Uploaded by donotusethisemail1877

Global Business Today 5th Edition

advertisement
GLOBAL
BUSINESS
TODAY
FIFTH EDITION
ASIA–PACIFIC PERSPECTIVE
hiL23674_fm_i-xxx.indd i
08/06/19 05:52 PM
Copyright © 2019 McGraw-Hill Education (Australia) Pty Ltd
Additional owners of copyright are acknowledged in on-page credits
Every effort has been made to trace and acknowledge copyrighted material. The authors
and publishers tender their apologies should any infringement have occurred.
Reproduction and communication for educational purposes
The Australian Copyright Act 1968 (the Act) allows a maximum of one chapter or 10% of
the pages of this work, whichever is the greater, to be reproduced and/or communicated
by any educational institution for its educational purposes provided that the institution (or
the body that administers it) has sent a Statutory Educational notice to Copyright Agency
(CA) and been granted a licence. For details of statutory educational and other copyright
licences contact: Copyright Agency, 66 Goulburn Street, Sydney NSW 2000. Telephone:
(02) 9394 7600.
Website: www.copyright.com.au
Reproduction and communication for other purposes
Apart from any fair dealing for the purposes of study, research, criticism or review, as
permitted under the Act, no part of this publication may be reproduced, distributed or
transmitted in any form or by any means, or stored in a database or retrieval system,
without the written permission of McGraw-Hill Education (Australia) Pty Ltd, including, but
not limited to, any network or other electronic storage.
Enquiries should be made to the publisher via www.mheducation.com.au or marked for
the attention of the permissions editor at the address below.
National Library of Australia Cataloguing-in-Publication Data
Author:Charles W. L. Hill, Tomas M. Hult, Rumintha Wickramasekera,
Kim MacKenzie, Cameron Gordon
Title:
Global Business Today: Asia–Pacific Perspective
Edition:
5th edition
ISBN:
9781760423674 (paperback)
Published in Australia by
McGraw-Hill Education (Australia) Pty Ltd
Level 33, 680 George Street, Sydney NSW 2000
Portfolio managers: Matthew Coxhill and Jillian Gibbs
Content developer: Anne Harmer
Production editor: Lara McMurray
Proofreader: Annabel Adair
Indexer: SPi, India
Cover and internal design: Seymour Design
Typeset in That 10/13 by SPi, India
Printed in Singapore on 70 gsm matt art by Markono Print Media Pte Ltd
hiL23674_fm_i-xxx.indd
ii
08/06/19 05:52 PM
GLOBAL
BUSINESS
TODAY
FIFTH EDITION
ASIA-PACIFIC PERSPECTIVE
HILL HULT WICKRAMASEKERA MACKENZIE GORDON
hiL23674_fm_i-xxx.indd iii
08/06/19 05:52 PM
hiL23674_fm_i-xxx.indd
iv
08/06/19 05:52 PM
 v
hiL23674_fm_i-xxx.indd v
08/06/19 05:52 PM
CONTENTS IN BRIEF
1
2
3
1
CHAPTER 1 GLOBALISATION
2
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE,
INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
CHAPTER 2 THEORIES OF TRADE, INVESTMENT
AND INTERNATIONALISATION
vi
55
56
CHAPTER 3 THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
101
CHAPTER 4 FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND THE INTERNATIONAL
MONETARY SYSTEM
159
COUNTRY DIFFERENCES
207
CHAPTER 5 DIFFERENCES IN CULTURE
208
CHAPTER 6 POLITICAL AND LEGAL ENVIRONMENTS
255
CHAPTER 7 ECONOMIC ENVIRONMENT
301
CHAPTER 8 ETHICS AND CORPORATE RESPONSIBILITY
351
CHAPTER 9 COUNTRY MARKET RESEARCH
391
COMPETING IN THE GLOBAL MARKETPLACE
4
hiL23674_fm_i-xxx.indd
GLOBALISATION
427
CHAPTER 10 THE STRATEGY OF INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS
428
CHAPTER 11 ENTERING FOREIGN MARKETS
473
CHAPTER 12 INTERNATIONAL MARKETING/BUSINESS ANALYTICS
509
CHAPTER 13 INTERNATIONAL PRODUCTION, OUTSOURCING AND LOGISTICS
557
CHAPTER 14 INTERNATIONAL HUMAN RESOURCE MANAGEMENT
599
08/06/19 05:52 PM
CONTENTS IN FULL
Prefacexiii
Organisation/contentxx
About the authors
Text at a glance
xxii
Acknowledgmentsxvi
Case and vignette matrix
xxiv
What’s new in the fifth edition
International Business Graduate Attributes
xiv
xix
xxviii
1 GLOBALISATION
1
CHAPTER 1 GLOBALISATION2
International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs)
3
Learning Objectives (LOs)
3
Opening Case: Kaihara: Globalisation of a shinise,
a long-lived company
4
Introduction6
What is globalisation?
