively be
pursued unilaterally by state actors responding to market developments.26
Perhaps the most obvious distinction shaping the content of the process is that between
those groups and actors who represent or are otherwise linked with economic sectors
8
characterized predominantly by non-specific assets on the one hand and those characterized by
specific assets on the other.27 In the first case, where the assets of a sector can easily be
transferred from one use to another, where sufficient market liquidity exists for those assets to be
bought or sold in a market, and where a reliable market price for those assets can be established
among a reasonably large range of buyers and sellers (non-specific assets), interest groups and
those political entrepreneurs more closely linked with such sectors will be likely to support
policy measures and policymaking institutions that liberalize market structures, maximize crossborder market opportunities, and/or promote competitive advantages in those fields. Finance and
tradable goods are key examples. On the other hand, where assets cannot easily be transferred
and liquid markets and reliable market prices are problematic, groups and political entrepreneurs
will either oppose liberalizing measures outright, usually by demanding various forms of
protectionism, or demand compensation for their loss of structural clout by demanding tax breaks
and benefits, adjustment assistance, and/or other side-payments.
In this context, our main hypothesis is that the endogenization of international and
transnational elements into the policy process is likely over time (a) to further privilege those
sectors and actors in the former (non-specific asset) category in terms of agenda-setting,
bargaining, and obtaining preferred policy outcomes and (b) to force those in the latter (specific
asset) category to adopt strategies that are based less and less on protectionism and more and
more on side-payments. In both cases, the center of gravity of the policymaking process in terms
of setting the policy agenda, the payoff matrix for the bargaining process itself, and the range of
feasible outcomes is shifted towards conditions that are broadly liberalizing or globalizing, in a
feedback process that reinforces transnationally intertwined interests and actors and progressively
marginalizes what used to be called >national capital=.
Indeed, the proportion of economic sectors and activities that is characterized by nonspecific asset structures is growing, for two reasons. The first is that even large-scale
manufacturing industries find it more difficult to establish and maintain monopolies, oligopolies,
formal or informal cartels, etc., at international and transnational levels than at national or local
levels. The world economy is too big for even the biggest economies of scale to lead to market
dominance. I am aware of only one large-scale industry which is characterized by growing
international oligopolization to any great extent, the commercial aircraft industry, although even
here the evidence is ambiguous and governments (including the European Union) have been
assiduous in attempting to impose compensatory regulation. Generally speaking, globalization
promotes increased competitiveness in most sectors. The second is that many industries are in
the process of restructuring in order to reflect technological changes that make them more flexible
in terms of production processes, management and organizational systems, marketing, the use of
new information and communications technology, etc. C what is often called the >Third
Industrial Revolution= or >post-Fordism=. Flexible structures are by definition more
marketizable and therefore structurally non-specific. The shift of the steel industry everywhere
from large-scale plants (often now called >Rust Belts=) to mini-mills is typical, despite the fact
that governments often have to pander politically to older large-scale firms for electoral reasons.
In this changing structural context, globalization changes the cost-benefit calculus away
from the promotion of domestic self-sufficiency or insulation toward adjustment mechanisms that
integrate or endogenize internationalized and transnationalized agendas, bargaining situations,
and policy outcomes. The capacity to form protectionist or quasi-protectionist coalitions is
9
thereby increasingly circumscribed as fewer actors C and fewer economically heavyweight and/or
politically significant actors C have a direct economic or political interest in such policy
measures. Broadly speaking, then, globalization increasingly compels actors to seek liberal
solutions because only by accepting such solutions is it possible to form sufficiently large
coalitions to gain tolerable compensatory benefits from the policy process in the medium-to-long
term.
