Appendix 7 - Getting to Zero

advertisement
Mon Jul 08, 2013 at 04:30 AM PDT
GETTING TO ZERO: Is renewable energy economically viable?
by Keith Pickering
This diary is Part II of GETTING TO ZERO: Our non-fossil energy future.
Human civilization depends on food, food depends on weather, and weather
depends on climate. Every grain and every mammal on the face of the earth –
almost everything we eat – evolved under a different climate than the one we're
heading toward. We are running toward a cliff, and merely walking toward that
cliff isn't a viable strategy. We need to stop. Right now.
If civilization is to survive, we need to get to zero emission of fossil carbon, and
we need to get there rapidly. Every ton of carbon we emit stays in the air for
centuries, and will continue to warm the planet for centuries.
In this series GETTING TO ZERO we will take a very hard-headed look at current
energy policy and energy strategies. We will ask hard questions: does this really
get us to zero? How much would it cost? How rapidly can it be deployed? We may
find some answers along the way, but don't expect them to be easy.
Part 2: Is renewable energy economically viable?
An important new study in the journal Energy (Weißbach et. al. 2013,
paywalled) focuses on energy return on investment (EROI, or sometimes
ERoEI), which is the ratio of electrical energy produced by a given power source
to the amount of energy needed to build, fuel, maintain and decomission that
power plant. Here is one of the main results from the paper (higher numbers are
economically better):
1
PV=photovoltaic; E-66 is the Enercon 1.5 MW wind turbine model studied;
CSP=Concentrated Solar Power (Sahara site assumed); CCGT=Combined cycle
gas turbine; PWR=pressurized water reactor.
In this study, "unbuffered" is the raw generation without storage, while "buffered"
includes the cost of pumped hydro storage where it is needed to buffer the
difference in peaks between production and consumption (assuming, rather
optimistically, that the geography is available for any amount of such storage
facilities). Fueled energy sources already store energy in the fuel, so no additional
buffering is needed there. The hydropower system analyzed is a run-of-river type
(i.e., no dam or reservoir), which has a very favorable EROI, but would require
buffering at some times of the year if deployed en masse.
A couple of important points: first, these are energy costs and outputs, not
monetary costs, which can be entirely different. These numbers represent
technological ability only. Second, every source shown here has an EROI greater
than 1, which is break-even. In other words, each of these generates more
energy during its lifetime that the energy used to make and maintain it. That's
good. But note the gray area at the bottom labeled as the economic threshold. To
understand how this is arrived at, we need to take a major digression.
First we need to understand that not all energy is created equal. Electrical energy
is very useful, because it can immediately do work. Heat and chemical energy are
less useful because it's harder to get work out of them. This introduces an
important concept: exergy, which is available energy, or energy usable for work.
In general a large heat-type power plant (coal, gas, or nuclear) will require 3
joules of heat energy to create 1 joule of electrical energy. Therefore it is
common to weight electricity by a factor of 3 when computing the exergy of a
system. (Note also that unlike energy, exergy can be created and destroyed.)
So instead of computing the raw EROI, as in the graph above, it can be more
useful to consider the exergy equivalent, by weighting both the energy inputs and
energy output by a factor of 3 when the energy type is electrical. Weißbach
(pronounced "vise-bach") calls this EMROI, and the results are shown below.
2
Since all these sources produce high-weight electricity as output, but not all
energy inputs are electric, the EMROI of all sources is higher than their EROI.
What we've done here is taken one step toward monetizing the EROI, by allowing
for the greater monetary value of electricity compared to other energy types.
(This gives us Energy Money Return On Investment, EMROI). A fully monetized
ROI would include non-energy inputs like labor and capital, which can be very
large. That means a fully monetized ROI will always be smaller than EMROI. In
effect, EMROI is a theoretical "best case" scenario for monetary ROI.
