The ECJ Post Danmark judgment - Dansk forening for konkurrenceret

advertisement
Post Danmark: a big step towards a
consistent application of a consumer
oriented effects-based approach to
exclusionary pricing practices
Luc Peeperkorn*
Principal Expert in Antitrust Policy
DG Competition, Unit A 1 Antitrust case support and policy
Danish Competition Law Society, Copenhagen December 2012
*The views expressed are those of the speaker and do not necessarily reflect those of DG Competition or the
European Commission
1
The ECJ Post Danmark judgment
• Ruling of ECJ of 27 March 2012, Case C-209/10
Post Danmark A/S v Konkurrencerådet
• Preliminary ruling on questions referred by
the Danish Højesteret
• Will give you my views why this judgment is
very important
2
Why is this judgment so important?
• Firstly, ECJ was sitting as a Grand Chamber, i.e. 15
instead of the usual 3-5 judges
• Secondly, it affirms the application of a consumer
oriented effects-based approach to exclusionary
pricing conduct and thereby confirms many aspects
of the approach set out in the Commission’s Article
102 Guidance Paper (Guidance on the Commission’s enforcement
priorities in applying Article 82 of the Treaty to abusive exclusionary
conduct by dominant undertakings – adopted by the Commission in 2009)
3
Why is this judgment so important?
• Thirdly, it renders certain of the enforcement
priorities law and thereby provides for a more
consistent application of Art. 102 throughout the EU
• Fourthly, the effects-based approach leads to a more
consistent application of Articles 101 and 102,
important because of the concurrent application
• Lastly, it is good for international convergence,
which takes place along effects-based standards for
most practices (see ICN work)
4
Some facts of the case
• Post Danmark dominant on the liberalised market
for distribution of unaddressed mail and a legal
monopoly for addressed mail
• Forbruger-Kontakt main competitor on liberalised
market
• 2003/4 PD wins 3 major supermarkets as customers
from FK by offering targeted extra low prices
• The price offered to COOP is below ATC but above
AIC, the prices offered to SuperBest and Spar remain
above ATC
5
Some facts of the case
• September 2004: Konkurrencerådet holds that PD abused its
dominant position: its targeted price reductions are not
justified by cost differences and (may) lead to (1) primary line
discrimination, i.e. foreclosure of rivals of PD, and (2)
secondary line discrimination to the detriment of PD’s other
customers
• November 2004: Konkurrencerådet holds that PD had not
intentionally sought to eliminate competition and that there
was therefore no predatory pricing abuse
• July 2005: both decisions upheld by the competition appeals
tribunal (Konkurrenceankenævnet)
6
Some facts of the case
• No appeal as to the finding of no predation or to the
finding of secondary line discrimination
• However, PD appealed before the eastern regional
court (Østre Landsret) the finding of primary line
discrimination
• December 2007: finding upheld
• PD appealed before the Højesteret, claiming that its
prices could only be abusive if found to be predatory,
while the Konkurrencerådet maintained that prices
below ATC but above AIC could be abusive also
7
without the intention to foreclose
The referred questions
• April 2010: the Højesteret referred the following questions to
the ECJ:
• Do selective price reductions, on the part of a dominant
postal undertaking that has a universal service obligation,
to a level lower than the postal undertaking’s average
total cost, but higher than its average incremental costs,
constitute an exclusionary abuse, if it is established that
the price was not set at that level for the purpose of
driving out a competitor?
• If such pricing may be abusive, what are the circumstances
8
that the national court must take into account?
What the ECJ could have done and what it did
• The ECJ could have simply referred to the test
contained in its AKZO judgment: pricing above AVC
but below ATC can be found abusive only if a
strategy/intention to foreclose can be established
• But instead it came with a concise but elaborate
judgment expressing general points on the aim of
Article 102, on the role of an efficiency defence, on
how in general to assess pricing conduct and the
pivotal role of the as efficient competitor test in that
assessment
9
The aim of Article 102 and the notion of
exclusionary abuse
• § 20: Article 102 covers not only those practices that directly
cause harm to consumers but also practices that cause
consumers harm through their impact on competition…. It is
in the latter sense that the expression ‘exclusionary abuse’
appearing in the questions referred is to be understood.
• § 24: Article 102 applies, in particular, to the conduct of a
dominant undertaking that, through recourse to methods
different from those governing normal competition on the
basis of the performance of commercial operators, has the
effect, to the detriment of consumers, of hindering the
maintenance of the degree of competition existing in the
10
market or the growth of that competition.