10
The globalisation of markets
The globalisation of production
12
13
The emergence of global institutions
16
Drivers of globalisation
18
Declining trade and investment barriers
The role of technological change
Implications for the globalisation of production
and markets
The changing shape of the global economy
The changing world output and world trade picture
The changing foreign direct investment picture
19
20
21
23
23
24
The changing nature of the multinational enterprise
The changing world order
The global economy of the 21st century: The emerging
markets century?
The globalisation debate
27
28
30
32
Anti-globalisation protests
Globalisation, jobs and income inequality
Globalisation, labour policies and the environment
Globalisation and national sovereignty
Globalisation and the world’s poor
32
33
37
41
42
Managing in the global marketplace: What’s the difference?
44
Key terms
46
Summary46
International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs):
Learning and assessment tasks
48
Closing Case: Global innovation through the mobility
of ideas and talent
49
Endnotes53
2 CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
55
CHAPTER 2 THEORIES OF TRADE, INVESTMENT AND INTERNATIONALISATION
56
International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs)
57
Learning Objectives (LOs)
57
Opening Case: Bangladesh’s textile trade
58
Introduction59
Mercantilism61
Absolute advantage
61
Comparative advantage
62
Ricardo’s theory
The Samuelson critique
62
67
Evidence for the link between trade and
growth67
Heckscher-Ohlin theory
69
The Leontief paradox
70
The product life-cycle theory
71
Evaluating the product life-cycle theory
73
New trade theory
73
Increasing product variety and reducing costs
Economies of scale, first-mover advantages and the
pattern of trade
Implications of new trade theory
74
74
75
CONTENTS IN FULL vii
hiL23674_fm_i-xxx.indd vii
08/06/19 05:52 PM
National competitive advantage: Porter’s diamond
Factor endowments
Demand conditions
Related and supporting industries
Firm strategy, structure and rivalry
Evaluating Porter’s model
Foreign direct investment in the world economy
Why foreign direct investment?