Nevertheless, there are important exceptions to this general rule, three of which are
particularly salient at the time of writing. The first involves exogenous shocks where previously
negotiated policy and/or institutional outcomes prove to be counterproductive and the pressure of
unfavorable events shifts the underlying pattern of coalition-building away from what was
previously agreed either into a reshaped bargaining process or toward the limbo of an empty core
among former coalition partners. An example of these (mainly the latter, so far) is the collapse of
Argentina=s peso/dollar convertibility policy (also known as the >currency board=) in 2001-02 C
a laboriously won settlement that after five years of relative success has since the mid-1990s
unwound dramatically. The second involves negative reactions to particular liberalizing
measures on the part of >concentrated= domestic interests, i.e. those groups and actors that are
able to mobilize a well-defined sector of the electorate in particular geographical regions and
social categories where elections are tight and can be swung by political action. An example of
this is the Bush Administration=s agreement to impose tariffs on several categories of steel
imports, especially from Europe and Japan, in March 2002. The third, in this case only a partial
(and at first glance paradoxical) exception, is the spread C and often the transnational transfer C
of tighter and stricter, rather than looser and apparently more >liberal=, policy measures, such as
increasingly strong environmental regulations, health and safety regulations, and financial
regulatory reforms. An example of the last, still in the making, is the current pressure to tighten
up on auditing and accounting standards in the wake of the bankruptcy of the Enron Corporation
in late 2001. But this last exception may be the exception that proves the rule, as it is the
transnational transfer of such regulatory measures that is turning the competition state into the
regulatory state.28
Globalizing the policy process, therefore, although it is likely to lead to more liberal
outcomes over time C given the altered balance of interests, groups, actors, etc., involved in that
process C is unlikely to lead to a disarming of the state. Rather it is leading to a reallocation of
state resources and authority away from insulated domestic agendas toward policy measures that
promote coalitions among:
(1)
actual cross-border interests, usually economic but also social and political;
(2)
those domestic interests that are not merely vulnerable to international and transnational
conditions but also seeking to benefit from wider competitiveness; and
(3)
domestic interests seeking compensatory side-payments.
In this context, furthermore, two additional trends can be identified. The first is the
attempt (or strategic decision?) on the part of a growing number of political entrepreneurs
whether on the Right or on the Left to focus on facilitating such bargaining processes. Domestic
populist politics are increasingly seen as marginal and unproductive, while the discourse of
political >modernisation= is increasingly hegemonic. The second is the apparent emergence of
an awareness in a number of countries, and perhaps in the IMF, the World Bank and the WTO as
well, that political bargains entered into in this context have a wider political or ideational
10
dimension. If the kind of shift of policy agendas, bargaining processes, and policy outcomes
discussed here are to be seen as legitimate in the future, they will increasingly be presented as
representing wider liberal social and political values C and not merely >neoliberal= economic
solutions (in the European sense). Margaret Thatcher=s saying that >You can=t buck the
markets= is being challenged within the political mainstream not by the recreation of the mid20th century industrial welfare state, the state of the iron triangles, but by the notion of
>globalization with a human face= (Bill Clinton), the official promotion of poverty reduction
approaches by the World Bank, or the need for a >global safety net=. Indeed, even outside that
mainstream, today=s anti-globalization protesters are increasingly aware that the nation-state no
longer constitutes an effective arena for protest and that opposition to economic globalization
itself requires the globalization of protest from below.29
Finally, in terms of the inclusiveness or exclusiveness of the policy process in
transnationally-linked issue-areas, mass-based or voter-oriented groups would at first glance seem
less likely to participate proactively than in traditional domestic policy processes. However, this
rule of thumb falls away when the issue-area concerned becomes clearly perceived in popular
consciousness as being inherently or structurally international, transnational, or global. Thus
environmental protection increasingly involves mass input, mobilized through transnational
pressure groups like Greenpeace; nevertheless, epistemic communities in this issue-area have
managed to keep their central role through their specialized scientific expertise. Trade as an
issue-area is increasingly mobilizing mass groups in the wake of the Battle of Seattle, although
results are limited and mainly symbolic at this stage.
Conclusions
At the core of the model, then, is an apparent paradox. For the most part, the addition of
our two additional categories of actors to the golden pentangle model tends to give an even larger
agenda-setting role to elite groups, because they are more likely to be transnationally linked, than
is the case for the iron triangle model. The >democratic deficit=, the growing weakness of
organized labor, constraints on the welfare state, and the like, seem to give increasing structural
and relational power to the more mobile sectors of international capital, especially in the financial
sector. At the same time, however, expansion of the number of relevant categories of actors also
increases the possibilities for competition among various groups at different levels and makes it
less possible for a closed or monolithic national state C or even some sort of emerging >global
state=30 C to result. The process is more neo-pluralist than either fully pluralist or elitist.
