Uploaded by Chandler Bing

Trade modelling through partial and general equilibrium models (2)[1]

advertisement
Trade modelling through
partial and general
equilibrium models:Some
Applications
Professor Somesh. K.Mathur,IIT Kanpur
skmathur@iitk.ac.in
Online Lecture at the 55th Refresher Course in Economics through online mode organized by HRDC-JNU: October 3rd, 2022
Thank Manish Chauhan, research scholar at the IITK for the technical assistance
1

GRAVITY ANALYSIS WITH FOCUS ON STRUCTURAL GRAVITY MODEL AND FIRM
LEVEL TRADE ANALYSIS

APPLIED GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM MODELS : GTAP 10 and GTAP E

SINGLE MARKET PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM MODEL

APPLICATIONS
2
India’s Trade in Goods and Services with
the World

We have negative trade balance of merchandise where in we export 323 billion us dollars in 2019
but import 478 billion us dollars of merchandise from the world. This shortfall is met by positive
trade balance in terms of exports of services of the level of 321 billion us dollars and imports of 188
billion dollars, but not enough to cover up for having net current account deficit. This current
account deficit are more than matched by capital account surplus leading to have BOP surplus. The
latter has lead to appreciation of Indian rupee.

What is surprising to note is that we have Capital account surplus at the time of pandemic. Second
,all GTAP simulations of trade Liberalization show that India’s trade balance falls negative with
external Liberalization. Meaning our exchange rate may be overvalued and may see depreciation in
coming months.

What is disturbing is however to note that exports are not increasing while tariff increase has led to
constrains on imports and especially intermediate imports where in such protectionism in the
economy may force other countries to adopt tit for tat strategy of imposing duties on our products.

We need to focus on three Es, Electronics, Engineering and Electrical products and boost trade in
services and investments. For latter regulatory burdens and competition need to go up with fall in
non-tariff barriers. Our manufacturing, trade and MSMEs trade all are intertwined with each other .
Our overvalued exchange rate and lower growth in pandemic may be the reason that we saw our
PCY fell below that of Bangladesh.
3
4
Tariff Barriers among Indo-Pacific Nations
Table 1: Effectively Applied Weighted Average Tariff Rates between India and Indo-Pacific Regions
Product
India-ASEAN ASEAN-India
India-East
Asia
East AsiaIndia
IndiaIndia-EU-26 EU26-India France &
Germany
France &
Germany India
IndoPacific
India - IndoLatin
Pacific Latin
America America
India
India to
Latin
America
Indo-Pacific
Latin
America
Indo-Pacific
-- India
Extraction
0.02
3.98
8.91
0.75
9.65
0.06
6.5
0.4
0.37
4.33
0.67
4.32
GrainCrops
10.94
2.69
17.66
7.71
14.62
2.5
6.67
2.08
49.28
2.68
48.46
5.51
Heavymanu
1.48
1.52
5.58
2.99
8.28
2.59
8.38
3.11
2.37
3.24
4.62
3.21
Lightmanu
2
7.81
10.98
4.4
13.49
4.86
12.95
4.5
1.37
5.51
2.9
11.16
Meatandme
atprod
0
0.05
11.16
4.45
13.78
2.71
16.77
1.98
6.55
5.91
2.52
5.82
ProcessedFo
od
40.41
5.51
34.65
5.1
49.22
7.63
49.28
5.96
36.19
3.97
35.15
5.62
4.5
3.85
16.74
3.07
17.96
9.82
17.8
10.42
19.76
6.37
19.66
7.88
Textile
Source: WITS Database
5
Tariff Barriers among Indo-Pacific Nations
Effectively Applied Weighted Average Tariff Rates between India and Indo-Pacific Regions Continued….
Product
India - North North America India America
- India
Oceania
Oceania -India
India - South South East
East Asia
Asia - India
India - SSA
SSA - India
India - West
Asia
West Asia India
Extraction
1.49
0.35
2.92
0.1
0.64
7.54
1.48
1.97
2.34
1.42
GrainCrops
23.35
3.23
30.88
0.09
2.26
11.18
11.06
8.23
15.23
10.84
Heavymanu
7.62
1.54
7.58
2.45
0.44
6.34
4.18
4.18
7.33
5.02
Lightmanu
9.26
2.86
7.74
4.36
0.1
17.33
8.58
14.64
9.15
6.3
Meatandmeat
prod
23.25
1.08
2.88
2.42
1.24
6.68
2.88
13.34
2.94
1.74
ProcessedFoo
d
53.91
2.74
42.99
2.24
0.71
11.13
56.61
20.64
48.45
14.89
Textile
15.16
9.62
17.25
4.52
0.65
9.65
15.7
22.16
17.76
7.53
Source: WITS Database
6
Tariff Profile Conti….
Products
India-East Asia
India-ASEAN 10
Exports to
Grain Crops
Import from
Exports to
India-Other South Asian Countries
Import from
Exports to
Import from
26.8246
24.9264
4.6317
27.2592
6.5999
13.1421
1.77
22.2374
14.693
13.1839
6.1216
3.8573
Extraction
0.3964
0.9899
3.2482
3.4194
12.2931
13.3748
Processed Food
5.8585
35.1448
12.2293
73.6284
9.9807
10.5107
Textiles
3.7826
13.0624
3.7581
11.4759
9.3689
2.452
Light Manufacturing
1.5078
9.4988
5.8107
7.9824
7.152
1.9657
Heavy Manufacturing
1.6686
5.5867
1.5506
5.5155
7.9749
1.4283
Meat & Meat Products
Source: GTAP10
7
Tariff Profile
Country
Overall
Agriculture
Manufacturing
Republic of Korea
4.8
44.7
3.1
Cambodia
3.3
0.6
4.0
China
2.8
6.7
3.1
Japan
1.7
10.2
1.2
Thailand
1.7
1.0
2.0
Vietnam
1.2
1.1
1.3
Indonesia
0.9
1.0
1.0
Malaysia
0.9
0.1
1.1
Philippines
0.7
0.4
0.8
Myanmar
0.6
0.2
0.7
Lao PDR
0.2
0.2
0.2
Australia
0.0
0.0
0.0
Brunei Darussalam
0.0
0.0
0.0
New Zealand
0.0
0.0
0.0
Singapore
0.0
0.0
0.0
Note: Tariffs are trade weighted averages
Source: UNCTAD secretariat based on Nicita (2021)
8
Tariff Profile of Countries
Table 1: Tariff Profile of Major IPEF Countries
Tariff rate among IPEF 10
IPEF-10 to
IPEF-10
Japan
Exporting
to IPEF 10
US
export
to IPEF
10
IPEF 10
exporting
to japan
IPEF 10
export
to USA
India
exports to
IPEF 10
India
exporting
to Japan
IPEF to
India
Japan
Exporting
to India
India to US US to India
Agriculture and allied activities
5.98
8.04
12.8
25.84
1.47
16.4021
60.62
2.27
32.61
0.312
26.14
Coal
0.02
0.34
0
0.0018
0
0.0825
3.38
0
0
0
3.404
Oil
0.003
0.0002
0
0.0006
0
0
0.033
0
0
0
0.0022
Gas
0.099
0
0
0
0
0
5.03
0
0
0
0
0.6521
1.42
0.8828
0.49
0.024
0.647
4.5856
0
0
0
4.85
0
0
0
0
0
0.1172
0
0
0
0
0
0.89
2.95
0.366
1.54
0.8
1.7419
6.82
0.32
7.0085
0.51
8.1627
Industry
0.966
4.76
0.409
1.33
2.51
4.61
5.68
0.5199
7.725
3.955
7.1374
Average
1.076263
2.188775
1.807225
3.6503
0.6005
2.950088
10.76858
9
0.388738
5.917938
0.597125
6.212038
Oil and petroleum
Electricity
Energy intensive industry
Source: Author’s own simulations via GTAP E.
Non Tariff Barriers

Non tariff measures in India product wise distinguished by technical and non
technical or price measures. Footwear, fuels and wood faces price measures in
India like licensing, quotas, paratariffs, anti competitive export measures.
Animals, chemical, hides , vegetables and skin imports face TBTs and SPS non
tariff measures.

AMS command is used in GTAP to account for NTMs in the general equilibrium
model. The NTMs data comes from UNESCAP, WTO designed TINA and WITS
platforms. Textile and clothing faces both price and non price measures to
safeguard our economic interest. NTMs and NTBs have very thin line separating
them, meaning when NTMs are used as protectionist device they become barriers
and therefore are subject to discussion. Stones ,plastics and rubber imports faces
more price measures.