The pattern of foreign direct investment
The eclectic paradigm
Internationalisation of the company
77
78
79
79
79
80
82
83
86
86
88
The Uppsala models (U-models)
The Innovation-related models (I-models)
89
90
‘Born global’ companies
90
Key terms
94
Summary94
International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs):
Learning and assessment tasks
96
Closing Case: Logitech’s global approach
97
Endnotes99
CHAPTER 3 THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs)
102
Learning Objectives (LOs)
102
Opening Case: Unease over China’s rare earth trade policies
103
Introduction104
Instruments of trade policy
106
Tariffs106
Subsidies107
Import quotas and voluntary export restraints
110
Local content requirements
110
Administrative policies
112
Anti-dumping policies
112
Why governments intervene in trade
Political arguments for intervention
Economic arguments for intervention
Why governments intervene in FDI
Host-country benefits and costs
Home-country benefits and costs
113
101
Government policy instruments and FDI
126
Home-country policies
Host-country policies
126
127
Trade and FDI liberalisation
131
Trade and FDI liberalisation and the WTO
133
Regional economic integration
140
The move towards regional economic integration
Levels of economic integration
The case for regional economic integration
The case against regional economic integration
140
143
145
147
Key terms
150
Summary150
113
117
International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs):
Learning and assessment tasks
152
122
Closing Case: Make it Australian? Free trade versus
national identity
153
123
126
Endnotes157
CHAPTER 4 FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs)
160
Learning Objectives (LOs)
160
Opening Case: The Mexican peso, the Japanese yen
and Pokémon Go161
Introduction162
The foreign exchange market
The nature of the foreign exchange market
The functions of the foreign exchange market
Determination of the exchange rate
Prices and exchange rates
Interest rates and exchange rates
Investor psychology and the bandwagon effect
The international monetary system
Exchange rate regimes in practice
Motives and means for managing the foreign
exchange rate
Functions of an international monetary system
The rise and fall of the Bretton Woods system
A role for the IMF
159
178
180
184
185
187
164
Key terms
164
166
Summary200
172
172
174
176
177
200
International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs):
Learning and assessment tasks
202
Closing Case: The fluctuating value of the yuan gives
Chinese business a lesson in foreign exchange risk
203
Endnotes205
viii GLOBAL BUSINESS TODAY
hiL23674_fm_i-xxx.indd
viii
08/06/19 05:52 PM
3 COUNTRY DIFFERENCES
207
CHAPTER 5 DIFFERENCES IN CULTURE
208
International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs)
209
Superstitions231
Learning Objectives (LOs)
209
Language233
Opening Case: Evolving culture at Panasonic
210
Introduction211
What is culture?
Values and norms
The determinants of culture
Social structure
Individuals and groups
Social stratification
Religious and ethical systems
212
213
215
216
216
218
221
Christianity222
Islam223
Hinduism227
Buddhism229
Confucianism230
Spoken language
Unspoken language
233
234
Education235
Culture and the workplace
236
Cultural context
236
Cultural change
243
Key terms
248
Summary248
International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs):
Learning and assessment tasks
249
Closing Case: Cognition Consulting: Exporting
New Zealand’s educational expertise and culture
250
Endnotes253
CHAPTER 6 POLITICAL AND LEGAL ENVIRONMENTS
International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs)
256
Learning Objectives (LOs)
256
Opening Case: Transformation in Saudi Arabia
257
Introduction258
Political systems
Collectivism, socialism and individualism
Shifting ideology and FDI
Democracy and totalitarianism
The spread of democracy
The new world order and global terrorism
Legal systems
Different legal systems
258
260
264
268
272
274
275
276
255
Differences in contract law
Property rights and corruption
The protection of intellectual property
Product safety and product liability
Competition law
Taxation law
277
278
282
284
286
287
Key terms 292
Summary292
International Business Graduate Attributes (IGBAs):
Learning and assessment tasks
294
Closing Case: The elusive Elena Egorova
295
Endnotes299
CHAPTER 7 ECONOMIC ENVIRONMENT
International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs)
302
Learning Objectives (LOs)
302
Opening Case: Brazil’s struggling economy
303
Introduction304
Economic endowments—natural and created
305
Size305
Geography305
People306
Infrastructure and institutions
310
Productivity and competitiveness
312
301
Economic performance: Macroeconomic stability
314
Economic stability