The aim of Article 102 and the notion of
exclusionary abuse
• These two quotes are more than just repeating what already
had been said in Continental Can and Hoffmann La Roche
• The Hoffmann La Roche quote is amended by adding the
underlined to the detriment of consumers
• Together it confirms the choice in the Guidance Paper for a
consumer welfare oriented effects-based approach
• This is important in the debate of a more form-based versus a
more effects-based approach and of protecting the
competitive process in itself versus protecting consumers
• More than just semantics: differentiates between protecting
11
competitors and protecting competition
Clarification of ‘competition on the merits’
• §22: Competition on the merits may, by definition,
lead to the departure from the market or the
marginalisation of competitors that are less efficient
and so less attractive to consumers from the point of
view of, among other things, price, choice, quality or
innovation
• Language similar to Guidance Paper (§5-6)
• Competition on the merits = competition that does
not harm consumers
• Special responsibility = responsibility not to harm
consumers
12
Effective introduction of Article 102(3)
• Already clear in BA/Microsoft/TeliaSonera judgments that
also under Art 102 efficiency arguments can be used
• In PD §40-42, ECJ completely follows the Guidance Paper in
its distinction between an objective justification and
efficiency defence and to structure the latter as Art 101(3)
• Objective justification only a narrow ‘escape’, based on
arguments of general validity regarding health, safety etc
• Efficiency defence, based on same conditions as Art 101(3),
may provide a justification based on positive effects resulting
from that particular firm’s conduct
13
• Important also for consistent application of Art 101 and 102
As efficient competitor test as basis for
assessing pricing conduct
• Throughout the judgment the Court clarifies that, as a general
rule, Art 102 prohibits pricing conduct only if the conduct is
able to have an exclusionary effect on competitors as efficient
as the dominant firm, and that this provision does not aim to
shield inefficient competitors from competitive pressure (see
in particular paragraphs 21, 22, 28, 36, 38 of the judgment)
• § 38: Indeed, to the extent that a dominant undertaking sets
its prices at a level covering the bulk of the costs attributable
to the supply of the goods or services in question, it will, as a
general rule, be possible for a competitor as efficient as that
undertaking to compete with those prices without suffering 14
losses that are unsustainable in the long term
As efficient competitor test as basis for
assessing pricing conduct
• ECJ understands very well that only low pricing can exclude
and that it is only likely to harm consumers if the price is
below cost
• ECJ did not mention Compagnie Maritime Belge and Irish
Sugar, two cases where exceptionally abuse was found while
P>C
• In line with Guidance Paper: if reliable data are available,
Commission will apply the as efficient competitor test as part
of the assessment. In general harm to consumers only
possible if P < LRAIC (or ATC where significant common costs).
15
Only exceptionally harm possible if P > C
Some clarification on use of cost benchmarks
• Caution: ECJ had to work with cost estimates and definitions
as provided by Højesteret: not clear what exactly was
included in AIC: all short and long term incremental costs?
Apparently also part of common costs
• No strong conclusions but clear that ECJ is willing to consider
other cost benchmarks than AVC and ATC
• Guidance Paper stresses LRAIC and AAC
• In this case important common costs (shared infrastructure),
which makes that ATC benchmark may be more relevant than
LRAIC, as also described in Guidance Paper § 26 footnote 18
16
P<ATC not sufficient to find abuse: need to
show anticompetitive foreclosure
• The referred question was: when is pricing below ATC but
above AIC abusive? Answer by ECJ: in order to assess the
existence of anti-competitive effects in circumstances such as
those of that case, it is necessary to consider whether that
pricing policy […] produces an actual or likely exclusionary
effect, to the detriment of competition and, thereby, of
consumers’ interests
• Almost literally the description of anticompetitive foreclosure
in § 19 of Guidance Paper
• Shows again acceptance of effects-based approach
17
P<ATC not sufficient to find abuse: need to
show anticompetitive foreclosure
• Seems ECJ amended the AKZO test
• Akzo test:
• P < AVC: can presume strategy to foreclose as no economic
rationale to incur avoidable loss
• AVC > P < ATC: need to show strategy to foreclose (based on
intent documents/duration/selectivity etc)
• PD: if AIC > P < ATC: need to show likely anti-competitive
foreclosure effect
• Logically also sufficient if P < AIC
• No major change: strategy to foreclose and anticompetitive
foreclosure partly based on same factors
18
Effectively reduces application of Art 102(c)
• ECJ could have referred to older rebate case law in which
rather mechanically it was concluded that (secondary line)
price discrimination leads to an abuse under Art 102(c)
• In this case: COOP received better price than SuperBest and
Spar and these three received better prices than other
supermarkets
• § 30: this cannot of itself suggest that there exists an
exclusionary abuse
• General answer of the ECJ: need to show anticompetitive
foreclosure
19
• Effectively reduces application of Art 102(c)
Conclusion
• PD ruling strongly reminds us that aim of EU competition law
is to protect competition for the benefit of consumers
• PD ruling shows a strong support for an effects-based
approach for the assessment of exclusionary pricing conduct
• General acceptance of the as efficient competitor test for
pricing conduct (predation, margin squeeze, selective price
cuts) as part of the analysis to show anticompetitive
foreclosure
• Supports a more consistent application of EU competition law
• Question: will the General Court follow in the Intel case?
20
Thank you
21
Download