Anti Competitive measures include state trading enterprises for importing and
measures affecting competition. SPS includes registration requirements for
importers, tolerance limits for residue and restricted use of substance,
prohibitions and temporary geographic prohibitions. TBT includes licensing,
marking and packaging requirements, and other prohibitions.
10
Non-Tariff Barriers Profile of Selected
RCEP Nations
Australia
P:Export related measures
N:Intellectual property
Brunei
Cambodia
J:Distribution restrictions
Indonesia
H:Anti-competitive measures
G:Finance measures
Japan
F:Charges, taxes and other para-tariff measures
Malaysia
E:Licences, quotas, prohibitions and other quantity control
measures
D:Price control measures
Myanmar
New Zealand
C:Pre-shipment inspection and other formalities
Philippines
B:Technical barriers to trade
Singapore
A:Sanitary and phytosanitary measures
Thailand
Vietnam
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
11
Source: Prepared by Authors using Non-Tariff Barriers data from World Integrated Trade Solutions (WITS
database)
Non-Tariff Measures among Indo-Pacific Nations
(UNCTAD)
Developing
Country
Frequency
Index
Coverage
Ratio
Prevalance
Score
Developed
Country
Frequency
Index
Coverage Ratio Prevalance Score
Cambodia
96
98
4.4 Australia
67
70
3.5
China
90
92
6.8 Brunei
46
60
2.4
Colombia
46
63
2.5 Canada
100
98
4.2
Ecuador
46
64
2.6 Chile
61
61
1.3
Indonesia
61
70
3 France
92
89
6.3
Malaysia
48
63
2.4 Germany
92
89
6.3
Mexico
38
45
61
76
3.3
Myanmar
88
88
2.6 New Zealand
59
73
2.5
Oman
45
46
1.7 Russian Federation
76
85
4.2
Pakistan
11
33
0.2 Singapore
47
60
2.6
Peru
29
59
1.4 United Arab Emirates
52
46
3.4
Philippines
84
88
77
83
4.1
Sri Lanka
47
63
1.7 Average
69.16667
74.16667
3.675
Thailand
28
38
2.1
Vietnam
89
92
5
India
47
69
4.9
55.8125
66.9375
2.89375
Average
1 Japan
4 United States
Note: The coverage ratio (CR) measures the percentage of trade subject to NTMs, the frequency index12(FI) indicates the percentage
of products to which NTMs apply, and the prevalence score (PS) is the average number of NTMs applied to products.
Non-Tariff Barriers Distinguishing the Developed and Developing
Economies in Indo-Pacific Alliance
Non-Tariff Barriers by Sectors and Measures
Australia
Bangladesh
Brunei
Cambodia
Canada
Chile
China
Colombia
Comoros
Ecuador
Fiji
France
Germany
Indonesia
Iran, Islamic Rep.
Japan
Kenya
Korea, Rep.
Lao PDR
Madagascar
Malaysia
Maldives
Mauritius
Mexico
Mozambique
Myanmar
New Zealand
Oman
Pakistan
Papua New Guinea
Peru
Philippines
Russian Federation
Seychelles
Singapore
Somalia
South Africa
Sri Lanka
Tanzania
Thailand
United Arab Emirates
United States
Vietnam
Yemen
India
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
13
Source: UNCTAD NTM Measures
Increased Bilateral CO2 Emissions in Trade
Source: Tian, K., Zhang, Y., Li, Y., Ming, X., Jiang, S., Duan, H., ... & Wang, S. (2022). Regional trade
agreement burdens global carbon emissions mitigation. Nature Communications, 13(1), 1-12.
Note: The figure presents the increased amount of CO2 emitted in the region of origin
(left) for its
14
production
of exports to a destination (the right)
Sectoral Contribution to CO2 Emissions in Trade
Source: Tian, K., Zhang, Y., Li, Y., Ming, X., Jiang, S., Duan, H., ... & Wang, S.15 (2022). Regional trade agreem
burdens global carbon emissions mitigation. Nature Communications, 13(1), 1-12.
Gravity Model: Origin
Firstly given by Tinbergen (1962)
𝛽
𝐹𝑖𝑗 =
𝑀𝑖𝛼 𝑀𝑗
𝛿
𝐷𝑖𝑗
▪ 𝐹𝑖𝑗 is the flow of trade (exports or imports) from origin i to destination j;
▪ 𝑀𝑖 and 𝑀𝑗 are the economic masses (GDPs) of these two nations; and
▪ 𝐷𝑖𝑗 is the distance between these countries.
Econometric Model :
ln 𝑋𝑖𝑗 = 𝛽0 + 𝛽1 ln 𝐺𝐷𝑃𝑖 + 𝛽2 ln 𝐺𝐷𝑃𝑗 + 𝛽3 ln 𝐷𝑖𝑗 + 𝜀𝑖𝑡
16
Border Puzzle: McCallum (1995)
He estimated the following Gravity equation to see the trade pattern
between Canada and U.S. :
𝑿𝒊𝒋 = 𝜶 + 𝜷𝟏 𝒚𝒊 + 𝜷𝟐 𝒚𝒋 + 𝜷𝟑 𝒅𝒊𝒔𝒕𝒊𝒋 + 𝜷𝟒 𝑫𝑼𝑴𝑴𝒀𝒊𝒋 + 𝒖𝒊𝒋
Where:
•
•
•
•
𝑿𝒊𝒋 is the logarithm of shipments of goods from region i to region j,
𝒚𝒊 and 𝒚𝒋 are the logarithms of gross domestic product in regions i and j,
𝒅𝒊𝒔𝒕𝒊𝒋 is the logarithm of the distance from i to j,
𝑫𝑼𝑴𝑴𝒀𝒊𝒋 is a dummy variable equal to 1 for interprovincial trade and 0 for
province-to-state trade
The study found that U.S.-Canadian border led to the trade between
Canadian provinces that is a factor 22 (2200 percent) times trade between
U.S. and Canadian provinces.
17
Gravity Model: Evolution
▪ Anderson (1979)
❖
❖
❖
❖
▪ Anderson and Wincoop (2003)
All goods are differentiated by the place of origin,
Each region is specialized in the production of one good only,
The supply of each good is fixed, and
Identical homothetic preferences approximated by CES utility
function
𝒚𝒊 𝒚𝒋 𝒕𝒊𝒋
𝑿𝒊𝒋 = 𝒘
𝒚
𝝅𝒊 𝒑𝒋
Gravity
Model
𝟏−𝝈
1−𝜎
𝜋𝑖 1−𝜎 = ෍ 𝑝𝑗𝜎−1 𝜃𝑗 𝑡𝑖𝑗
∀𝑖
𝑗
1−𝜎
𝑝𝑗 1−𝜎 = ෍ 𝜋𝑖𝜎−1 𝜃𝑖 𝑡𝑖𝑗
∀𝑗
𝑖
• 𝜎=
1
1−𝜌
> 1 and 0 < 𝜌 < 1
• 𝜋𝑖 is the MR for Country i (Outward MR)
• 𝑝𝑗 is the MR for Country j (Inward MR)
• 𝜃𝑗 is the world income share of country j , 𝜃𝑗 =
𝑌𝑗
𝑌𝑤
18
Anderson and Wincoop (2003):
were of the opinion that it is not only the bilateral
trade barriers but also multilateral trade barriers
that determine the trade flows between two
countries and the trade cost function is:
𝜌
𝑡𝑖𝑗 = 𝑏𝑖𝑗 𝑑𝑖𝑗
Where: 𝑏𝑖𝑗 is the Border related indicator variable;
and 𝑑𝑖𝑗 is the distance between i and j
19
20
21
R Packhage Gravity
22
MTR
• Model 1: Capturing Multilateral Trade Resistance Term with Country Fixed Effects
• Under this approach the multilateral trade resistance terms can be captured by the usage of country
specific effects in the model. These effects will automatically take care of the country specific
characteristics and multilateral trade resistance terms. Under this model, the equation can be
written as:
23
MTR
• Model 2: Capturing Multilateral Trade Resistance Term with the Method Developed by
Baier and Bergstrand (2009)
• This is another way to capture the multilateral resistance terms by making the proper
adjustments in the trade cost factor that will automatically capture the trade resistance
terms. Hence, there is no need to apply the fixed effects. Under this approach, the gravity
model can be written as:
• Where:
are the modified trade costs and the modification has been done by
using the following formula:
24
Bonus Vetus OLS (BB 2009)
Original form of Theoretical Gravity
𝑘
𝑘
log 𝑋𝑖𝑗
= log 𝑌𝑖𝑘 + log 𝐸𝑗𝑘 − log 𝑌 𝑘 + 1 − 𝜎𝑘 log 𝜏𝑖𝑗
− log Π𝑖𝑘 − log 𝑃𝑗𝑘
Baier and Bergstrand transformation
𝑘
log 𝑋𝑖𝑗
=
log 𝑌𝑖𝑘
+
log 𝐸𝑗𝑘
− log 𝑌 𝑘
+ 1 − 𝜎𝑘
𝑘∗
log 𝜏𝑖𝑗
by using the 1st order Taylor series approximation of MTR:
𝑘∗
log 𝜏𝑖𝑗
𝑘
𝑘
𝑘
𝑁
𝑘
𝑘
𝑁
𝑁
𝑘
= log 𝜏𝑖𝑗
− ∑𝑁
𝑗=1 𝜃𝑗 log 𝜏𝑖𝑗 − ∑𝑖=1 𝜃𝑖 log 𝜏𝑗𝑖 + ∑𝑖=1 ∑𝑗=1 𝜃𝑖 𝜃𝑗 log 𝜏𝑖𝑗
weighted by GDP shares
𝑶𝑘𝑖 =
𝑌𝑖𝑘
𝑌𝑘
25
Bonus Vetus OLS (BB 2009) Contd.
BB estimation procedures
1. Calculate the weight terms
∗
2. Calculate log 𝜏𝑖𝑗
for EACH trade-cost variable
ln dist ∗𝑖𝑗 = ln dist 𝑖𝑗 −∑𝑖 𝜃𝑖 ln dist 𝑖𝑗 −∑𝑗 𝜃𝑗 ln dist 𝑖𝑗 +∑𝑖 ∑𝑗 𝜃𝑖 𝜃𝑗 ln dist 𝑖𝑗
contig ∗𝑖𝑗 = contig 𝑖𝑗 − ∑𝑖 𝜃𝑖 contig 𝑖𝑗 −∑𝑗 𝜃𝑗 contig 𝑖𝑗 + ∑𝑖 ∑𝑗 𝜃𝑖 𝜃𝑗 contig 𝑖𝑗
3. Estimate the BB gravity model with OLS
𝑘
log 𝑋𝑖𝑗
=
Find the weight term:
∗
Calculate log 𝜏𝑖𝑗
log 𝑌𝑖𝑘
𝜃𝑖𝑘
=
+
log 𝐸𝑗𝑘
𝑘
− log 𝑌 + 1 − 𝜎𝑘
𝑘∗
log 𝜏𝑖𝑗
1
𝑁𝑖𝑘
Variable
Obs
ln_exporte~
P
ln_importe~
P
Mean
Std. Dev. Min
Max
583 26.85428 1.837116 23.32071 30.31317
583 26.80706 1.988583 23.32071 30.31317
26
MTR
• In the above equation, θi and θj and are the income shares of
country I and county j in the word income; and TCijk are the
calculated trade costs between the trading nations for the
trade of kth product.
27
MTR
• Model 3: Capturing Multilateral Trade Resistance Terms withthe Method Developed by Novy
(2013)
• Novy(2013) decomposed the growth of trade into three factors: the growth of income of the trading
partners; decline in the trade costs between them; and the decrease in the multilateral trade
resistance term. His final equation of decomposition of trade is given by
• Where: (I) is the contribution of growth in income; (II) is the contribution of decline in trade costs;
and (III) is the contribution of increase in the multilateral trade resistance term. From equation the
part (III) can be picked to replace the multilateral trade resistance terms in the gravity equation. The
final gravity equation can be written as:
28
MTR
• Where, MTRijt is the multilateral trade resistance terms and
calculated as:
• In the above equation yi,yj and yw denotes the GDPs of
country i, country j and world respectively, and xii and xjj
denotes the domestic trade of country i and country j
respectively.
29
30
Measurement of Trade Costs (Novy, 2008)
❖ No need to assume 𝑡𝑖𝑗 = 𝑡𝑗𝑖 and any particular trade cost function;
❖ Change in bilateral trade costs also affects the Intra-national trade; &
❖ Trade Costs vary overtime.
Final equation of Anderson and Wincoop(2003) can be used for the
intra-national trade of country i:
𝑦𝑖 𝑦𝑖 𝑡𝑖𝑖
𝑥𝑖𝑖 = 𝑤
𝑦
𝜋𝑖 𝑝𝑖
𝑥𝑖𝑖 Τ𝑦𝑖
𝜋𝑖 𝑝𝑖 =
𝑦𝑖 Τ𝑦 𝑤
1−𝜎
1
𝜎−1
𝑡𝑖𝑖
31
Continued…
Making the bilateral equation:
𝑦𝑖 𝑦𝑗
𝑥𝑖𝑗 𝑥𝑗𝑖 =
𝑦𝑤
2
𝑡𝑖𝑗 𝑡𝑗𝑖
𝜋𝑖 𝑝𝑖 𝜋𝑗 𝑝𝑗
1−𝜎
By substituting the values of 𝜋𝑖 𝑝𝑖 and 𝜋𝑗 𝑝𝑗 :
𝜏𝑖𝑗 =
•
•
•
•
1
𝑥𝑖𝑖 𝑥𝑗𝑗 2 𝜎−1
𝑥𝑖𝑗 𝑥𝑗𝑖
−1
𝜏𝑖𝑗 represents the tariff equivalents of trade costs,;
𝑥𝑖𝑖 and 𝑥𝑗𝑗 are the intranational trade flows of country i and jrespectively;
𝑥𝑖𝑗 and 𝑥𝑗𝑖 are the international bilateral trade flows of country i and j;&
σis the elasticity of substitution across goods.
“Trade costs depend upon the ratio of intra-national trade to
international trade”
32
Decomposition of Growth of Trade
∆𝑙𝑛 𝑥𝑖𝑗 𝑥𝑗𝑖 = 2∆𝑙𝑛
𝜏𝑖𝑗 =
𝑦𝑖 𝑦𝑖
+ 1 − 𝜎 ∆𝑙𝑛 𝑡𝑖𝑗 𝑡𝑗𝑖 − 1 − 𝜎 ∆𝑙𝑛 𝜋𝑖 𝑝𝑖 𝜋𝑗 𝑝𝑗
𝑦𝑤
𝑡𝑖𝑗 𝑡𝑗𝑖
𝑡𝑖𝑖 𝑡𝑗𝑗
1
2
−1
𝜏𝑖𝑗 +1
=>
2
=
𝜏𝑖𝑗 +1 =
𝑡𝑖𝑗 𝑡𝑗𝑖
𝑡𝑖𝑖 𝑡𝑗𝑗
𝑡𝑖𝑗 𝑡𝑗𝑖 = 𝜏𝑖𝑗 +1
∆𝑙𝑛 𝑥𝑖𝑗 𝑥𝑗𝑖 = 2∆𝑙𝑛
𝑦𝑖 𝑦𝑖
+ 1 − 𝜎 ∆𝑙𝑛
𝑦𝑤
𝑡𝑖𝑗 𝑡𝑗𝑖
𝑡𝑖𝑖 𝑡𝑗𝑗
1
2
2
𝜏𝑖𝑗 +1
𝑡𝑖𝑖 𝑡𝑗𝑗
2
𝑡𝑖𝑖 𝑡𝑗𝑗
− 1 − 𝜎 ∆𝑙𝑛 𝜋𝑖 𝑝𝑖 𝜋𝑗 𝑝𝑗
𝑦𝑖 𝑦𝑖
2
+
1
−
𝜎
∆𝑙𝑛
𝜏
+1
+ 1 − 𝜎 ∆𝑙𝑛 𝑡𝑖𝑖 𝑡𝑗𝑗 − 1 − 𝜎 ∆𝑙𝑛 𝜋𝑖 𝑝𝑖 𝜋𝑗 𝑝𝑗
𝑖𝑗
𝑦𝑤
𝑦𝑖 𝑦𝑖
2
∆𝑙𝑛 𝑥𝑖𝑗 𝑥𝑗𝑖 = 2∆𝑙𝑛
+
1
−
𝜎
∆𝑙𝑛
𝜏
+1
− 1 − 𝜎 ∆𝑙𝑛 𝜋𝑖 𝑝𝑖 𝜋𝑗 𝑝𝑗 + ∆𝑙𝑛 𝑡𝑖𝑖 𝑡𝑗𝑗
𝑖𝑗
𝑦𝑤
𝑦𝑖 𝑦𝑖
∆𝑙𝑛 𝑥𝑖𝑗 𝑥𝑗𝑖 = 2∆𝑙𝑛
+ 2 1 − 𝜎 ∆𝑙𝑛 𝜏𝑖𝑗 +1 − 1 − 𝜎 ∆𝑙𝑛 𝜋𝑖 𝑝𝑖 𝜋𝑗 𝑝𝑗 − ∆𝑙𝑛 𝑡𝑖𝑖 𝑡𝑗𝑗
𝑦𝑤
𝜋𝑖 𝑝𝑖 𝜋𝑗 𝑝𝑗
𝑦𝑖 𝑦𝑖
∆𝑙𝑛 𝑥𝑖𝑗 𝑥𝑗𝑖 = 2∆𝑙𝑛
+
2
1
−
𝜎
∆𝑙𝑛
𝜏
+1
−
1
−
𝜎
∆𝑙𝑛
𝑖𝑗
𝑦𝑤
𝑡𝑖𝑖 𝑡𝑗𝑗
𝑦𝑖 𝑦𝑖
𝜋𝑖 𝑝𝑖 𝜋𝑗 𝑝𝑗
∆𝑙𝑛 𝑥𝑖𝑗 𝑥𝑗𝑖 = 2∆𝑙𝑛
+
2
1
−
𝜎
∆𝑙𝑛
𝜏
+1
−
1
−
𝜎
∆𝑙𝑛
𝑖𝑗
𝑦𝑤
𝑡𝑖𝑖 𝑡𝑗𝑗
∆𝑙𝑛 𝑥𝑖𝑗 𝑥𝑗𝑖 = 2∆𝑙𝑛
33
Cntd…..
∆𝑙𝑛 𝑥𝑖𝑗 𝑥𝑗𝑖 = 2∆𝑙𝑛
𝑦𝑖 𝑦𝑖
+ 2 1 − 𝜎 ∆𝑙𝑛 𝜏𝑖𝑗 +1 − 1 − 𝜎 ∆𝑙𝑛
𝑦𝑤
𝜋𝑖 𝑝𝑖
𝑡𝑖𝑖
1
2
𝜋𝑗 𝑝𝑗
𝑡𝑗𝑗
1
2
𝜋𝑗 𝑝𝑗
𝑦𝑖 𝑦𝑖
𝜋𝑖 𝑝𝑖
+
2
1
−
𝜎
∆𝑙𝑛
𝜏
+1
−
2
1
−
𝜎
∆𝑙𝑛
𝑖𝑗
𝑦𝑤
𝑡𝑖𝑖
𝑡𝑗𝑗
𝑦𝑖 𝑦𝑖
= 2∆𝑙𝑛
+ 2 1 − 𝜎 ∆𝑙𝑛 𝜏𝑖𝑗 +1 − 2 1 − 𝜎 ∆𝑙𝑛 Φi Φj
𝑦𝑤
2
1
2
1
2
∆𝑙𝑛 𝑥𝑖𝑗 𝑥𝑗𝑖 = 2∆𝑙𝑛
∆𝑙𝑛 𝑥𝑖𝑗 𝑥𝑗𝑖
𝒚𝒊 𝒚𝒋
𝟐∆𝒍𝒏
𝟐 𝟏 − 𝝈 ∆ 𝒍𝒏 𝟏 + 𝝉𝒊𝒋
𝟐 𝟏 − 𝝈 ∆ 𝒍𝒏 𝜱𝒊 𝜱𝒋
𝒚𝒘
𝟏𝟎𝟎% =
+
−
∆𝒍𝒏 𝒙𝒊𝒋 𝒙𝒋𝒊
∆𝒍𝒏 𝒙𝒊𝒋 𝒙𝒋𝒊
∆𝒍𝒏 𝒙𝒊𝒋 𝒙𝒋𝒊
(𝒂)
(𝒃)
(𝒄)
Where:
•
•
•
(a) is the Contribution of Income Growth;
(b) is the Contribution of the Decline in Relative Bilateral Trade Costs; and
(c) is the Contribution of the Decline in Relative Multilateral Resistance.
34
35
Source: A. GAURAV AND S. K. MATHUR 2013
36
37
38
Traditional Way for Measuring MTR
• Remoteness Index
dist 𝑖𝑗
Re 𝑚𝑖 = ∑𝑗
𝐺𝐷𝑃𝑗 /𝐺𝐷𝑃𝑊
39
PPML Model
• PPML model is another estimation method for the gravity
models in their multiplicative forms.
• The model belongs to generalized linear models using quasipoisson distribution and log-link.
• The model is present by Silva and Tenreyro (2006).
• The estimation method can be used for cross sectional and
panel data sets.
40
The PPML equation is:
log Lamda = Cons tan t +  i +  j + 1tariff +  2 dis tan ce +
 3 NTM Re porter Pr evelanceSCore +  4 NTMPartner Pr evelanceScore +
 5 RCEPTCdummyij +  6 RCEPTD − 1dummyij +  7 RCEPTD − 2dummyij +  8 ASEANTCdummyij +
 9 ASEANTD − 1dummyij + 10 ASEANTD − 2dummyij + error
 i i and  j are modelled through 16 exporter and 16 importer dummies. ASEAN TC dummy takes the value 1 if i and j are part of the ASEAN
agreement (ten ASEAN nations). RCEP TC dummy takes the value 1 if i and j are part of the RCEP agreement (15 RCEP nations). RCEP TD-1
dummy takes the value 1 if i is part of the RCEP agreement and j is not part of the RCEP agreement, 0 otherwise. RCEP TD-2 dummy takes the
value 1 if i is not part of the RCEP agreement while j is part of the RCEP agreement, 0 otherwise. ASEAN TD-1 dummy takes the value 1 if i is
part of the ASEAN agreement and j is not part of the ASEAN agreement, 0 otherwise. ASEAN TD-2 dummy takes the value 1 if i is not part of
the ASEAN agreement while j is part of the ASEAN agreement, 0 otherwise. The above equation uses OLS for estimating the equation. If the
dependent variable takes the value 0, we use the PPML (Poisson Pseudo Maximum Likelihood Procedure) for estimation of our model.
41
Applications of Gravity Modelling
• Trade Creation and Trade Diversion
• Trade policies and Welfare
• Counterfactuals
42
• Cost of Importing an Automobile Part This table shows the cost to the United States of purchasing an
automobile part from various source countries, with and without tariffs. If there is a 20% tariff on all
countries, then it would be cheapest for the United States to buy the auto part from itself (for $22).
• But when the tariff is eliminated on Mexico after NAFTA, then the United States would instead buy from
that country (for $20), which illustrates the idea of trade creation.
• If instead we start with a 10% tariff on all countries, then it would be cheapest for the United States to
buy from Asia (for $20.90). When the tariff on Mexico is eliminated under NAFTA, then the United States
would instead buy there (for $20), illustrating the idea of trade diversion.
43
Structural Gravity Analysis to Understand the Trade Creation
and Trade Diversion Impact of Indo-ASEAN FTA on Trade of
India with IPEF and Indo-Pacific Nations
44
45
46
47
48
• Codes in STATA for Multilateral Trade Resistance terms
egen exporters=group(reporter)
egen importers=group(partner)
quietly tabulate exporters, generate(exp_dum_)
quietly tabulate importers, generate(imp_dum_)
• Codes for generating variable for Bonus vetus OLS (BVU) in stata
egen temp1 = mean(ln_distance), by ( productname )
egen temp2 = mean(ln_distance), by ( productname )
egen temp3 = sum(ln_distance), by ( productname )
gen ln_distance_star = ln_distance - temp1 - temp2 + (1/(30.31*30.31))*temp3
egen temp4 = mean(ln_tariff), by ( productname )
egen temp5 = mean(ln_tariff), by ( productname )
egen temp6 = sum(ln_tariff), by ( productname )
gen ln_tariff_star = ln_tariff - temp4 - temp5 + (1/(30.31*30.31))*temp6
egen temp14 = mean(ln_ntm_prevalence_score_reporter), by ( productname )
egen temp15 = mean(ln_ntm_prevalence_score_reporter), by ( productname )
egen temp16 = sum(ln_ntm_prevalence_score_reporter), by ( productname )
gen ln_ntm_prevalence_reporterstar = ln_ntm_prevalence_score_reporter - temp14 - temp15 + (1/(30.31*30.31))*temp16
egen temp17 = mean(ln_ntm_prevalence_score_partner), by ( productname )
egen temp18 = mean(ln_ntm_prevalence_score_partner), by ( productname )
egen temp19 = sum(ln_ntm_prevalence_score_partner), by ( productname )
gen ln_ntm_prevalence_partnerstar = ln_ntm_prevalence_score_partner - temp17 - temp18 + (1/(30.31*30.31))*temp19
49
• Codes for two-way fixed effect model in STATA
regress ln_imports ln_gdp_exporter ln_gdp_importer ln_distance ln_tariff ASEAN_dummy ASEAN_td_1 ASEAN_td _2 RCEP RCEP_td_1 RCEP_td_2
ln_ntm_prevalence_score_reporter ln_ntm_prevalence_score_partner exp1_dum_1 exp1_dum_2 exp1_dum_3 exp1_dum_4 exp1_dum_5 exp1_dum_6
exp1_dum_7 exp1_dum_8 exp1_dum_9 exp1_dum_10 exp1_dum_11 exp1_dum_12 exp1_dum_13 exp1_dum_14 exp1_dum_15 exp1_dum_16
imp1_dum_1 imp1_dum_2 imp1_dum_3 imp1_dum_4 imp1_dum_5 imp1_dum_6 imp1_dum_7 imp1_dum_8 imp1_dum_9 imp1_dum_10 imp1_dum_11
imp1_dum_12 imp1_dum_13 imp1_dum_14 imp1_dum_15 imp1_dum_16, vce(robust)
• Codes for PPML in STATA: Poisson Pseudo Maximum Likelihood
poisson importvaluesper1000usd gdp_exporter gdp_importer distance simpleaverage ASEAN_dummy ASEAN_td_1 ASEAN_td _2 RCEP RCEP_td_1
RCEP_td_2 ln_ntm_prevalence_score_reporter ln_ntm_prevalence_score_partner exp1_dum_1 exp1_dum_2 exp1_dum_3 exp1_dum_4 exp1_dum_5
exp1_dum_6 exp1_dum_7 exp1_dum_8 exp1_dum_9 exp1_dum_10 exp1_dum_11 exp1_dum_12 exp1_dum_13 exp1_dum_14 exp1_dum_15
exp1_dum_16 imp1_dum_1 imp1_dum_2 imp1_dum_3 imp1_dum_4 imp1_dum_5 imp1_dum_6 imp1_dum_7 imp1_dum_8 imp1_dum_9 imp1_dum_10
imp1_dum_11 imp1_dum_12 imp1_dum_13 imp1_dum_14 imp1_dum_15 imp1_dum_16, vce(robust)
• Codes for PPML in R: Poisson Pseudo Maximum Likelihood
ppml (dependent_variable, distance, additional_regressors, robust = FALSE, data=…)
• Codes for Structural Iterated Least Squares in R
sils( dependent_variable, distance, additional_regressors = NULL, income_origin, income_destination, code_origin, code_destination, maxloop = 100,
decimal_places = 4, robust = FALSE, verbose = FALSE, data, ... )
• Codes for Bonus vetus OLS (BVU) in R
bvu( dependent_variable, distance, additional_regressors = NULL, income_origin, income_destination, code_origin, code_destination, robust = FALSE,
data, ... )
50
FIRM LEVEL ANALYSIS THROUGH GRAVITY
MODELLING AND EMPRICAL FACTS RELATED TO
FIRM LEVEL TRADE
51
52
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
60
61
62
63
64
General Equilibrium Methodology
• GTAP – E a energy environment variant of the General Equilibrium
Model
• We have used the GTAP-E with 10th version of database and the data
year is 2014 for simulation. The main feature of GTAP-E model is to
evaluate the impact of alternative climate change policies among other
policies like trade, industrial, freer capital flows and human capital
formation on economic variables and carbon emissions, among others.
65
Introduction
• GTAP E model is a computable general equilibrium model of world economy.
• The standard GTAP Model of Center for Global Trade Analysis, Purdue
University, Indiana, United States has revamped to form a CGE model containing
energy and environmental modeling
• It was revised by McDougall and Golub 2007.
• GTAP-E with 10th version of database has the data year as 2014 for simulation.
• The main feature of GTAP-E model is to evaluate the impact of alternative climate
change policies on economic and carbon emissions also.
66
• According to the Burniaux and Truong 2002,
• GTAP-E allows for inter-fuel and inter-factor substitution in the production structure of firms and
in the consumption behavior of private households and the government sector. Apart from
standard macroeconomic results, GTAP-E captures the effects arising from changes in energyenvironmental policy strategies, both in terms of economic and environmental indicators.
• Since this model is specifically designed to be used in the context of greenhouse gases (GHG)
mitigation policies which also includes modified treatment of energy demand energy-capital and
inter-fuel substitution, carbon dioxide accounting, taxation and emission trading, The major
prospective feature of the GTAP-E in existing debate on climate change is illustrated by some
illustrative simulations of the implementation of the Kyoto Protocol.
• According to the Antimiani et al 2012,
• GTAP-E represents a top-down approach of energy policy simulation because it estimates the
demand of energy inputs in terms of sectoral demand producing detailed macroeconomic
projections.
• The main change in the amended GTAP to GTAP-E is the inclusion of the possibility of energy
input substitution in production and consumption, allowing for a more detailed description of
substitution possibilities in different energy sources.
• GTAP E model has incorporated the energy substitution, both in the production and consumption
structure. The important issue of capital-energy substitutability vs. complementarily is also
explicitly considered.
67
Production Structure
• Antimiani et al 2012 states that GTAP-E model incorporates energy in the value-added nest in two different steps.
• First, energy commodities are separated into ‘electricity’ and ‘non-electricity’ groups, where a substitution elasticity (𝜎𝐸𝑁𝐸𝑅 )
operates. The following nest separates nonelectric into coal and non-coal with a specific substitution elasticity (𝜎𝑁𝐸𝐿𝑌 ) and
non-coal into gas, oil, and oil-refined products, with a specific substitution elasticity (𝜎𝑁𝐶𝑂𝐿 ).
• Secondly, energy composite is combined with capital to produce energy-capital composite to be incorporated in the valueadded nest. This production structure can be further enriched to include biofuel production (Taheripour et al. 2007) or clean
energy technologies as in the ICES model (Bosello et al. 2011).
• According to this approach, energy inputs are part of the endowment commodities owned by producers. Capital and
energy use mainly depends on the model parameters (elasticity values) and the policy simulated
• GTAP-E model incorporates energy directly in the value-added nest as compared to the standard GTAP model
which energy inputs are treated as intermediate inputs (outside the value-added nest).
• In the GTAP-E case, energy inputs are combined with capital to produce an energy-capital composite; the latter is
combined with other primary inputs in a value-added-energy nest using a CES function.
68
69
Consumption Structure
• In consumption, GTAP-E modifies both private and government consumption
whereas in standard GTAP model, private and government consumption are
separated from private savings.
• Government consumption has a Cobb-Douglas structure (with a substitution
elasticity equal to one), where energy commodities are separated from
nonenergy commodities by a nested-CES structure.
• Household private consumption follows the standard GTAP model, using the
constant-difference-of-elasticity (CDE) functional form previously described,
but in the second-level nest, the GTAP-E model further specifies the energy
composite using a CES functional form.
• A further significant change in the consumption structure is the possibility of
adding carbon tax to private expenditure, as well as to public (government)
expenditure, for goods that emit carbon dioxide when used.
70
• Lee 2002
They follow the Tier 1 method as suggested in the revised 1996 IPCC Guidelines (IPCC/OECD/IEA, 1997) to
estimate CO2 emissions, based on the GTAP energy volume data. The formula to calculate CO2 emissions is
as follows:
71
Experimental Design
• The present study analyses India’s gains and losses in three experimental scenarios:
• First scenario is when India bilaterally liberalizes with the RCEP nations on one to one basis.
✓This bilateral liberalization includes removal of bilateral tariff levels to zero, reduction in NTB
levels leading to harmonization of standards and raising of productivity of the level of 2 per cent
(assumed) and freer capital flows leading to a productivity improvement of 2 per cent, carbon
taxation of the level 2 per cent and improvement in productivity of the skilled labor along with the
promotion of transport and communication sector under the aegis of the industrial policies adopted
by the entire region. The 2 per cent technological improvement in consonance with the study done
by Barro and Sala-I-Martin (1995).
• Second scenario is the one in which India becomes part of comprehensive treaty and India
bilaterally liberalizes with all the RCEP nations along with the other RCEP nations also bilaterally
liberalizing among themselves.
✓This higher level of integration additionally includes whole gamut of policies ranging from trade
and capital liberalization, reduction in NTBs, making concentrated efforts to improve productivity
of skilled labor in the region and imposing carbon taxation to address climate change and adoption
of industrial policy for promoting transport and communications.
• In the third scenario, we evaluate the RCEP in its present form.
72
Scenario I, II, II: EV, VGDP, Carbon
Emissions and Trade Balance
Scenario III: RCEP in Present Form and its Impact
on India and ROW
Scenario II: When India becomes Part of
Comprehensive Trade Deal
Scenario I: When India Bilaterally Liberalizes with RCEP Nations
EV
Country
USA
EV
Carbon
Emissions
VGDP
Trade
Balance
EV
Carbon
Emissions
VGDP
VGDP
Carbon
Emissions
Trade
Balance
Trade Balance
-1716.4
-0.28
-0.08
-56459
-15637
-0.92
-0.15
35283.9
-12846
-0.81
-0.13
30401.98
-4969
-0.31
-0.08
11360.7
-18569
-0.81
-0.16
29384.3
-14819
-0.7
-0.15
25594.03
EEFSU
1748.41
-0.1
-0.04
11325.9
-645.42
-0.58
-0.06
2090.49
-1083.6
-0.52
-0.04
1757.41
JPN
78811.7
2.13
1.15
-14230
119176
5.06
3.96
-41482
118966
5
3.93
-41878.71
N-ZEALAND
3630.46
1.93
0.36
-260.27
5339.16
4.13
0.43
-927.7
5354.13
4.14
0.46
-940.52
AUSTRALIA
24975.4
2.14
0.07
427.24
34591.3
3.74
-0.59
-7681.1
33891.9
3.55
-0.62
-7083.7
EEx
3441.84
-0.13
-0.12
24859.1
254.81
-0.55
-0.16
5533.45
152.4
-0.47
-0.09
4834.42
CHN
158103
1.79
-1.49
59395.6
195918
2.32
-1.69
-8845.4
192886
2.25
-1.81
-5888.68
IND
34795
1.56
0.06
-13597
25074.4
0.17
-0.15
1523.52
-2376.9
-0.73
-0.05
3562.48
ROW
-1073.4
-0.25
-0.03
-18445
-14702
-0.87
-0.01
20142
-12224
-0.76
0
17723.9
ASEAN10
51257.2
2.99
-0.41
7.6
60473.5
2.7
-0.5
-8307.6
50606.3
1.7
-0.33
-5818.91
KOREA
23386.6
1.7
0.6
-4494.9
43037.9
4.5
3.32
-26802
39096.6
4.25
3.27
-22255.43
EU27
Source: Author's own simulations using GTAP –E
73
Scenario I: Sectoral Growth
Scenario I: When India Bilaterally Liberalizes with RCEP Nations
Qo
USA
EU27
EEFSU
NEWZEA
LAND
JPN
AUSTRAL
IA
EEx
CHN
IND
ROW
ASEAN10
KOREA
Land
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
UnSkLab
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
SkLab
0
0
0
2
2
2
0
2
2
0
2
2
Capital
0
0
0
2
2
2
0
2
2
0
2
2
NatRes
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
Agr
0.1
0.31
-0.02
0.96
1.17
1.29
0.14
0.74
2.98
0.22
0.69
-10.69
Coal
0.18
0.3
0.75
-3.06
5.43
2.79
0.43
-1.88
-4.86
0.5
1.7
-3.39
Oil
0.19
0.26
0.18
0.36
0.45
0.21
0.28
0.18
0.81
0.29
-0.26
-0.09
Gas
0.45
0.6
0.36
0.66
1.26
-0.22
0.43
-9.37
1.26
0.51
-2.14
-12.52
-0.15
-0.15
-0.11
1.36
0.32
0.59
-0.13
0.86
1.78
-0.11
0.43
1.07
Electricity
0.01
0.08
-0.01
1.61
2.03
1.2
-0.08
0.62
1.87
0.01
1.26
1.02
En_Int_ind
0.25
0.25
-0.09
1.22
1.82
1.27
-0.18
1.2
0.81
0.17
0.01
1.43
Oth_ind_se
r
0.01
0.03
-0.01
1.82
1.81
1.7
-0.01
1.36
1.16
0.02
2.16
1.96
Transport
-0.11
-0.07
-0.11
0.68
-0.26
-0.35
-0.21
-0.3
1.13
-0.11
-0.51
0.17
Communic
atio
-0.63
-0.71
-0.62
-0.18
0.15
-0.41
-1.04
1.84
1.86
-1.11
0.23
0.28
CGDS
-0.09
-0.19
-0.03
3.34
2.75
2.73
-0.04
1.96
3.05
-0.12
2.79
4.65
Oil_pcts
Source: Author's own simulations using GTAP –E
74
Scenario II: Sectoral Growth
Scenario II: When India becomes Part of Comprehensive Trade Deal
Qo
USA
EU27
EEFSU
NEWZEA
LAND
JPN
AUSTRAL
IA
EEx
CHN
IND
ROW
ASEAN10
KOREA
Land
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
UnSkLab
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
SkLab
0
0
0
2
2
2
0
2
2
0
2
2
Capital
0
0
0
2
2
2
0
2
2
0
2
2
NatRes
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
Agr
0.14
0.34
-0.07
-1.64
0.97
3.85
0.11
0.96
2.41
0.26
0.66
-15.02
Coal
0.49
0.63
0.91
-8.94
1.66
1.39
1.14
-2.5
-3.77
1.53
2.64
-6.43
Oil
0.4
0.41
0.31
-1.78
-1.18
-0.7
0.43
-0.47
1.33
0.54
-0.28
-2.28
Gas
0.89
0.72
0.25
-4.02
-0.52
-0.74
0.27
-11.11
2.5
0.89
-0.51
-0.72
-0.27
-0.29
-0.22
4.4
-0.94
0.25
-0.38
0.98
1.62
-0.2
-0.34
5.06
0
0.07
-0.05
2.79
1.34
0.5
-0.15
0.49
1.63
-0.06
1.12
2.33
En_Int_ind
0.62
0.35
-0.19
1.86
-1.87
-1.58
-0.35
0.59
1.16
0.22
-0.07
2.81
Oth_ind_se
r
-0.03
0.01
-0.05
1.86
2.35
2.34
-0.05
1.67
1.05
0
2.1
1.82
Transport
-0.07
-0.07
0.07
3.73
-3.39
-3.31
-0.05
-1.07
1.89
0.14
-1.24
1.15
Communic
atio
-0.48
-0.61
-0.53
-1.71
-1.55
-2.08
-0.74
1.51
2.29
-1.62
1.22
1.94
CGDS
-0.92
-0.85
-0.44
6.6
4.9
4.89
-0.48
2.85
1.77
-0.82
4.07
10.01
Oil_pcts
Electricity
Source: Author's own simulations using GTAP –E
75
Scenario III: Sectoral Growth
Scenario III: RCEP in Present Form and its Impact on India and ROW
Qo
USA
EU27
EEFSU
JPN
NEWZEALAND
AUSTRALIA
EEx
CHN
IND
ROW
ASEAN10
KOREA
Land
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
UnSkLab
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
SkLab
0
0
0
2
2
2
0
2
0
0
2
2
Capital
0
0
0
2
2
2
0
2
0
0
2
2
NatRes
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
Agr
0.25
0.3
-0.01
-1.46
1.12
3.99
0.09
1.33
0.09
0.28
0.55
-7.17
Coal
0.44
0.5
0.58
-9.51
-2.05
-0.02
0.79
-2.71
1.02
2.03
2.56
-6.72
Oil
0.34
0.33
0.25
-1.75
-1.24
-0.59
0.33
-0.44
0.39
0.44
0.38
-1.98
Gas
0.72
0.54
0.12
-3.83
-0.59
-0.33
0.06
-10.89
0.58
0.7
2.16
-0.62
-0.22
-0.25
-0.18
4.39
-0.88
0.23
-0.22
0.82
-0.23
-0.12
-0.02
4.96
0
0.08
-0.03
2.79
1.32
0.44
-0.08
0.41
-0.01
0
1.04
2.37
En_Int_ind
0.57
0.4
-0.1
1.67
-2.02
-1.73
-0.07
0.37
0.15
0.4
0.98
2.42
Oth_ind_ser
-0.02
0.03
-0.03
1.88
2.36
2.38
-0.02
1.67
-0.05
0.02
1.47
1.58
Transport
-0.11
-0.15
0.03
3.76
-3.37
-3.13
-0.09
-1.1
-0.11
0.08
-0.4
1.47
Communicatio
-0.63
-0.74
-0.61
-1.83
-1.6
-2.02
-0.97
1.57
-1.01
-1.93
3.85
2.68
CGDS
-0.79
-0.74
-0.39
6.65
4.93
4.69
-0.42
2.77
-0.52
-0.71
3.38
8.77
Oil_pcts
Electricity
Source: Author's own simulations using GTAP –E
76
Scenario I: Welfare Decomposition
WELFARE
1 co2trd
2 alloc_A1
3 endw_B1
4 tech_C1
6 tot_E1
7 IS_F1
Total
1 USA
0
-633
0
0
-534
-549
-1716
2 EU27
0
-2206
0
0
-2832
65.1
-4973
3 EEFSU
0
637
0
0
1093
18.2
1748
4 JPN
0
19830
37748
22198
-907
-56.7
78812
5 NEWZEALAND
0
952
1871
803
4.42
-0.606
3630
6 AUSTRALIA
0
6279
11732
5803
1113
47.1
24975
7 EEx
0
70.2
0
0
3300
71.7
3442
8 CHN
0
30160
61989
69558
-5114
1510
158103
0.001
8331
18682
10309
-1449
-1155
34717
10 ROW
0
-984
0
0
51.7
-142
-1074
11 ASEAN10
0
6583
23735
14490
6469
-18.4
51258
12 KOREA
0
4722
10967
8705
-1211
207
23390
0.001
73741
166724
131866
-15.7
-2.53
372312
9 IND
Total
Source: Author's own simulations using GTAP –E
77
Scenario II: Welfare Decomposition
WELFARE
1 co2trd
2 alloc_A1
3 endw_B1
4 tech_C1
6 tot_E1
7 IS_F1
Total
1 USA
0
-2521
0
0
-10487
-2629
-15636
2 EU27
0
-7349
0
0
-12057
834
-18572
3 EEFSU
0
-698
0
0
-454
507
-646
0.043
29592
38025
31327
19511
722
119177
0
1202
1882
1334
905
16.6
5339
-0.002
8895
11799
8660
5277
-39.5
34591
0
-1166
0
0
344
1077
255
8 CHN
0.024
46089
62282
86133
84.5
1332
195920
9 IND
-0.023
7913
18625
4210
-4492
-1234
25022
0
-4701
0
0
-9616
-381
-14699
0.022
7924
23863
25560
2851
276
60474
0
10168
11151
14533
7694
-503
43043
0.064
95347
167627
171756
-441
-20.5
434269
4 JPN
5 NEWZEALAND
6 AUSTRALIA
7 EEx
10 ROW
11 ASEAN10
12 KOREA
Total
Source: Author's own simulations using GTAP –E
78
Scenario III: Welfare Decomposition
WELFARE
1 co2trd
2 alloc_A1
3 endw_B1
4 tech_C1
6 tot_E1
7 IS_F1
Total
1 USA
0
-2061
0
0
-8549
-2236
-12846
2 EU27
0
-6096
0
0
-9259
536
-14818
3 EEFSU
0
-1076
0
0
-341
334
-1083
0.004
29478
38023
31137
19676
651
118966
5 NEWZEALAND
0
1202
1882
1321
937
12.1
5354
6 AUSTRALIA
0
8732
11794
8565
4860
-60.2
33892
7 EEx
0
-1009
0
0
460
701
152
-0.003
44667
62259
85630
-582
906
192881
9 IND
0
-639
0
0
-1570
-168
-2377
10 ROW
0
-3998
0
0
-7813
-414
-12225
-0.002
6998
23809
24811
-5277
264
50605
12 KOREA
0
7118
11123
14322
7064
-539
39087
Total
0
83317
148891
165786
-395
-11.1
4 JPN
8 CHN
11 ASEAN10
Source: Author's own simulations using GTAP –E
397588
79
Scenario I: Real Returns to the Factors of
Production
Scenario I: When India Bilaterally Liberalizes with RCEP Nations
Pfactreal
Land
USA
EU27
EEFSU
JPN
NEWZEALAND
AUSTRALIA
EEx
CHN
IND
ROW
ASEAN10
KOREA
0.53
1.45
-0.12
5.79
5.99
6.96
0.62
5.04
20.15
1.05
6.12
-49.42
UnSkLab
-0.03
-0.02
-0.01
1.57
1.61
1.46
-0.02
1.24
1.51
-0.04
1.8
2.52
SkLab
-0.01
-0.03
-0.01
0
-0.05
-0.02
-0.03
-0.33
-0.53
-0.05
0.23
1.31
Capital
-0.01
-0.05
-0.01
-0.01
-0.07
-0.12
-0.01
-0.55
-0.67
-0.05
-0.05
1.12
NatRes
0.68
0.85
0.64
5.14
3.69
1.6
0.9
1.96
6.65
0.91
0.8
-36.41
Source: Author's own simulations using GTAP –E
80
Scenario II: Real Returns to the Factors of
Production
Scenario II: When India becomes Part of Comprehensive Trade Deal
Pfactreal
USA
EU27
EEFSU
JPN
NEWZEALAND
AUSTRALIA
EEx
CHN
IND
ROW
ASEAN10
KOREA
Land
0.66
1.52
-0.41
-6.72
5.92
22.09
0.4
6.86
15.96
1.14
6.66
-61.14
UnSkLab
-0.1
-0.08
-0.09
2.56
2.67
2.44
-0.11
1.72
1.29
-0.17
2.54
4.78
SkLab
-0.11
-0.1
-0.1
1.03
0.93
1.02
-0.11
0.24
-0.76
-0.19
0.98
3.6
Capital
-0.1
-0.12
-0.09
1.19
0.97
0.66
-0.07
-0.01
-0.92
-0.19
0.8
3.85
NatRes
1.38
1.09
0.9
-6.46
1.21
0.69
1.25
2.03
5.94
1.53
2.11
-45.58
Source: Author's own simulations using GTAP –E
81
Scenario III: Real Returns to the Factors of
Production
pfactreal
Land
USA
EU27
EEFSU
JPN
NEWZEALAND
AUSTRALIA
EEx
CHN
IND
ROW
ASEAN10
KOREA
1.26
1.35
-0.12
-5.86
6.63
22.85
0.37
9.02
0.44
1.29
5.42
-36.17
UnSkLab
-0.09
-0.06
-0.07
2.56
2.67
2.41
-0.08
1.67
-0.14
-0.15
2.01
4.14
SkLab
-0.09
-0.07
-0.08
1.03
0.93
0.99
-0.08
0.17
-0.17
-0.16
0.45
2.79
Capital
-0.08
-0.1
-0.07
1.18
0.97
0.58
-0.05
-0.1
-0.19
-0.17
0.4
3.07
NatRes
1.17
0.92
0.7
-5.78
1.16
0.42
0.94
2.63
0.59
1.32
3.12
-27
Source: Author's own simulations using GTAP –E
82
Conclusions
• This study indicates that India gains more in terms of welfare and VGDP growth
when India bilaterally liberalizes trade with the RCEP trading nations as compared
to the scenario when India joins the RCEP trade deal either in the nascent form or
when it has a comprehensive trade deal with its expanding members.
• India needs capital flows from Japan, Korea, Australia, Singapore and other RCEP
nations and Indian capital is also needed across the ASEAN countries. India is also
connected to the RCEP nations through enhanced trade in services, transport and
communications and GVCs.
• Therefore, greater trade in agriculture, light manufacturing and meat and meat
products will bring dividends to India besides enhancing agricultural productivity
in the country. Trade liberalization with carbon taxations in the RCEP expanding
region may tackle climate change partly by reducing carbon emissions but
compromising our growth rates and consumption marginally.
83
Theoretical Understanding: International Trade
Agreements and Single Market Partial Equilibrium
Analysis
•
Trade Creation and Trade Diversion
• When trade agreements are made, the increased trade can be of two types.
1. Trade creation
•
Gain in consumer surplus for importing country due to lower prices.
•
Gain in producer surplus for exporting country due to increased sales.
welfare gains for both countries.
84
2. Trade diversion occurs when one member country imports a product from
another member country that it was previously importing from an outside
country.
•
Trade is taken away from one country and moved to another country.
•
This is not always the most efficient move since the former country might
have been producing at lower costs, but due to changes in tariffs, it ends up
cheaper to import from the member country.
85
Equations for Trade Creation and Trade
Diversion
• 𝑃𝑑 𝑔,𝑐 =𝑃𝑤 𝑔,𝑐 (1+𝑡𝑔,𝑐 )
• 𝑡𝑔,𝑐 = 𝑡𝑔𝑀𝐹𝑁 (1-𝜃𝑔,𝑐 )
• θ𝑔,𝑐 = 1-
𝑡𝑔,𝑐
𝑡 𝑀𝐹𝑁
• Total trade effect = Quantity effect + price effect
86
• Trade creation
• Trade creation is defined as the direct increase in imports
following a reduction on the tariff imposed on good g from
country c. To obtain this, SMART uses the definition of price
elasticity of import demand:
• ℇ𝑔,𝑐 =
𝑑𝑚𝑔,𝑐 /𝑚𝑔,𝑐
𝑑𝑝𝑑
𝑔,𝑐
൘𝑝 𝑑
𝑔,𝑐
• Solving for dm g ,c we obtain the trade creation (TC g ,c ) evaluated
at world prices and associated with the tariff reduction on good g
when imported from country c:
• 𝑇𝐶𝑔,𝑐 = 𝑃
𝑤
𝑔,𝑐
𝑑𝑚𝑔,𝑐 = 𝑃
𝑤
𝑑𝑡𝑔,𝑐
ℇ 𝑚
𝑔,𝑐 𝑔,𝑐 𝑔,𝑐 (1+𝑡𝑔,𝑐 )
= ℇ𝑔,𝑐 𝑚𝑔,𝑐
𝑑𝑡𝑔,𝑐
(1+𝑡𝑔,𝑐 )
87
• If the tariff reduction on good g from country c is a
preferential tariff reduction (i.e., it does not apply to
other countries, c , then imports from country), then
imports of good g from country c are further going to
increase due to the substitution away from imports of
good g from other countries that becomes relatively
more expensive. This is the definition of trade
diversion in the SMART model.
• 𝑇𝐷𝑔,𝑐 = 𝑑𝑚𝑔,𝑐 =
𝑚𝑔 ,≠𝑐 𝑚𝑔 ,𝑐
𝑑𝑡𝑔,𝑐
𝑚𝑔 ,≠𝑐 +𝑚𝑔 ,𝑐 (1+𝑡𝑔,𝑐 )
𝜎𝑔 ,𝑐 ,≠𝑐
• Where 𝜎𝑔,𝑐,≠𝑐 is the substitution elasticity .
88
Price Effect: This is a third component reported in the
Trade Total effect and occurs only with a finite export
supply elasticity assumption
Revenue effect = tariff rate * value of imports
A tariff revenue change = final tariff * final import
value - initial tariff * initial import value.
Welfare effect =CS +PS + Govt revenue
89
SMART Model
Tariff Revenue Effect
In the SMART model, change in tariff revenue can be easily calculated using the following formula:
𝑑𝑇𝑅𝑖 = 𝑇𝑅𝑖1 − 𝑇𝑅𝑖0 … (3.24)
0
𝑤
0
𝑇𝑅𝑖0 = ෍ 𝑡𝑘,𝑗
𝑝𝑘,𝑗
𝑚𝑘,𝑗
… (3.24𝐴)
𝑘
𝑤
1
𝑇𝑅𝑖1 = ෍ 𝑡𝑘,𝑗
𝑝𝑘,𝑗
𝑚1𝑘,𝑗
… 3.24𝐵
𝑘
0
1
Where, 𝑇𝑅𝑖0 and 𝑇𝑅𝑖1 are the total tariff revenues incurred by the importing country (i) before and after the change in trade policy; 𝑡𝑘,𝑗
and 𝑡𝑘,𝑗
are the tariff rates
𝑤
0
𝑤
before and after trade policy shock; and 𝑝𝑘,𝑗
𝑚𝑘,𝑗
and 𝑝𝑘,𝑗
𝑚1𝑘,𝑗 are the value of imports before and after the trade policy change at world prices.
Welfare Effect
The net welfare effect is estimated by multiplying the change in imports with the average between the incidence of tariff barriers before and after their change (Laird
and Yeats, 1986).
𝑤𝑘,𝑖
0
1
(𝑡𝑘,𝑗
+ 𝑡𝑘,𝑗
)
𝑑𝑚𝑘,𝑗 ×
2
=
… (3.25)
100
Generally, welfare effect is defined as the sum of producer and consumer surplus in the economy due to the adoption of tariff reduction policy. With the infinite
export supply elasticity, the whole welfare effect is composed of consumer surplus only, which arises because of decrease in price of imported product with the
reduction of tariffs on that product. However, with less than infinite export supply elasticity, one can calculate the producer surplus existed in the exporting country
90
due to increment in the world price of imports due to increment in demand for imported product.
Ukraine Russia War and India: A General
Equilibrium Analysis
• How does the war between Ukraine and Russia affects us? We use the General equilibrium model GTAP 10 to include all
simulations to restrict trade, capital, natural resource flows to Russia and Ukraine including displacement of skilled and
unskilled labour from Ukraine to EU 28. The simulations include the impact of restricted transport and communications,
restricted trade in services links and restricted flow of natural resource and extraction products between India and Russia
due to the impact of the war and the sanctions imposed by the west on Russia.Indias welfare becomes negative 6000
million us dollars with negative .83 vgdp growth rates. The sector which gets impacted the most negatively in India are the
extraction sector and public utilities like gas, water and construction along with domestic investments. Russian and
Ukrainian economy also gets impacted drastically over the years with negative 4 percent growth rates. EU gains in terms of
welfare and vgdp growth rates because of the displacement of labour from Ukraine. Oceania, MENA and SSA gains in
terms of vgdp growth and welfare due to diversion of natural resource intensive trade from Russia to natural resource rich
countries. India imports from Russia coal, oils, diamonds, newsprint, fertilizer, vegetable oil, asbestos among others. India
exports to Russia telephones for cellular networks,medicaments, fish, tobacco, coffee, meat,fruits and grapes. Ukraine
trade with Russia would be highly restricted as well. Ukraine exports to Russia ,aluminium oxide,iron ore, railway
locomotives, uranium , coal , titanium ores among others. Russia exports to Ukraine include petroleum oil, coal, ammonia
anhydrous, fuel elements like cartridges, fertilizers, medicaments, coke and semi coke, among others. India may have
abstained from voting against Russia in the UN but geopolitical reality is pushing it towards the west. Severing transport
and service links between India and Russia may be the fallout of the war and the sanctions. Sanctions ,however take a
while to have its full impact. Surely oil prices have gone beyond 105 us dollars a barrel and gas availability has been
restricted with substitution happening across countries. MENA, SSA , EU and Oceania are the major gainers of this
imbroglio. EU only because of the displacement of labour both skilled and unskilled from Ukraine. Otherwise EU 28 also
witnesses negative growth
91
Russian Sanctions
• The sanctions on Russia whether it is increase in tariff and non tariff barriers or embargo on extraction
industries like fishing, coal, oil and gas exploration or barriers on trade in services and manufacturing has
negative welfare and brings vgdp loss for the EU 28 and India. Russians will suffer the most in terms of vgdp
loss exceeding negative 4.94 if tariff and non tariff barriers are raised in agriculture and allied activities
including extraction with negative output oriented technological progress in light and heavy manufacturing.
The vgdp loss is less of negative 4.34 percent if tariff and non tariff barriers are raised with negative output
oriented technological progress in extraction . Then comes negative loss of vgdp reaching negative 3.93 if
output oriented technological progress becomes negative in services, transport and communications and
public utilities like electricity, gas manufacturing and distribution, water and electricity. Sanctions in
agriculture and allied activities has the least impact on the Russian economy. Services sector sanctions
though bring maximum welfare loss of 74 billion US dollars in Russia. If sanctions are imposed on all sectors
Russian economy will suffer a loss of negative 7.35 percent with 113 billion US dollars as welfare loss. All
trade policy instruments and embargo have differential impacts. MENA and SSA regions gain while EU 28
and India loose in terms of welfare and vgdp loss due to these developments. Sanctions seems to favour real
returns to land and natural resource in Russia indicating that Russia will divert it's energy trade to South
Asia, Oceania, MENA and Sub Saharan African countries. Unskilled labour, skilled labour and investments will
suffer in Russia pulling down it's growth rates. We use GTAP 10 and GTAP Energy Environment variant of the
General equilibrium models for our analysis.
92
The Economic Impact of Sanctions : A General Equilibrium Analysis with impacts on Carbon Emissions
• It is technological blockade in industry and services rather than sanctions on gas production , exports and
distribution with tariff escalation on energy intensive industries and industry and services which brings
negative vgdp growth in Russia at the level of nearly 3 percent in Russia. The trade gets diverted to land
intensive and natural resource intensive products from Russia which improves upon its trade balance with
the Rest of world putting pressure on its currency to appreciate than the expectation that the rouble will
depreciate. We use energy environment variant of the General Equilibrium model GTAP E for our analysis.
Any sanction on gas production , exports and technological blockade brings negative vgdp growth of 2.50
percent growth in Russia but a larger fall in welfare reaching negative 44 billion US dollars. Technological
blockade with tariff escalation in coal, oil and petroleum in Russia surprisingly brings positive welfare growth
in Russia with negative vgdp growth not exceeding 2 percent in Russia. Trade diversion is surely happening
with India and EU27 gaining with sanctions according to GTAP E model if the sanctions are imposed in all
sectors, agriculture, industry and services, energy intensive industries, coal, oil, petroleum, petroleum,
electricity, among others. The Russian economy welfare and vgdp growth would be negative. Vgdp loss
would be nearly 5 percent with comprehensive sanctions. All embargo and trade policy instruments have
beggar by thy impacts. Some economies grow at the cost of Russian economy. Inter fuel substitution
happens with sanctions but agriculture, land and natural resource real returns gains with sanctions in Russia.
EU 27 gains maybe because of migration of Ukrainian skilled and unskilled labour because of the War.The
carbon emissions growth rates become negative due to sanctions.
93
Covid Impact using General Equilibrium
Modelling
• How did covid and covid lockdowns impact the Indian economy since 2020. We use GTAP 10
general equilibrium model to study the economy wide impact of various shocks that occurred
to covid and grand lockdown policies adopted in India. Simulations include negative
spillover on the shipping industry, negative impact of disruptions in global value chains
added processes, decline in endowments of skilled and unskilled labour due to covid
reduction in outputs of manufacturing industries and negative impacts on public works
transportation with positive impact on business services and communications. The covid
also had negative impact on the production processes in India..Tourism were also
negatively. We find from our comprehensive simulations massive 8.90 fall in vgdp in India
welfare loss of 138 billion us dollars. Public utilities, domestic investments,
and heavy manufacturing saw massive fall in outputs and value added.Real returns to
unskilled labour and capital were impacted negatively the most. Land real returns were
negatively but an amount less than the other factors of production. Returns to Natural
were impacted positively. Carbon emissions went down with rise in energy inputs like
and energy intensive products in India due to covid. Financial package equivalent to 15
our 200 lakh crore GDP and Ukrainian Russian war may have had differential impacts on
welfare in India.
94
CPTPP vs RCEP using General
Equilibrium Modelling