Thus the globalization of public policy is a complex process. At one level it creates new
playing fields for a wider range of groups to participate. At another level, however, it is also a
process characterized by a specific set of constraints and opportunites, especially those stemming
from the distinction between non-specific and specific asset structures. Nevertheless,
globalization of the policy process involves the continual and growing interaction of both old and
new elements of the political opportunity structure, giving political entrepreneurs considerable
scope to shape that evolution. Finally, it strengthens the hand of internationally linked interests
and actors and shifts the balance of agenda-setting, policy bargaining, and policy outcomes
towards globalizing coalitions and proto-coalitions. The impact of globalization on the policy
process is already both extensive and substantial and is not likely to diminish.
11
NOTES
1
.
Aseem Prakash and Jeffrey A. Hart, eds., Globalization and Governance (London:
Routledge, 1999; Karsten Ronit and Volker Schneider, eds., Private Organizations in
Global Politics (London: Routledge, 2000).
2
.
P.G. Cerny, >Globalization and the Erosion of Democracy,= European Journal of
Political Research, vol. 26, no. 1 (August 1999), pp. 1-26.
3
.
P.G. Cerny, >Globalization and the Changing Logic of Collective Action,= International
Organization, vol. 49, no. 4 (Autumn 1995), pp. 595-626.
4
.
Mustapha Kamal Pasha and David L. Blaney, >Elusive Paradise: The Promise and Peril
of Global Civil Society,= Alternatives, vol. 23, no. 3 (Summer 1998), pp. 417-450. P.G.
Cerny, >Political Agency in a Globalizing World: Toward a Structurational Approach,=
European Journal of International Relations, vol. 6, no. 4 (December 2000), pp. 147-162.
5
.
E.g., Theda Skocpol, States and Social Revolutions (Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 1979); Charles E. Lindblom, Politics and Markets: The World=s PoliticalEconomic Systems (New York: Basic Books, 1977); Peter A. Hall, Governing the
Economy: The Politics of State Intervention in Britain and France (New York and
Cambridge: Oxford University Press and Polity Press, 1986).
6
.
P.G. Cerny, >Webs of Governance and the Privatization of Transnational Regulation,= in
David G. Andrews, C. Randall Henning, and Louis W. Pauly, eds., Organizing the
World=s Money: Essays in Honor of Benjamin J. Cohen (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University
Press, forthcoming 2002).
7
.
Sidney Tarrow, >Transnational Politics: Contention and Institutions in International
Politics=, Annual Review of Political Science (forthcoming); Cerny, >Political Agency=,
op. cit.
8
.
Axel Hülsemeyer, ed., Globalization: Convergence and Divergence (London and New
York: Palgrave, forthcoming 2003).
9
.
Paul Hirst and Grahame Thompson, Globalization in Question: The International
Economy and the Possibilities of Governance (Cambridge: Polity Press, 2nd edition 1999).
10
.
Thomas Kuhn, The Structure of Scientific Revolutions (Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, 1862).
11
.
Gary Marks, Liesbet Hooghe, and Kermit Blank, >European Integration from the 1980s:
State-Centric v. Multi-level Governance,= Journal of Common Market Studies, vol. 34,
12
no. 3 (September 1996), pp. 341-378.
12
.
Peter M. Haas, >Introduction: Epistemic Communities and International Policy
Coordination,= International Organization, vol. 46, no. 1 (Winter 1992), pp. 1-35; Diane
Stone, Capturing the Political Imagination: Think Tanks in the Policy Process (London:
Frank Cass, 1996); Raymund Wehrle and Volker Leib, >The Internet Society and Its
Struggle for Recognition and Influence=, in Ronit and Schneider, op. cit., pp. 102-123;
Mark Evans and Jonathan Davies, >Understanding Policy Transfer: A Multi-Level,
Multi-Disciplinary Perspective=, Public Administration, vol. 77, no. 2 (Summer 1999),
pp. 361-385.
13
.
Pasha and Blaney, op. cit.; Tarrow, op. cit.; Margaret E. Keck and Kathryn Sikkink,
Activists Beyond Borders: Advocacy Networks in International Politics (Ithaca, NY:
Cornell University Press, 1998).
14
.
Hugh Heclo, >Issue Networks and the Executive Establishment=, in Anthony King, ed.,
The New American Political System (Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute,
1978), pp. 87-124.
15
.
