Presentation-Doha-Qatar-April-29-2013

advertisement

A Moral Obligation,

An Economic Priority:

The Urgency of Enrolling Out-of-School Children

Nicholas Burnett

April 29, 2013

Outline

 Primary Education: A Basic Human Right

 Out-of-School Children: A Persistent Global Challenge

 The Economic, Social, Political and Environmental

Benefits of Primary Education

 The Economic Costs of Out-of-School Children

1

Primary Education: A Basic Human Right

“Everyone has the right to education.”

Article 26 of the 1948 Universal

Declaration of Human Rights

“Ensuring that by 2015 all children, particularly girls, children in difficult circumstances and those belonging to ethnic minorities, have access to, and complete, free and compulsory primary education of good quality.”

“Ensure that, by 2015, children everywhere, boys and girls alike, will be able to complete a full course of primary schooling.”

Education For All Goal 2 Millennium Development Goal 2

2

Out-of-School Children

• According to official estimates, over 61 million children of primary school age are out of school (UIS 2012).

• Discrepancies between latest household datasets and UIS/UNESCO data on out-ofschool children suggest that the global population of OOSC is much higher.

27%

26%

47%

Expected never to enroll

Dropped out

Expect to enroll late

Source: UIS 2012

3

Out-of-School Children

• Progress in reducing OOSC has stagnated since the mid-2000s.

• OOSC are concentrated geographically (Sub-Saharan Africa and South Asia) and demographically

(females, children living with disabilities, and the poor).

• In some regions, OOSC is a persistent problem due to conflict or natural disaster.

South Africa

Mali

Yemen

Kenya

Niger

Burkina Faso

Cote d'Ivoire

Philippines

Ethiopia

Pakistan

Nigeria

0 2 4 6 8 10

2010

1999

4

Out-of-School Children: Country Variation

Breakdown of OOSC populations based on UIS analysis of household surveys, 2013

Number of

OOSC

(thousands)

School-aged

Children

(thousands)

% OOSC % Drop-outs % Likely to start late

Cote D'Ivoire*

(6-11, UIS 2009)

DRC

(6-11, EPDC 2010)

India**

(6-10, EPDC 2006)

India

(6-10, UIS 2008)

Mali

(7-12, UIS 2011)

Pakistan

(5-9, UIS 2010)

1,161

3,022

23,400

2,278

850

3,074

11,285

123,619

123,619

2,510

38%

26%

19%

2%

34%

8%

6%

3%

0.3%

1%

5,125 19,755 26% 2%

Yemen

(6-11, UIS 2010)

857 3,926 22% 4%

* The breakdown for Cote d’Ivoire is generated using regional figures for Sub-Saharan Africa, provided by UIS (2012).

**Two estimates are provided for India due to the large discrepancy between UIS and EPDC data.

9%

14%

7%

0.7%

1%

16%

10%

% Unlikely to Ever

Start

21%

6%

9%

0.9%

32%

8%

7%

% Non-completing

OOSC

The uneven progress in reducing OOSC makes this a critical time to reconsider the benefits of primary education and support

EAC’s mission.

29%

12%

12%

1.2%

33%

10%

11%

5

What benefits do out-of-school children forgo?

Economic Social Political Environmental

6

Economic Benefits of Primary Education

• Wage/Productivity gains associated with years of schooling.

• Economic returns to primary education are high, and critical to rising out of poverty.

Changes in Marginal Return to Education in Latin America in the 1990s.

Source: Behrman, Birdsall, and Szekely (2003)

Note: Linear return refers to yearly change in returns.

Returns to Investment in Education Level

Source: Psacharopoulos and Patrinos 2011

• Primary education has additional value as a gateway to the income benefits associated with post-primary education.

7

Social Benefits of Primary Education

• An instrument for social reproduction of social change. Good quality curricula can be instrumental for societal and personal values.

• Positive influence on education attainment of the next generation.

• Amartya Sen’s capabilities framework.

• Gross primary enrolment rates associated with lower rates of crime.

• Social Cohesion.

• Gender Equity, empowerment, self-esteem.

8

Health Benefits of Primary Education

Comparison of Under-five Mortality Rates by

Mother’s Education Level (2000-2010)

• Maternal and Child Care.