Should India align with the 15 nation's RCEP with which it has relatively higher 185 billion trade or and with
11 nations CPTPP with which it has lesser 70, billion trade in agriculture, industrial products and petroleum
? It will depend on India's engagement with the mega blocks who agree on having deeper integration
clauses along with adoption of atmanirbhar policies in india promoting innovation in manufacturing and
transport and communications and member states promoting global value chains in the region . We
construct three simulation scenarios . First, when India seperately has deeper integration relations with
RCEP and CPTPP in the form of tariff and non tariff liberalization, freer movement of capital, skilled labour
and endowment enhancement of natural capital, with global value chains enhancing technological
progress and output oriented technological progress in manufacturing and transport and communications.
This is the best scenario for india irrespective of whether India joins CPTPP or RCEP, in terms of welfare
hovering 110, billion US dollars to 117 billion US dollars with vgdp growth beyond 5 percent in all scenarios .
Other scenarios of deeper integration clauses mentioned above with adoption of common industrial
policies of having output oriented technological progress in manufacturing in all member nations and
having free trade with either RCEP and CPTPP , brings relatively lower welfare and vgdp growth in india.
CPTPP 7, common members of RCEP and CPTPP, comprising of Australia, New Zealand, Vietnam, Brunei,
Singapore , Japan and Malaysia are impacted more or less same whether they are part of RCEP or CPTPP by
deeper integration policies. CPTPP4, the other nations in eleven member alliance, comprising of Canada,
Mexico, Peru and Chile and RCEP8 are impacted negatively when India aligns with RCEP and CPTPP
respectively. All factors gain in this deeper integration alignment except real returns to natural capital. We
have the highest average tariff imposed on CPTPP7 tuning to level of 22 percent while for RCEP8 nation's
product we impose on an average 20 percent tariff rates. We protect our grains crops and processed food
sectors the most with tariffs reaching 70 percent for edible oil, palm oil and dairy products being imported
from the two mega blocks.
95
Engagements with China