But note that the economic threshold has increased in EMROI too. Here's how
those thresholds are computed:
... an EROI threshold can be roughly estimated by the ratio of the GDP to the
unweighted final energy consumption while an EMROI threshold can be estimated
by the weighted final energy consumption (which is not the primary energy
consumption). For the U.S., for instance, the GDP was $15 trillion in 2011 while
the unweighted end energy consumption was about 20 trillion kWh, resulting in
an “energy value” of some 70 cent/kWh (Germany ~135 cent/kWh). The average
electricity price, however, is 10 cent/kWh [10], (Germany ~18 cent/kWh) so
there is a factor of 7 higher money to energy ratio on the input side. The same
calculation for the weighted final energy consumption (the electricity demand was
multiplied by a factor of about 3) results in a ratio of about 16 for both countries,
assuming average primary energy costs of 5 cent/kWh and 3.5 cent/kWh for
Germany and the USA, respectively. A similar ratio can be seen for other
countries which leads to the conclusion that the thresholds are 7 and 16 for the
EROI and the EMROI, respectively, assuming OECD-like energy consuming
technology. For lower developed countries thresholds might be smaller, thus
making also “simple” energies like biomass economic.
Here's the idea in a nutshell: in the US, a kWh of energy (unweighted) costs
about 10 cents but it produces about 70 cents worth of GDP, a ratio of 7 to 1.
(Note the switch: we're talking money now, not joules.) If we do the same
computation in exergy terms, the ratio is 16 to 1. That means the fully monetary
3
ROI of exergy, for the economy as a whole, is 16. But remember that if we have
an exergy source whose EMROI is less than 16, its fully monetary ROI must be
less than that -- which means that deploying such a source on a large scale will
reduce GDP. The economy becomes less efficient as we deploy less efficient
energy sources to run it. As we spend more of our time and effort making exergy,
we will spend less making all the other stuff we need and GDP goes down. The
flip side of this is that as the price of electricity goes up and GDP goes down, the
economic threshold decreases: more marginal energy sources will become
profitable.
Solar PV and biomass both fall below the current threshold, and wind would
too, if we deploy it widely enough to require storage buffering. Concentrated
solar thermal beats the threshold (at least in the Sahara desert case, and
presumably the southwestern US would be comparable.) There are limited areas
in which it could be deployed, but it makes sense to do so.
Wind is a tricky case. If you ask most people, they will tell you that we don't
currently have energy storage for wind. In fact we do, but the buffering for wind
comes from natural gas powerplants, which are typically built at the same time
wind is deployed. When the wind dies, the backup gas plants are turned on, to
keep the grid power reliable. Thus the energy storage for wind is embodied in the
natural gas that isn't burned when the wind turbine is producing peak output.
This means that wind, as it's used now in the US, isn't really zero-fossil. It's a
hybrid system that's part wind, part natural gas. And considering the availability
of wind (30% is typical for a wind turbine), most of the energy actually comes
from the fossil side of the equation. We're using the wind to offset some of the
CO2 emissions from the gas plant (which is good), but instead of getting to zero,
we're just walking toward the cliff instead of running toward it.
Denmark currently is one of the most wind-energy-intensive countries in the
world, which works because they buffer their wind energy against hydroelectric
power from Norway and Sweden. When the wind is blowing in Denmark, they
export electricity to Sweden, which then can turn down its hydro plants (thus
keeping more water stored in the reservoirs behind the dam). When the wind
dies, Sweden turns up the taps on the hydroelectric production, and exports that
stored energy back to Denmark. It's a great zero-fossil system, but it's only
possible because of the unique geography that places a flat windy country right
next to a couple of wet mountainous countries.
Finally, it's important to note that the grid-buffering sources for wind (hydro in
Denmark, gas in the US) both have a higher EROI than wind itself. Thus these
hybrid systems do make economic sense, but that's partly because the buffering
portion makes economic sense on its own. Essentially, these hybrid systems
dilute the EROI of hydro or gas, in order to subsidize the EROI of the wind portion
of system. For the hybrid gas system that makes sense, because the reduction in
CO2 is worth it. For the hydro-buffered system, the question is more problematic.
In any case, it's clear that if wind had to be buffered with a non-generating
storage-only system, the economics would be difficult to justify.
But the big winners in non-fossil energy are run-of-river hydro (Weißbach allows
a 100 year plant lifetime, which may be generous) and nuclear (at a 60 year
plant lifetime, in line with other studies). And by the way, this is one reason
Weißbach's study is better than some earlier works: he includes plant lifetime in
4
his computations, which can make a big difference. Wind turbines, for example,
are subjected to large physical stresses which limits their lifetime to about 20
years, both in this study and according to the National Renewable Energy
Laboratory. In effect, you have to build a windfarm two or three times over
during the lifetime of a nuclear plant, and that adds up.
Two cases were analyzed for coal, one hard coal (EROI 29, EMROI 49) and one
brown coal (EROI 31, EMROI 49). These were averaged to an EROI of 30 as
shown. In the US we have plenty of hard coal reserves and don't use brown coal.