Anthony King, >The American Polity in the Late 1970s: Building Coalitions in the
Sand=, in King, ed., The New American Political System, p. 391.
16
.
P.G. Cerny, >Globalization, Governance, and Complexity,=, in Prakash and Hart, eds.,
Globalization and Governance, op. cit., 188-212 (expanding on categories developed by
Theodore Lowi).
17
.
P.G. Cerny, >The Dynamics of Financial Globalization: Technology, Market Structure,
and Policy Response,= Policy Sciences, 27:4 (November 1994), 319-342.
18
.
See, for example, Kenneth Pomerantz and Steven Topik, The World That Trade Created:
Society, Culture, and the World Economy, 1400 to the Present (Armonk, NY, and
London: M.E. Sharpe, 1999).
19
.
P.G. Cerny, >Globalizing the Political and Politicizing the Global: Reflections on
International Political Economy as a Vocation,= New Political Economy, vol. 4, no. 1
(January 1999), pp. 147-162; Cerny, >Reconstructing the Political in a Globalizing
World: States, Institutions, Actors and Governance=, in Frans Buelens, ed., Globalization
and the Nation-State (Cheltenham, Glos.: Edward Elgar, 1999), pp. 89-137; Theodore J.
Lowi, >Our Millennium: Political Science Confronts the Global Corporate Economy,=
International Political Science Review, 22:2 (April 2001), 131-150.
20
.
P.G. Cerny, >The New Security Dilemma: Divisibility, Defection, and Disorder in the
Global Era,= Review of International Studies, vol. 26, no. 4 (October 2000), pp. 623-646.
21
.
Will Hutton and Anthony Giddens, eds., On the Edge: Living With Global Capitalism
(London: Jonathan Cape, 2000); Roy Hattersley, >Campaign for Real Labour is On,= The
13
Observer (London), 8 July 2001; P.G. Cerny, The Changing Architecture of Politics:
Structure, Agency, and the Future of the State (London: Sage, 1990), 242-246.
22
.
I am indebted to Michael Shalev for this phrase.
23
.
James N. Rosenau, National Leadership and Foreign Policy: A Case Study in the
Mobilization of Public Support (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1963).
24
.
The concept of >publics= as >associations of consumers= draws from a strand of public
choice literature originally developed in the context of urban politics by scholars such as
Elinor and Vincent Ostrom; see the discussion in P.G. Cerny, >Globalization,
Governance, and Complexity,= op. cit.
25
.
Jeffrey Frieden and Ronald Rogowski, >The Impact of the International Economy on
National Policies: An Overview=, in Robert O. Keohane and Helen V. Milner, eds.,
Internationalization and Domestic Politics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
1996), pp. 25-47.
26
.
Eric N. Helleiner, States and the Re-emergence of Global Finance (Ithaca, NY: Cornell
University Press, 1994).
27
.
Jeffry A. Frieden, >Invested Interests: The Politics of National Economic Policies in a
World of Global Finance=, International Organization, vol. 45, no. 4 (Autumn 1991), pp.
425-52; P.G. Cerny, >Globalization and the Changing Logic of Collective Action,= op.
cit,; Frieden and Rogowski, >The Impact of the International Economy on National
Policies: An Overview=, op. cit. Non-specific and specific assets are categories
developed by Oliver E. Williamson in Markets and Hierarchies (New York: Free Press,
1975) and The Economic Institutions of Capitalism (New York: Free Press,1985).
28
.
Cf. P.G. Cerny, >Restructuring the Political Arena: Globalization and the Paradoxes of
the Competition State=, in Randall D. Germain, ed., Globalization and Its Critics:
Perspectives from Political Economy (London: Macmillan, 2000), pp. 117-138 Michael
Moran, >Understanding the Regulatory State=, British Journal of Politics and
International Relations, vol. 4, no. 1 (forthcoming April 2002); Evans and Davies,
>Understanding Policy Transfer=, op. cit.
29
.
Amory Starr, Naming the Enemy: Anti-Corporate Movements Confront Globalization
(London, New York, and Australia: Pluto Press and Zed Books, 2000), especially Chapter
3; Flora Lewis, >The Anti-Globalization Spoilers Are Going Global,= International
Herald Tribune, 6 July 2001.
30
.
Martin Shaw, Theory of the Global State (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
2001).
14
Download