It is said if one wishes to look east it is inevitable that one would need to align with China.
Why is it then all GTAP simulations show that India China, Pak China, ASEAN china or RCEP
deal has negative welfare for India, Pakistan and ASEAN 10 respectively.China gains in all the
alignments. This is happening despite all South Asian and east Asian countries including
Oceania major imports come from China. Of course South Asia exports reach more to the
west, east Asian countries are more linked in their exports and imports and investments with
China. GVCs in South Asia can be linked to textile production where in inputs are provided by
China. Maybe if one looks at tariff structure we may have some answers. Bangladesh highest
tariff rates 165 percent, India 44 percent, Pakistan 65 percent, SL 29 percent, China 7
percent, Japan 5 percent, Indonesia 36 percent but all other ASEAN nations with average 25
percent.Meaning with reduction in tariffs in home country having relatively higher tariffs,
consumers gain, producers loose, loss of government revenue, loss in returns to factors
intensive in production of good whose tariff had come down, loss in terms of terms of trade
and possibly trade balance , investment and savings and marginal net effect on GDPs. On the
other hand tariff reduction in home country provides trade to partners and substantial
improvement in GDP via trade and higher investments and savings. I think we need to invest
outside in terms of telecommunications, ports, build roads and have physical connectivity
and village development with investment in 4IR technology to shift comparative advantage in
our favour. Strategic industrial policy may be the answer keeping that protectionism needs to
be kept at check.
96
SAARC