• Reproductive behaviors.

• Nutrition.

• Mortality Rates.

• Communicable disease.

• Health literacy.

The top bar in each set compares children of mothers with no education to children of mothers with post-primary education.

The bottom bar compares children of mothers with no education to children of mothers with primary education. 9

Political Benefits of Primary Education

• Development of democracy.

• Civic engagement.

• Government accountability.

• Voter participation.

• Additional benefits in conflict/post-conflict states.

• Peace-building.

Environmental Benefits of Primary Education

• Emerging evidence that education is associated with resilience to natural disasters (Blankespoor

2010).

• Primary education can also play a key role in mitigating climate change, by encouraging environmentally sustainable lifestyles.

11

What are the economic costs of out-of-school children?

Microeconomic Approach

12000

10000

8000

6000

4000

A

B

2000

0

2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 2022

Year

12000

10000

8000

6000

4000

2000

0

0

Macroeconomic Approach

A

B

2 4 6 8

Average Years of Schooling (S)

How much higher would GDP be …

…in ten years, if all of today’s children currently expected not to complete primary school actually do complete basic education?

…today, if a country had achieved universal primary school completion for the entire working population?

10

12

Microeconomic Cost Estimation

Total Microeconomic Cost

= B - A (see graph)

=

Direct Cost as a % of GDP

+

Probability-weighted GDP loss from forgone secondary education

B

A

2008 2010 2012 2014

Year

2016 2018 2020 2022

=

=

[% non-completing OOSC] x

[Wage premium to primary education]

+

[% non-completing OOSC] x

[Wage premium to secondary education] x

[rate of continuation from primary to secondary school] x

[rate of secondary school completion]

13

Microeconomic Cost Estimation

% Non-completing

OOSC

Direct Cost as a % of GDP

Probability-weighted GDP loss from forgone secondary education

Direct GDP loss +

Probability-weighted GDP loss from forgone secondary education

Cote d'Ivoire

(6-11, UIS 2009)

DRC

(6-11, EPDC 2010)

India*

(6-10, EPDC 2006)

India*

(6-10, UIS 2008)

Mali

(7-12, UIS 2011)

Pakistan

(5-9, UIS 2010)

29%

12%

12%

1.2%

33%

10%

4.3%

1.1%

0.3%

0.0%

2.9%

0.8%

2.54%

0.84%

0.98%

0.1%

2.61%

0.5%

6.8%

1.9%

1.3%

0.1%

5.5%

1.3%

Yemen**

(6-11, UIS 2010)

11% 1.1%

Sources for Wage Premia: Colclough (2009), Psacharopoulos and Patrinos (2004)

1.70% 2.8%

*Two estimates are provided for India due to the large discrepancy between UIS and EPDC data.

**Continuation to secondary school data was unavailable for Yemen. Mali’s rate of continuation was used, since Yemen and Mali have similar gross enrollment rates in secondary school.

Macroeconomic Cost Estimation

 Relationship between income and schooling estimated by

Barro and Lee (2010).

 If the average citizen completes primary education, then S = 6.

 The red segment above shows the estimated macroeconomic cost of OOSC for a country with

S = 4.

12000

10000

8000

6000

4000

2000

0

0 2 4 6

Average Years of Schooling (S)

8 10

15

Macroeconomic Cost Estimation

Macroeconomic estimates of the cost of large OOSC populations, 2010.

Country

Mean Years of Schooling (2010)

Estimated Income loss per capita

Cote D'Ivoire

D.R. of

Congo

India

Mali

Pakistan

Yemen

4.50

3.47

5.10

2.03

5.59

3.69

22.2%

43.3%

12.3%

83.8%

5.3%

38.4%

16

Conclusion

Research confirms that primary education has a range of strong positive impacts, increasing income potential, empowering citizens, reducing crime rates, improving public health, and breaking the cycle of poverty.

 Good quality education fosters life-long learning and ensures progress to higher education.

 The economic cost of today ’s out-of-school children is as much as 7% of GDP in some developing countries.

Out-of-school children represent an even greater source of economic loss when uneducated adults (out-of-school children of past generations) are accounted for.

Out-of-school children represent an unconscionable underinvestment that prevents nations from reaching their full economic and social potential.

Download