Also, the authors omitted from this study the energy cost needed to transport
coal, apparently because that varies by country. Using EIA data, this amounts to
244 KJ per tonne-km for rail transport. So in the US, where a lot of coal is moved
from mines in Wyoming to end users far away, a typical 1000 mile trip would
lower the EROI of coal from 29 to 28, while EMROI remains unchanged at 49.
It's interesting to note that other studies have put the unweighted EROI of
Canadian tar sands between 4 and 6, below the economic threshold. But
since the output of tar sands is non-electrical energy, its EMROI decreases
compared to EROI, which would put tar sands even farther below the
economic threshold in exergy terms. So instead of building Keystone XL,
Canada's economy would benefit far more by putting a lot of hydro in the Rockies
and building a powerline instead of a pipeline. If Obama nixes the pipeline (as he
seems poised to do), perhaps someone in Canada will take a harder look at the
dismal economics of it. Or we might have to wait until Harper is out of office.
EROI isn't a new concept, and there are a lot of similar studies out there already.
Weißbach has taken a good look at the previous literature and identified and
corrected inconsistencies in many previous works. Most especially, the EROI of
nuclear power in previous studies has been notoriously all-over-the-map, and
Weißbach has pointed out a raft of errors, omissions, and uneven-handedness in
earlier works, both those that come out above and below his result. Also,
Weißbach has used the most up-to-date databases available on the energy
embodiments of materials, which are required to compute energy inputs.
One reason previous studies on nuclear have been all over the map is that it's a
moving target: the EROI of nuclear has been rising rapidly during the past 20
years (and will continue to rise) as the industry switches from gas-diffusion
enrichment of uranium, to centrifuge enrichment (which is 35 times more energy
efficient). Since uranium enrichment is a major part of energy input, this makes a
huge difference. A nuclear plant using 100% gas diffusion would have and EROI
of 31, EMROI of 34, comparable to coal. Weißbach's numbers above are based on
83% centrifuge, 17% diffusion. The World Nuclear Association projection is that
there will be no more diffusion enrichment anywhere in the world by 2017. With
100% centrifuge, nuclear will have an EROI of 106, EMROI of 166 according to
Weißbach's analysis. In other words, the switch from diffusion to centrifuge
roughly quadruples the overall energy efficiency of nuclear power.
Beyond that, there is a new laser enrichment process being developed called
SILEX which promises to be 10 times more energy efficient than centrifuge. And
even beyond that, some Gen IV reactor designs (the fast neutron reactor, and the
liquid-fuel thorium reactor, or LFTR) don't use enrichment at all, and could
therefore come in at EROI of about 114, EMROI of 187. The LFTR in particular
can't melt down and produces almost no long-term waste, which is why the
Chinese are working on one right now. They've got 300 engineers doing the
design, based on US research into liquid fuel reactors from the 1960's and 70's.
(Your tax dollars at work -- in China.) The fast neutron reactor can use our
existing long-term nuclear "waste" as its fuel, which is why the Russians have
them, China and India are building them, and the British are considering it.
5
So if you ever wondered why climate scientists like James Hansen are pronuclear, this is one reason. Yes, wind is fine if it can be grid-buffered against a
non-fossil generating source. And absolutely we need more hydro, especially runof-river hydro where it's feasible. But there are limits to the amount of river
where it is feasible. So if we want to eliminate fossil fuels from electricity
production (and we do), and if we want to manage that transition so that it
doesn't hurt the economy (and we do), nuclear has to be part of the mix. And in
fact, it has to be a much bigger part of the mix than it has been in the past. In
the next part of GETTING TO ZERO, I will address the safety issues of nuclear
power in detail, but for right now what you need to know is that even after
accounting for latent deaths from Chernobyl (and non-deaths from
Fukushima), nuclear is still one of the safest forms of energy.
Finally, if you'd like to take a detailed look at the calculations, Weißbach's
spreadsheet can be found on Google Docs. I used the spreadsheet to
compute some of the numbers above.
Citation:
Weißbach, D., G. Ruprecht, A. Huke, K. Czerski, S. Gottlieb, and A. Hussein.
"Energy intensities, EROIs (energy returned on invested), and energy payback
times of electricity generating power plants." Energy 52 (2013) 210-221.
ISSN 0360-5442, http://dx.doi.org/....
6
Download