A comprehensive SAARC agreement between India and other South Asian countries can bring welfare gain of more
than 187 billion us dollars and vgdp growth of more than 4,90 percent for other South Asian countries except India.
We use GTAP 10 model to evaluate a comprehensive economic partnership between India and other South Asian
countries and among other South Asian countries including tariff and non tariff Liberalization between and among
South Asian partners and freer flow of capital and skilled labour mvement from India flowing into other South Asian
countries with promotion of common industrial policy by focusing on manufacturing sector in the other South Asian
countries. India witnesses welfare gain of more than 300 billion us dollars with more than 1.90 percent vgdp
growth. The SAARC where in intra trade is mere 5 percent of its world trade bring more dividends to other South
Asian countries with all sectors uniformly growing due to comprehensive agreement with India where in India plays a
major rule in promoting skills, export of manufacturing and provisioning outward capital. The vgdp growth of India
reaches more than 6 percent if in addition to comprehensive agreement ,we invite skilled labour from abroad and
provide output oriented TFP growth of manufacturing sector of India. Industrial policy adoption with skilled labour
enhancement helps India grow at record faster rates with comprehensive alignment with other South Asian
countries.Political climate and geopolitical realities with geoeconomics should drive India to align more with its
neighbours. India protects mostly processed food and grains and crops while other South Asian countries
protect their manufacturing sector in terms of tariffs .We impose on an average 6 percent tariffs on products coming
from other South Asian countries with extraction and grain crops being taxed at 13 percent with lowest tariffs of
merely 2 percent on manufacturing exports from other South Asian countries. The other South Asian countries
average tariffs on Indian products are 8.57 percent with extraction being taxed at 12.29 percent and textiles at 9.36
percent. Light and heavy manufacturing are taxed on an average at 7 percent by other South Asian countries. The
other South Asian countries average tariffs among themselves are merely 8 percent on an average with relatively
higher tariffs for textiles at 13.41 percent, heavy manufacturing at 9.79 percent and grains and crops at 8.07
97
percent.
Quality of Inputs and Input Oriented
Technological Progress

If we improve upon the quality of inputs in India by bringing in input augementing technological progress in capital, energy
inputs like coal, crude oil, petroleum, natural gas and electricity, augement unskilled labour, skilled labour, land and natural
resource in that serial order of inputs then the welfare and vgdp also grows in that order except for energy inputs where in
introduction of technology in energy inputs bring in maximum vgdp growth of 1.05 percent in india with second highest welfare
increase of 15 billion US dollars after capital augementing technological progress bringing in maximum welfare of 18 billion US
dollars with nearly one percent vgdp growth. Input augementing technological progress in our profession is best understood as
in with lesser inputs if we can produce the same output or with same inputs we can produce more. Surely like 4IR technologies
it has impact on unemployment in the economy. These are results from the general equilibrium models like GTAP 10 and GTAP
E by assuming two percent technology upgrading input policy. Unskilled labour augementing technological progress or training
of workers bring in 11 billion US dollars welfare gain in India, the third highest, but vgdp growth of nearly 0.50 percent vgdp
growth. Skilled labour biased technological progress, land biased and natural resource biased technological progress bring in
lesser welfare and vgdp changes in relative sense. The latter is a surprising result we get from the GTAP E model simulation
results. If we add in structural issue of unemployment in the simulation all our results of positive welfare and vgdp changes
turn into negative figures. We then do one set of simulation results where in we bring in technological progress in all inputs
together, that is, augement capital, energy, unskilled labour,skilled labour, land and natural resource by 2 percent together ,
the resultant welfare increase is 54 billion US dollars with more than 3 percent vgdp growth in India. The interesting part is
that the unemployment situation gets resolved by introduction of input augementing technological progress in all inputs to an
extend that vgdp and welfare have marginal increment despite the structural presence of unemployment. The real returns to
factors especially land and natural resource witnesses a spike due to the introduction of input augementing technological
progress. It is capital, energy and unskilled labour augementing technological progress which brings in maximum welfare and
vgdp growth in India followed by skilled labour, land and then natural resource. What about other nations like China, US and
Japan. We again find capital augementing technological progress contributing relatively more to welfare with figures much
higher in comparison to India. However, our energy augementing technological progress bring in relatively the highest vgdp
growth rates in comparison to the US and China.
98
India Oceania Trade agreements

Any India Oceania nation's trade agreement should contain deeper integration clauses to
make it work in favour of India's interest in promoting welfare and vgdp growth in india. The
GTAP simulations show that comprehensive agreement between India and Oceania need to go
beyond tariff and non tariff liberalization and freer movement of endowments between
member nations and introduce input and output oriented technological progress in mining
and extraction and transport and communications and enhance value added processes to
bring positive welfare and vgdp growth in india exceeding those in the Oceania nation's. The
unemployment closure in India are part of the simulations allowing prices of factors like
skilled and unskilled labour to be exogenous while endowment of labour to be endogenous
variable in india. The welfare and vgdp growth in india reaches 162 billion US dollars with
more than 7 percent vgdp growth in india after introducing deeper integration policies of
output and input oriented technological progress in extraction and mining and transport and
communications and enhancing value added in the model over and above tariff and non tariff
liberalization with movement of capital and labour inflows in the nation. A base line scenario
with no deeper integration clause always favour the Oceania nation's with India's welfare and
vgdp growth becoming negative due to the alignment. Only deeper integration helps india
while Australia welfare also reaches 77 billion US dollars with 6.1 percent vgdp growth. All
our factors gain with deeper integration in respect of base line scenario of tariff and non
tariff liberalization with movement of capital and labour flows. In the latter land and natural
resource looses in India in terms of real returns to factors of production.
99
Unemployment Slacks

How does unemployment closure get added in the general equilibrium models
GTAP 10 and GTAP E. This is done by swapping the exogenous qo quantity
output of skilled and unskilled labour for a region by making the same as
endogenous and real returns to factors of production as exogenous allowing
the latter to change exogenously. If one wants the endowments market to
clear and yet want real returns to be exogenous then endowment slack needs
to be introduced. The impact of india unemployment closure is reduction in
welfare , vgdp and trade while an increase in trade deficit for India if India
participates in a free trade area with the indo Pacific alliance nation's. The
swapping code needs to be written below rest of endogenous statement in the
closures of the rungtap window interface with gempack computer language.
100
Russian Far Eastern Alliance

What are the benefits for India by aligning with the Russian led far eastern economic forum comprising of
Russia, ASEAN 10 nations, Iran,Afghanistan, Eurasian nation's Belarus, Kazakhstan and Armenia, further
including China, Mongolia, Japan, Korea,Oceania nation's Australia and New Zealand and other east Asian
countries?. We use GTAP 10 general equilibrium model to simulate the impact of implementing the deeper
integration policies among the member states on economy wide variables in india and collectively among
the broader alliance nation's. The deeper integration policies include tariff and non tariff liberalization with
endowment increases in natural resource and capital, natural resource input augementing technological
progress in india and in the Russian led regional member countries , output oriented technological progress
in extraction and mining and in sectors like grains and crops and adoption of new shipping technologies
connecting shipping routes from Vladivostok ,Russia to Chennai in India. We have a welfare gain of 45 billion
US dollars while the Russian led far eastern region gains 292 billion US dollars as welfare gain from adopting
common deeper integration policies. Our vgdp growth is more than 3 percent while for the far eastern
forum the vgdp growth reaches nearly 2 percent. This engagement of India in securing economic, political
and security interests brings dividends to real returns to Indian capital, skilled labour and unskilled labour.
Real Returns to natural capital, though surprisingly becomes negative in the entire region including india.
India seems to gain from foreign engagements if it pursues common industrial policy further to augement
trade policy actions and by specifically focussing on enhancing output oriented technological progress in
manufacturing and transport and communication. The alignment with 45 indo Pacific nation's, 27 EU
nation's, African 54 nation's economic union , or 11 nation CPTPP nation's and more importantly liberalizing
multilaterally brings higher overall gains for India. Lot of investments and trade in extraction, light and
heavy manufacturing get a boost due to the deeper alignment with the Russian led far eastern region.. The
region which gets impacted negatively the most with far eastern union are the 27 nation's EU member
countries.
101
India Shanghai Cooperation

India Shanghai cooperation organization free trade area with only bilateral tariff and non tariff liberalization among 8
members, additional 4 observer countries and 6 dialogue partners and India brings relatively higher welfare and vgdp growth
among SCO7 members with welfare reaching 137 billion US dollars in the region and nearly 1.50 percent vgdp growth. India's
and SCO observer and dialogue partners welfare hovers nearly 27 billion US dollars with growth less than 1.50 percent vgdp
growth.It seems that SCO8 is a military, political and economic alliance comprising of india, China, Pakistan, Russia,
Uzbekistan, Tajikistan, Kazakhstan and Kyrgyzstan. Energy and Transport and communication and connectivity are sectors that
are of immense interest to India. The four observer. Countries in the SCO are Afghanistan, Iran, Belarus and Mongolia. The 6
dialogue partners are Armenia, Azerbaijan, Sri Lanka, Nepal, Cambodia and Turkey. We build in our simulations of the GTAP 10
model besides tariff and non tariff liberalization, endowment increase of natural resource in all member nations due to
possible deeper alignment of the agreement, natural resource enhancing technological progress as factor input augementing
technological progress and adoption of common industrial policy of promoting output oriented technological progress in
manufacturing and transport and communication in the entire Eurasian region including India. The vgdp growth of india reaches
more than 5 percent , the highest among all other 7 SCO members and rest of dialogue members and observer countries. The
welfare of India jumps to 67 billion US dollars but not the figure for SCO7 where in welfare reaches more than 400 billion US
dollars with adoption of deeper integration and common industrial policies. The returns to all factors in the region including in
India increases except for real returns to natural capital. The endowment increase of natural resource decreases real returns
violating the Rybczynski theorem linking endowments with factor supplies in the long run with assumption of no impact on
returns to factors. Trade in heavy manufacturing,textiles, transport and communications, other services and extraction and
mining go up in the region. Domestic investments prop up growth rates due to adoption of deeper integration policies including
pursuing common industrial policies across the member states including that in India. India tends to protect the following
sectors by imposing relatively higher tariffs on SCO7 exports of grains and crops, meat and meat products and processed food
to India. SCO7 imposes the highest tariff of 17 percent on Indian exports of meat and meat products. SCO7 tend to protect its
textiles and heavy manufacturing while trading with its dialogue and observer partners. It is SCO7 welfare and vgdp growth
rates who are maximum gainers of the indo sco trade agreement. India's route to central Asia can cater to its energy and
natural resource needs and adapt to Neo geopolitical alignment with China and Pakistan also as important discussant member
states along with the Eurasian region. Further gains are possible if Indian capital gets invested in the central Asian region.
America's, MENA and other resource rich region SSA gets impacted negatively in terms of welfare and vgdp growth.
102
Carbon Emissions

What if all countries mimics India's growth story and adopts common industrial policy by making
concerted attempts to have 8 percent output oriented technical progress in services sector, 4
percent in industry and 2 percent output oriented growth of agriculture and allied sectors including
meat and meat products and processed food?GTAP E General equilibrium model results show that
Japan, followed by US, then EU 27, then china and finally India will have relatively high growth
rates in that serial order. Carbon emissions also follow the same order with India and China having
the least growth in carbon emissions not exceeding 2.5 percent . What is to be noted that services
sector is the major carbon emitter followed by industry and then agriculture. Services include
transport and communications, public utilities like electricity, gas, construction and other services
including business and financial services. Trade liberalization and carbon taxation can partly take
care of climate change . Therefore, it seems innovation, common long term industrial policies of
promoting research and development
and trade liberalization are inputs to sustainable
development processes across nation's. Chinese and Indian carbon emissions growth rates do not
exceed 2.5 percent, while for Japan, US and EU27 carbon emission growth rates exceed 6.5 percent
when all adopt innovations mimicking tfp process of India. Carbon taxation rates can be 10 percent
to have negative carbon emission growth rates across developed nations and for incentivising
countries for substituting traditional energy resources into renewables and bio fuels. Scarcity of
natural capital is the major constraint to the innovation and development processes all around with
capital, skilled labour and unskilled labour gaining due to the adoption of self reliance policies with
trade and fdi liberalization.
103
India EU 28

India EU 28 comprehensive trade partnership would raise growth rates in India by nearly 3 percent and welfare levels by 50 billion US
dollars. EU 28 growth rates would go up by 1.13 percent while welfare levels would go up by whopping number 230 billion US dollars by
having one comprehensive deal with India. These are estimates of the general equilibrium GTAP 10 simulation model which also reads into
the fact that returns to natural capital for EU would grow by nearly 8 percent by aligning with India. The latter seems to suggest that either
scarcity is pulling up the rates in the EU, or the stolper Samuelson impact is playing its role where in by pushing one natural resource
intensive sector leads to rise in real returns for natural capital, or India a natural resource scarce country is fulfilling the energy needs and
requirements of the EU28 . The latter cannot happen. Therefore, all GTAP simulations show that if EU aligns with East Asia it would have
more relative gains in terms of welfare and vgdp growth. However, the alignment with EU will help India to liberalize in terms of tariffs and
non tariff barriers, invite foreign capital and address carbon emissions through carbon taxation and trade liberalization. India imposes on an
average 75 percent duties on processed food imports from the EU. We have very high tariff duties on vegetable oils, dairy products, food
products, beverages and tobacco products from the EU. We impose heavy tariffs on grains and crops from EU at the level of 17 percent
from the EU. EU maximum tariff rates are for indian textiles but not exceeding 8 percent. The global value chain requirements of the EU
are in motor vehicles, chemicals, machinery, food and processing, computer and electronic equipment, among others.EU helps other
nations like Netherlands and Ireland in their countries exports of other business services. EU has maximum forward linkages in chemicals,
wholesale trade, machinery and motor vehicles. The GVC requirements of the EU are met by the US, Germany, China, UK and Netherlands.
Is India in a position to replace EU GVC partners? This is an open question. We need to bring our average tariffs of 16 percent on EU imports
to lower levels, reduce non tariff barriers, invite foreign capital, address climate change, promote skill labour and human capital formation
and promote our textiles& domestic investments and expand public utilities like electricity, water, gas and construction. We need to focus
now on 5 Es. Electrical products, Engineering products, Electronic, Energy and Environment. After covid Health as well.The next set of
results based on GTAP 10 would tell us that by having comprehensive treaties based on multilateralism gives us more benefit or rather by
aligning regionally or bilaterally. MENA and SSA regions, ASEAN or other South Asian region gives us potential big markets to meet our energy
needs and expand our exports of manufacturing and hence higher relative growth rates. If we have comprehensive agreement with other
South Asian countries and build on improving the political climate all around , we can grow at more than 5 percent. However, such growth
will be sourced through our energy needs , public utilities and manufacturing exports to our neighbours.South Asian partners would have
lower growth rates and welfare, but their all sectors would grow uniformly. By aligning with ASEAN nations, we expect to grow by more
than 4 percent. In all the simulations it is quiet clear our growth in real returns to natural capital becomes negative.Meaning, we have
104
scarcity in coal, oil, petroleum, gas, extraction, mining among others. We can tide the latter by inviting capital and natural resource
technologies from Oceania,MENA, South Asian partners and ASEAN nations.Alternatively, we can invest heavily in alternative energy
resources .
India China African Union

Who gains more, India or China or 54 nations African countries if we and Chinese have comprehensive bilateral Liberalization
with the 54 nations African Comprehensive Free Trade Area? We use the General Equilibrium models GTAP 10 and an
environment energy variant of the GTAP model GTAP E for our analysis. The Indians have the maximum relative gains in terms
of welfare and vgdp growth by aligning with AFCFTA.The welfare gains are between 65 billion to 110 billion us dollars
depending on comprehensive nature of alignment with vgdp growth exceeding 5 percent in India with possible comprehensive
alignment in future. Also, their seems to be more gains in terms of welfare and vgdp growth of the African nations if they align
with the Indians rather than the Chinese.. The downside for Africans nations are land and natural resource intensive products
gets exported to India and China with supporting inflow of capital, skilled labour and technology of natural resource extraction
coming from China and India. Chinese capital seems to bring their own labour having downside impact on manufacturing
processes in Africa. Our capital is more salubrious. Therefore, AFCFTA as standalone can succeed if among 54 nations they can
promote manufacturing and textiles production in their nation states. Our simulations take a comprehensive scenario where in
we liberalize tariff and non tariff Liberalization with Freer flows of capital and skilled labour and having common industrial
policy across countries with concerted attempts made to promote manufacturing sector in the 54 nations African region. All
sectors in Africa grows if they align with India, while If they have comprehensive treaty with the Chinese, manufacturing sector
in Africa gets impacted negatively or sees a tardy progress. Chinese alignment also brings 111 billion us dollars gain for China
but skewed impact on African manufacturing sector with relatively lower vgdp growth in China in comparison with India.
Carbon emissions go up but can be taken care by carbon taxation all around. Our average tariffs on AfCFtA are below 10
percent while AFCFTA tariffs on Indian products exceeds 13 percent. We impose higher tariffs on AFCFTA textiles and
processed food of the level of 26 and 10 percent , while AfCFTA tariffs are around 18 percent for our textiles and processed
food products. AfCFTA welfare and vgdp growth rates are relatively lower when they align with India and China but matches
these countries if AFCFTA standalone can promote manufacturing sector in the 54 nations member states. Returns to natural
capital and land though becomes negative in India and China with bilateral liberalization with the 54 nations AfCFTA.
105
India Nafta

We do comprehensive analysis of India North America Free trade area comprehensive pact using Purdue University GTAP 10
general equilibrium model and use of UNESCAP TINA and RiVA trade intelligence networks . The sectors which are likely to
grow in India with the possible comprehensive agreement are services sector in India namely financial and other business
services, probably replacing Ireland and Luxembourg in Europe as users of NAFTA other business and financial services. The
other sectors which are likely to grow in India are metals, chemicals, motor vehicles, transport equipments, manufacturing,
leather, wood products, printing and publishing among others. NAFTA global value chains are read by its forward and backward
linkages in other business services, chemicals, wholesale trade, mining, financial services, motor vehicles, computers and
computer equipments, machinery, other transport equipment, among others. These GVC relationships are presently catered by
the Europeans,china and japan and NAFTA member states.The GTAP model shows that if we have tariff and non tariff
Liberalization, freer flows of capital and skilled labour movements between NAFTA and India and have common industrial policy
to promote light manufacturing and other business services in both regions, NAFTA would grow by nearly 1.91 percent with 238
billion welfare gains and India will have 2.91 growth with 58 billion welfare gain. The major source of welfare gain is the
technological progress which will see a rise due to the possible agreement in the future.The above performances with respect
to welfare changes maybe due to the fact that tariffs imposed by India on US products are on average 16 percent ,while
US average tariffs on Indian products are merely 2 percent. We impose 32 percent duties on grains and crops coming from US
with 50 percent tariffs on processed food from US. Maximum duties that US imposes on us is on textiles and garments of the
level of 8 percent. We impose 10 percent, 8 percent, and 7 percent duties on US textiles, light manufacturing and heavy
manufacturing respectively from the US. We export to US, diamonds, medicaments,fish,petroleum oil, jewellery, bed linen,
kitchen and toilet linen, among others. We import from the US oils, petroleum oils, turbo jets, metals, petroleum gases and
other gaseous hydrocarbons, nuts, almonds, media products, cotton, acyclic hydrocarbons, among others. We are hoping that
we can be valuable partners in supply chain management of the US, Canadian and Mexicans economies in sectors like Motor
vehicles, other transport equipment, chemicals,fuels, machinery, other business services, wholesale trade, computer and
electronic equipments, among others. GTAP models shows that extraction sector and domestic investments will pull up growth
in the NAFTA region with the pact. NAFTA however gains the most if it aligns with the East Asian economies like China, Japan,
Korea , ASEAN nations ,among others because it majorily needs energy inputs and outputs and agricultural inputs from these
nations. Returns to natural resource in both regions though becomes negative by the comprehensive agreement. Our
Land,skilled labour, unskilled labour and capital gains by this agreement.Textile sector in India would see a major push due to
the comprehensive agreement.
106
India UK

India UK comprehensive trade treaty will favour UK more than India in terms of welfare and vgdp growth. We use GTAP 10
Energy Environment general equilibrium model ,a variant of the GTAP model to simulate and understand economy wide impact
of UK India trade deal including impacts on carbon emissions in both nations. We include in our simulations tariff and non tariff
Liberalization on all goods both ways with freer movement of capital and skilled labour flows across both nations with
concerted attempts to promote trade in services in both nations including promotion of financial, education , health and
business services trade happening between UK and India. India's welfare gain is more than 85 billion us dollars while UK gains
more than 192 billion US dollars as welfare gain. VGDP growth for UK is more than 7 percent ,while for India vgdp growth is
more than 3 percent due to comprehensive trade deal. All sectors in India grows with services and domestic investments pulling
up growth in India. For UK domestic investments of more than 18 percent and services growth pulls up vgdp growth of more
than 7 percent in the UK. In UK all sectors grow except industry and energy intensive products like pharmaceuticals,
chemicals, minerals and metals. Energy intensive exporters gain from the comprehensive deal between India and UK, while US
and EU are nations and region which witnesses a fall in welfare and growth. UKs Global value chains are met by European
nations , US and China in products like business and financial services, chemicals, wholesale trade, mining, motor vehicles,
machinery, other transport equipments, among others. UK exports to India includes metals, silver, turbo jets, petroleum, coke,
ferrous waste and scrap, diamonds, aluminium waste and scrap, inorganic and organic compounds, paper and paper waste and
scrap, whiskies, among others. India exports to the UK petroleum oil, medicaments, jewellery, t shirts, turbo jet parts,
garments, footwear, aircraft and spacecraft parts, diamonds, among others. India imposes on an average 10 percent tariffs on
UK exports of industrial products, 123 percent tariffs on UK exports of grains, vegetables and processed food to India, not more
than 5 percent tariffs on UK exports of energy inputs and output exports to India. Correspondingly UK tariffs on Indian products
are 4.25 percent on Indian industry exports, mere 5.2 percent on indian agricultural exports, and still lower tariffs on energy
intensive exports from India. Carbon taxation of 3 percent and 5 percent in India and UK respectively can reduce carbon
emissions in both India and UK respectively with little compromise on growth and welfare in UK and India. Skilled labour gains
the most in India among other factors. In UK land gains the most while natural capital looses in the UK. For India, it is a win win
situation with all sectors growing with vgdp growth and welfare gain but much lower than the UK economy. UK gains more by
this comprehensive deal with skewed impact on industry and energy in the UK. Maybe UK then needs to build alliance with
energy exporters from middle East and North Africa, Oceania, East asian and Latin American region.
107
India GCC

GTAP10 simulations. What happens if India has free trade both ways with the GCC six Nations,
UAE, Saudi, Qatar,Oman,Kuwait and Bahrain. India would have maximum gains among the
trading group in relation with welfare changes of the level of 2250 million us dollars, followed
by UAE and then Qatar. East Asian nations, Kuwait and EU, among others would loose in terms
of negative welfare changes.UAE followed by Qatar and then India in that serial order would
gain in terms of value GDP changes. India and UAE would though have negative trade balance
with the rest of the world post free trade scenario. Saudi Arabia would have maximum
positive trade balance with the rest of the world post FTA of GCC with India .In india sectors
which would gain would be meat and meat products, processed food and light manufacturing.
Textile would not gain much. Transport and Communication and utilities would also benefit in
India. The fact though remains that maximum gains for India are when India liberalizes with
all nations , followed by ASEAN 10, RCEP, Indo Pacific, CPTPP, MENA, EU 27 , SCO and then
followed by individual nations like US, UK, among others. Where should GCC look for
maximum gains, EU28, East asia, China or other MENA countries. It seems East Asia alignment
would give them relatively maximum gains. Bahrain though has maximum gains in terms of
GDP when GCC aligns with MENA nations. Saudi Arabia, Qatar, Kuwait gain more when aligning
with EU and North American nations.
108
109
110
U S C H IN A T R A D E W A R
Analysis of US China Trade War and form ation of possible Free trade area am ong them selves using GTAP 10 m odel gives som e interesting results. The welfare
and vgdp gains for China relatively becom e higher than US if at som e point of tim e China and US form a free trade area. The Chinese welfare gains reaches
more than 15000 million US dollars with vgdp growth of 0. 40 percent while US attains welfare gain of 8000 million US dollars with vgdp growth of 0. 17
percent.
The average tariffs that US imposes on all chinese products is 2 percent while the average tariffs that China imposes on all the US products is 6 percent. If due to
to trade war the average tariffs on each other's products reaches say 25 percent ,China and US welfare and vgdp are impacted drastically downward with
China being relatively impacted more by the trade war strategy undertaken atleast by the US to curb it's heavy trade deficit with China. Trade war or bilateral
imposition of higher tariffs though leads to improvement in trade balances of both the nations, US and China .
Countries and regions which gain in terms of welfare and vgdp due to trade war are Canada, Mexico, EU 28, Latin Americans, East Asian regions copiously while
while India marginally. I guess the realignment of exchange rates are better ways to handle the trade deficit rather than adopting beggar by thy tit for tat tariff
policies.Without any trade war ,US imposes 1.10 percent tariffs on Chinese grains and crops, 0.68 percent tariffs on Chinese meat and meat products, 0.2730
percent tariffs on extraction industry, 2.719 on Chinese processed food, 10. 30 on Chinese textiles, 4.32 percent on Chinese light manufacturing and 1.02 on
chinese heavy manufacturing.
Chinas tariffs are relatively higher. US grains and crops faces nearly 3 percent duty in China, for meat and meat products it is nearly 9 percent, extraction 0. 64,
Processed food from US 8. 9 percent, Textiles ,7. 7 percent, US light manufacturing from US nearly 10 percent and US heavy manufacturing 3.76 percent. With
trade war, in the US, the following sectors have negative impacts, grains and crops, public utilities and domestic investments.
In China heavy and light manufacturing, domestic investments, services and public utilities are impacted negatively. Further tomorrow in addition to tariff barriers,
barriers, some non tariff barriers are imposed between China and the US , they would further depress welfare and vgdp growth both in China and US with
China being impacted more negatively. The favourable impact would be felt among rest of the north american nations, EU, East Asians and Latin Americans as
trade would get diverted to such regions. Also trade balance would become favourable in the US and China. Textiles in both the region's would gain from Trade
Trade war. All factors of production loose in both China and US except natural resource and land in China with trade war.
111
US CHINA TRADE WAR
US China trade war in 2018.Gains and Losses and impact on India. GTAP 10 simulations.Three Simulation scenarios. Free trade
scenario of zero tariffs imposed both ways, Tariff rates of 10 percent applied to trade in grains, extraction and meat and meat
products both ways and 25 percent tariffs both ways on light and heavy manufacturing and third simulation of 25 percent tariffs
imposed both ways on all products.
It seems that trade war improved trade balance with rest of the world for both countries,US and China. Welfare and GDP loss for
both countries, US and China in case of 25 percent tariffs imposed by both countries with China suffering higher reduction in GDP, a
decline of nearly 4 percent. The latter happens as production and trade of light and heavy manufacturing in China got adversely
impacted.
EU, Canada, Mexico, East Asia,India among others impacted positively in terms of GDP positive changes. However in India one
witnesses welfare loss and negative trade balance. The best scenario for India is under simulation two when US and China imposed
tariffs on selected products.
Free trade brings dividend for both China and US but other countries impacted negatively in serial order, EU28,;Canada, Mexico,
East Asia, among others. Trade war bought negative impact on grains and extraction business in US and negative growth in domestic
investments in US and China and hence decline in GDP.
It may be noted that the US had marginal positive GDP changes and positive trade balance when tariffs were imposed on selected
products two ways. Welfare changes were negative though.China impacted more by the US China trade war. The tariff war were
quiet stringent on the consumers because of the price rise
112
TINA AND GTAP SIMULATIONS: INDIA CHINA
RELATIONSHIP
Trade Intelligence network Tina estimates of Trade creation and Trade diversion between
India and China. Trade creation for China 12 billion US dollars a figure 6 times the figure
for trade creation of India. Around 5 percent of our exports reach China but around 14
percent of our imports come from China.
The corresponding figure for China with respect to India, the share is 3 percent with
respect to exports and less than one percent with respect to imports. Importantly see what
we import from India. Looks like fertilizers, electronic and engineering goods. Trade
creation and trade diversion are based on the SMART model based on import substitution,
export supply and import demand elasticities
113
TINA AND GTAP SIMULATIONS: INDIA CHINA
RELATIONSHIP
What happens at some stage in future we think of having two way free trade between India and China. GTAP
10 simulations. We loose in terms of trade balance, welfare and vGDP having negative welfare, trade balance,
and GDP. We loose in terms of trade in grains, trade in meat products and heavy manufacturing.
We have negative trade balance due to mainly negative trade balances in extraction and heavy manufacturing.
Returns to unskilled labour, skilled labour, capital and much more than the former three,returns to natural capital
would go up, namely those who are involved in forestry, fishing, coal and oil extraction and metals.
Chinese would have positive 0. 17 growth in vGDP and more than 4200 million us dollars welfare gain if it
aligns with India. Gains would double for China and maybe some gains for India if services and investment
Liberalization are included. As of today free trade with China brings negative welfare for India.
Idea is to shift comparative advantage in its own favour in India by investing in Electrical, Electronics, Engineering
goods and 4IR technologies, promote village development, ports, telecommunications, among others to match the
Chinese superiority. Pharma and medical products and GVCs can be further developed in India.
114
Indo Pacific Economic Framework 14
using General Equilibrium Modelling

Which regions would gain the most under Indo pacific economic framework present areas of
cooperation? We use the general equilibrium models to analyze and simulate the impact of present
dispensation under the IPEF 14 focusing on four areas of cooperation namely connectivity
including physical and digital connectivity, raising labour and environmental standards and following
norms of fair trade, energy and climate security, and enhancing global value chains to stem supply
chain disruptions. It seems that the US,Japan, Korea, Australia, New Zealand and Fiji would gain the
most in terms of welfare and vgdp growth followed by India and then Asean 7 nation's in terms of
vgdp growth. This serial order changes as and when IPEF 14 becomes a trade agreement where in
their is free flow of goods, services and capital and skilled labour flows across nation's. ASEAN 7
jumps to the second position in terms of vgdp growth and welfare while India would be a laggard
when IPEF would allow tariff liberalization along with free movement of factor flows across nation's.
The welfare levels are any figure between 63 billion US dollars to 99 billion US dollars for India
under two simulation scenarios of no trade agreement and one when IPEF 14 transforms into a trade
agreement. Similarly ASEAN welfare levels reach 126 billion US dollars with ,nearly 5 percent growth
under trade agreement scenario. It is the QUAD nation's, Korea and new Zealand which reap the
maximum benefit under both scenarios, no and with trade agreement with welfare reaching beyond
1100 billion US dollars with nearly ,4.50 percent growth in the member states with trade agreement
and free flow of labour and capital. A carbon taxation of 6 percent along with trade liberalization
can take care of the carbon emissions and partly address the climate change in the US led IPEF 14
nation's. Fiji is the 14 th nation apart from asean 7 nation's along with the QUAD, new Zealand and
Korea.
115
India ASEAN

We use energy environment variant of the general equilibrium GTAP model named GTAP E to analyze
standalone ASEAN 10 comprehensive liberalization at some future date among themselves and then
bring in India's participation in the treaty. We assume tariff and non tariff liberalization with freer
movement of skilled labour and capital with input and output oriented technological progress in
sectors like industry and services ,agriculture and energy intensive industries. We find that
standalone liberalization of ASEAN 10 brings welfare of 110 billion US dollars for the asean 10
nation's with vgdp growth of 4 percent and more . The same figure jumps to 132 billion US dollars
with 6 percent growth rate if India becomes it's eleventh participating member. The growth rates
seems to emanate from high domestic investments and high sectoral growth rates of industry,,
services and agricultural sector. For India welfare levels reach 89 billion US dollars with 4.48
percent vgdp growth. The growth is again pushed up by domestic investments, industry and services,
energy intensive industries, agriculture , electricity and petroleum. In fact carbon emissions growth
of more than 3 percent and 1 percent in India and ASEAN 10 nation's due to this deeper integration
policies can be taken care by imposition of 3 percent carbon taxation. In India all factors gain
except real returns to natural capital while in ASEAN 10 except for land and natural resource ,skilled
and unskilled labour and capital gains with adoption of deeper integration policies. The carbon tax
rates are real carbon tax rates at 1997 US dollars per tonne.The trade balance for both India and
ASEAN 10 with rest of the world becomes negative. Energy exporters gain with this alignment of
India with ASEAN 10. Their are however deeper gains for India if we align deeper with Indo Pacific
alliance countries, IPEF, CPTPP, EU 27 and last not the least we multilaterally liberalize under the
aegis of the WTO.
116
Services Sector Contribution using
General Equilibrium Modelling

Services sector contribution in India can be also read by using the two general equilibrium models GTAP 10
and GTAP E . The simulations are worked out by ensuring that the sectors like transport and communication,
public utilities and other services including business and financial services are given productivity shocks
keeping the services sector as final demand and also by considering them as inputs to the production of all
commodities. In addition we add simulations by including productivity shocks in skilled labour as inputs to
the production processes. The welfare levels increases to more than 80000 million US dollars while vgdp
growth is nearly 4 percent due to productivity shocks of the services sector. Public utilities and domestic
investments are the major gainers because of services sector growth in terms of technology. Here comes the
interesting part. Productivity shocks to light and heavy manufacturing and textiles both considering them as
inputs and outputs, the welfare levels are more than 80000 million us dollars with vgdp growth of nearly 7
percent. Welfare and vgdp grows further if productivity of skilled labour and capital increases industry
output all around. Agriculture productivity and allied activities brings relatively lower gains in terms of
welfare and vgdp growth. The agriculture sector growth is important given that 48 percent of the workforce
is still in the agriculture sector

Services contributes more than 60 percent of the GDP involving 30 percent of the work force. Industry
contributes 25 percent of the GDP while agriculture contributes around 15 percent of the GDP. All in all
productivity shocks to outputs and inputs of the sector has welfare and growth dividends with
manufacturing seems to be having greater relative impact on vgdp growth and employment. The quality of
employment in the services sector is lagging behind especially in sectors like financial services and business
services. Trade,Roads and Railways, public administration and defense, banks share in services sector
contribution in terms of GVA are the highest. Air transport, communication, banks, non life insurance,
computer related services among others are high productive services sectors.
117
Structural Transformation in India using
General Equilibrium Modelling

We use GTAP 10 simulations to understand the structural transformation of the Indian economy by assuming same and
differential output oriented technological progress for manufacturing, services and agriculture. The theory of structural
transformation were first given by Simon Kuznets who conjectured that share of agriculture in GDP and employment would first
go up, then these shares would come down for agriculture and increase for manufacturing and industry and finally the shares of
services in GDP and employment would go up. India seems to have leapfrogged the development process with services taking
the lead role after agriculture lost its share in GDP but not employment to a great extend. The missing phase is the increase of
share of manufacturing in GDP and employment of India Second, services sector employment share in India is around 30
percent of the total workforce of India, while agriculture employs 48 percent of the workforce. Using GTAP 10 model and the
shock aoall we assume 2 percent output oriented technological progress in agriculture and manufacturing and 6 percent output
oriented technological progress in services. We find that we can achieve more than 11 percent vgdp growth. All factors of
production would gain except natural capital. Domestic investments would be the driver of the growth rates in India. The
second set of simulations showed us that by seperating output oriented technological progress and assuming it to be same
across agriculture and allied activities, manufacturing and services, we find maximum growth and employment due to
technological progress in manufacturing sector with negative real returns to land and natural resource, but skilled labour and
unskilled labour with capital gaining the most. Output oriented technological progress in Agriculture brings relatively the
lowest vgdp growth as compared to other two sectors with positive real returns of all factors except land. Natural resource
returns becomes positive if we see growth in agriculture. Worrying part is that Indian agriculture still employs 48 percent of our
492 million work force. Lower vgdp growth rates with 50 percent of the workforce still stationed in agriculture either requires
massive education and training of the agricultural workforce or use of biotechnology to convert agricultural resources and
waste into alternative energy resources. This may take care of the workforce in agriculture sector Subsidies tend to reduce
world prices and bring in distortions in the economy. Services output oriented technological progress of 8 percent can push
vgdp growth alone to more than 8 percent with real returns to all factors including land gaining except natural resource.
Scarcity of Natural resources seems to be a thorn in India's progress. Domestic investments and public utilities like electricity,
water, gas, construction have ability to push Indian growth rates. Renewables and alternative energy resources are future areas
of investment for sustainable growth and achieving the millenium development goals.The new geopolitics and geoeconomics
can become constraints unless and untill global governance, social harmony and democracy prevails with concerted attempts
made to reduce authoritarianism all around.
118
Relative Gains in aligning with Regional
Groups

India's maximum relative gains in terms of vgdp growth of 6.95 percentage is by having one
comprehensive trade, economic and industrial partnership with EU ,27 nations. These are
simulation results from the GTAP 10 model . Followed by this is the India's vgdp growth of
6.82 percentage when India has one complete , full and comprehensive liberalization deal
with 54 nations African Comprehensive free trade area. This is followed by having deeper
integration with South Asia with India growing at 6.74 percentage. Then comes Oceania when
India grows at 6.35 percentage. The next is MENA when India grows at 6.14 and finaly Latin
American region when India grows at 5.35 percent..The laggard performance in terms of vgdp
growth of India is when it comprehensively liberalizes with ASEAN, East Asia and North
American regions. The difficulty is that welfare gains are more for India when it liberalizes
with East Asian region including ASEAN nations. This may be due to possibly the average
tariffs imposed by India on East Asian region products seems to be relatively higher as
compared to other regions of the world. The comprehensive agreement includes tariff, non
tariff and capital and skilled labour liberalization with adoption of common industrial
policies in the entire region. India gains with our alignment with the EU 27 because of
manufacturing growth in India along with services sector growth with pulling up of domestic
investments in India due to comprehensive agreements with the EU 27 nations. Energy
scarcity and negative returns to natural capital are constraints to India's progress.
119
Hands on Experience through analyzing trade data
in stata and R using partial equilibrium models and
simulations through General Equilibrium
Modelling
120
EXPORT SUBSIDIES AND TARIFFS
What is the partial and general equilibrium impact of giving exports subsidies and tariffs on home and foreign country and the
world assuming home country is a large country.Exports subsidies imposed by large countries tends to increase price received by
exporters incentivizing them to produce more. Consumers loose because of the increase in prices.
These two developments shifts the demand and supply curves leading to decrease in terms of trade or world prices. In addition
production and consumption Distortions leads to decline in welfare for the home country. This is the partial equilibrium impact of
imposing subsidies on home countries.
General equilibrium impact of export subsidies on employment, trade balance, allocative efficiency, investment savings among others
also happens but difficult to gauge due to myriad and complex inter relationships among the variables.
What is the partial equilibrium impact of giving export subsidies on your trading partners. Your terms of trade Loss is terms of trade
gain for the foreign country. However consumption Distortions reduces the welfare. Net effect is ambigous. World welfare is
negative due to production and consumption Distortions across the world.
Export subsidies can be more pernicious than tariffs if general equilibrium impacts allso turns to be negative. Tariffs have ambigous
impact on welfare of large country, decline in welfare of foreign country due to decline in terms of trade and production Distortions
happening in foreign country. World welfare reduces due to distortions.
121
122
123
PRODUCTION SUBSIDIES
When production subsidies are given it is equivalent to saying that price received by domestic
producers goes up. Will producers increase their domestic prices. No. They did so when export
subsidies were given. They will not do it because no will buy from them and would import the product at
lower world prices.
However, when export subsidies are given domestic producers will increase their domestic prices.
Why Reason being otherwise all will become exporters and no domestic producers and domestic
market would exist .Domestic subsidies leads to production distortions but export subsidies leads to
both production and consumption distortions.
Production subsidies are relatively less distortive and maybe that is the reason they continue to be
mandated in the WTO. Export subsidies are also most of the times supported by import tariffs on the
same goods in which export subsidies were given.
124
Ban on Wheat Exports

What is the general equilibrium impact of ban on export of wheat by India to the rest of the world? It seems that India gains
marginally in terms of welfare , trade balance and higher production of wheat due to further increase of wheat prices in the
international market. Net importers of wheat like the Middle East and North African region and Sub Saharan African nations would
loose the most in terms of welfare.We knew about the partial equilibrium impacts of export ban through the lerners theorem that
export tax and import tax have equivalent but ambigous impacts on net welfare of the nation assuming export ban to be equivalent to
export tax. Ambigous impact on net welfare due to export ban because terms of trade improvement will increase welfare in the
nation while production and consumption distortions would reduce welfare due to export ban. Producers of wheat in home for
example would get less incentivised to produce and sell after the ban creating scarcity and jacking up of world prices. Production
distortions because net proceeds are less while consumers gain hopefully due to reduction in domestic prices.The net output
producers like North American region and Oceania would gain the most due to India's export ban decision and rise in world prices.We
use GTAP 10 general equilibrium model to work out the impacts of raising average tariffs on wheat in India to 20 percent and 40
percent respectively from present tax duties on wheat imports on an average being 11.23 percent for all regions imports of wheat
into India. For other grains and crops on an average taxes in India are 24 percent for all regions imports of agriculture products. By
creating scarcity through export ban the world prices would go up further. This may incentive major producers to produce more and
export more. This includes the major producers and exporters of wheat like North American region, the EU, Oceania, Russia and
Ukraine and India to some extend. MENA and SSA who are net importers of wheat would loose the maximum due to export ban
followed by negative welfare for regions like EU and East Asia . North America, India and Oceania would be the net gainers in terms
of welfare and output production. India's trade balance also improves marginally. Trade of wheat may also gets diverted to Oceania
and North American region due to export ban in India, and whatever trade was suppose to get diverted to us due to Russian Ukraine
War would be lost as well . Russia and Ukraine would be the impacted the most negatively due to the war and subsequent curtailment
of production and export of wheat. We impose on average 24 percent duty on wheat imports from Russia and Ukraine, Oceanias
wheat get taxed at 24.99 percent, East Asia 0 percent ,South East Asia 36.44 percent, South Asia 0 percent, North America 16.30
percent, Latin America 0 percent, EU 28 is charged 0 percent duty on wheat coming into india, MENA 2.71 percent and Rest of the
world 20.9 percent. Domestically export prices and home prices may go down because the surplus gets diverted to domestic market
provided middlemen do not distort the same. The entire trade policy literature is about how trade policy actions creating a division
125
between export/ domestic prices and international prices. Protectionism is beggar by thy policy where in one country gains at the
cost of the others while world welfare goes down .Their is limited impact on vgdp growth across regions except marginal impacts on
MENA and SSA regions though.
Sugar Restraint

We use GTAP 10 General equilibrium model to study and read the impact of recently announced sugar export restraint
measures on the Indian economy and other major ten regions of the world. These are Oceania, East Asia, South East Asia,
South Asia, North America, Latin America , EU 28, MENA, SSA and rest of the world. The average tariffs on all regions imports
of sugar into India is 26.35 percent while all regions imports of Indian sugar is taxed at the rate of 10.46 percent. The export
restrictions are like export taxes. Export taxes have equivalent impacts like that of import taxes on welfare. We assume in our
simulations 50 percent target tariff rates , a raise of 24 percent from the present rate of 26 percent due to export restraint
measures. Our welfare goes up by 201 million US dollars but we see a fall in trade balance with the rest of the world with
marginal decline in vgdp growth of .12 percent due to negative thirteen percent growth in quantity value added of sugar.
Export taxes tend to create scarcity and the world prices are likely to go up. This may hit net sugar importers like East Asian
and SSA countries. Domestically the producers are likely to get lesser proceeds because they need to pay higher taxes.
Consumers gain domestically because of lower prices. Trade policies always have beggar by thy impacts. We gain against the
loss in welfare , output and exports of other region's . North America, Latin America, EU 28 and South East Asian exports of
sugar would go up. However, the following regions have lot of potential to increase their sugar output and exports. These
include our South Asian partners, MENA and SSA region. Latin American region welfare and exports go up due to one more
protectionist measure adopted by India. We impose maximum duty on sugar imports on East Asian region with tariffs reaching
30.10 percentage , Oceania 25.06 percent, South East Asia 26.96 percentage, South Asia 1.45 percent, North America 26.35
percent, Latin American exports of sugar to India are taxed at 60 percent, EU 28 percent, MENA 24 percent, SSA 14.56 percent
and ROW imports are taxed on an average of 29.45 percent. We tend to protect our processed food and grains and crops sector
the most among all sectors. The sugar impacts are different from wheat ban exports. The GTAP results showed India gained in
terms of welfare, vgdp and trade balance in case of ban of wheat exports . In case of sugar restraints returns to land and
unskilled labour, transport and communications and public utilities are negative due to one more protectionist measure
adopted by India. However all trade policies adopted by large countries have ambiguous impacts as some factors,sectors and
stake holders gain and others loose. Trade always have unequal impacts on returns to factors of production. Hence
complementary policies are needed to compensate the loosers. In this case agricultural exporters of sugar and wheat. We need
liberalization of agricultural sector which seems to be the most protected sector ac
126
127
Yotov 2022 on gravity analysis being an
estimating CGE Model

See table in next slide
128
References
• Anderson, James E., and Eric Van Wincoop. "Gravity with gravitas: A solution to the border puzzle." American
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
economic review 93, no. 1 (2003): 170-192.
Batra, Amita. Regional economic integration in South Asia: Trapped in conflict?. Routledge, 2012.
Batra, Raveendra N. Studies in the pure theory of international trade. Springer, 1973.
Bernard, Andrew B., J. Bradford Jensen, Stephen J. Redding, and Peter K. Schott. "Firms in international
trade." Journal of Economic perspectives 21, no. 3 (2007): 105-130.
Burfisher, Mary E. Introduction to computable general equilibrium models. Cambridge University Press, 2021.
Chaney, Thomas. "Distorted gravity: heterogeneous firms, market structure, and the geography of international
trade." American Economic Review 98, no. 4 (2008): 1707-1721.
Costantini, Valeria, and Massimiliano Mazzanti, eds. The dynamics of environmental and economic systems:
innovation, environmental policy and competitiveness. Springer Science & Business Media, 2012.
Falvey, Rodney E., David Greenaway, and Udo Kreickemeier, eds. Palgrave handbook of international trade.
Palgrave Macmillan, 2011.
Gaurav, Abhishek, and Somesh K. Mathur. "Determinants of trade costs and trade growth accounting between
India and the European union during 1995–2010." The World Economy 39, no. 9 (2016): 1399-1413.
Gopinath, Gita, Elhanan Helpman, and Kenneth Rogoff, eds. Handbook of international economics. Elsevier,
2014.
130
References Contd.
• Grossman, Gene M., and Kenneth Rogoff, eds. Handbook of international economics. Vol. 3. Elsevier, 1995.
• Hertel, Thomas Warren. Global trade analysis: modeling and applications. Cambridge university press, 1997.
• Kathuria, Sanjay, ed. A glass half full: The promise of regional trade in South Asia. World Bank Publications,
2018.
• Mathur, Somesh K., Rahul Arora, and Sarbjit Singh, eds. Methods and Applications in Trade Policy Research.
Athena Academic.
• Mathur, Somesh K., Rahul Arora, and Sarbjit Singh, eds. Theorizing international trade: An Indian perspective.
Springer, 2017.
• Pacakge gravity in R, CRAN , Estimation Methods for Gravity Models
• Robert, E. Baldwin. The Development and Testing of Heckscher-Ohlin Trade Models: A Review. MIT., 2008.
• Shepherd, Ben. "The gravity model of international trade: A user guide." (2013).
• Yotov, Yoto V. "Gravity at Sixty: The Workhorse Model of Trade." (2022).
• Yotov, Yoto V., Roberta Piermartini, and Mario Larch. An Advanced Guide to Trade Policy Analysis​: The Structural
Gravity Model. WTO iLibrary, 2016.
131
Thankyou for your patience
132
Download