314
Economic growth and employment fluctuations
316
Inflation318
External viability and the balance of payments
319
Economic performance: Economic development
322
Measures of economic development
Broader conceptions and measures of development
Economic systems
Market economy
Command economy
323
327
329
330
330
CONTENTS IN FULL ix
hiL23674_fm_i-xxx.indd ix
08/06/19 05:52 PM
Mixed economy
Economic systems and economic development
331
332
Summary345
Economies in transition
336
International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs):
Learning and assessment tasks
346
336
336
Closing Case: Economic development
in Bangladesh347
345
Endnotes349
The spread of the market
The nature of economic transition
Key terms
CHAPTER 8 ETHICS AND CORPORATE RESPONSIBILITY
International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs)
352
Learning Objectives (LOs)
352
Opening Case: Sustainability initiatives at Natura
Cosmetics, The Body Shop and Aesop
353
Introduction354
Ethical issues in international business
356
Employment practices
356
Human rights
357
Environmental pollution
358
Bribery and corruption
359
Corporate social responsibility
361
Sustainability363
351
Philosophical approaches to ethics
372
The Friedman doctrine
Cultural relativism
Righteous moralism
Naive immoralism
Utilitarian and Kantian ethics
Rights theories
Justice theories
372
373
373
374
375
376
377
Ethical decision making in international business
379
Organisation culture and leadership
Decision-making processes
Ethics officers
Moral courage
Social enterprises
Summary of managerial actions
380
381
383
383
384
384
Ethical dilemmas
364
Child labour
365
Key terms
367
Summary385
The roots of unethical behaviour
Personal ethics
Decision-making processes
Organisation culture
Unrealistic performance expectations
Corporate governance and leadership
367
368
368
368
368
385
International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs):
Learning and assessment tasks
386
Closing Case: Woolworths’ corporate responsibility strategy
387
Endnotes389
CHAPTER 9 COUNTRY MARKET RESEARCH391
International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs)
392
Learning Objectives (LOs)
392
Opening Case: Spotify and Soundcloud
393
Introduction394
The promise and pitfalls of exporting
Improving export performance
An international comparison
Export promotion agencies
Using export management companies
Export strategy
Basic entry decisions
395
397
397
397
398
399
400
Which foreign markets?
400
Gross fixed capital formation
405
The CAGE framework for distance
analysis405
Cost–risk trade-off
408
Timing of entry
Scale of entry and strategic commitments
Financing trade
409
410
413
Lack of trust
414
Letter of credit
415
Draft416
Bill of lading
417
A typical international trade transaction
418
Export credit insurance
419
Conclusion419
Key terms
422
Summary422
International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs):
Learning and assessment tasks
423
Closing Case: Jollibee: A multinational company
from the Philippines
424
Endnotes426
x GLOBAL BUSINESS TODAY
hiL23674_fm_i-xxx.indd
x
08/06/19 05:52 PM
4 COMPETING IN THE GLOBAL MARKETPLACE
427
CHAPTER 10 THE STRATEGY OF INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS
428
International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs)
429
Learning Objectives (LOs)
429
Opening Case: Red Bull’s global strategy
430
Introduction431
Strategy and the company
432
Value creation
433
Strategic positioning
435
Operations: The company as a value chain
436
Organisation: The implementation of strategy
438
In sum: Strategic fit
441
Global expansion, profitability and profit growth
441
Expanding the market: Leveraging products
and competencies
442
Location economies
443
Experience effects
445
Leveraging subsidiary skills
448
Summation449
Cost pressures and pressures for local responsiveness
Pressures for cost reductions
Pressures for local responsiveness
450
450
451
Differences in distribution channels
Host government demands
452
454
Choosing a strategy
454
Global standardisation strategy
Localisation strategy
Transnational strategy
International strategy
455
455
456
457
The evolution of strategy
458
Strategic alliances
460
The advantages of strategic alliances
The disadvantages of strategic alliances
Making alliances work
460
461
462
Key terms
466
Summary466
International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs):
Learning and assessment tasks
467
Closing Case: The growth strategy of Haier
468
Endnotes470
CHAPTER 11 ENTERING FOREIGN MARKETS
International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs)
474
Learning Objectives (LOs)
474
Opening Case: International market entry at Starbucks
475
Introduction476
Entry modes
476
Exporting476
Importing480
Turnkey projects
481
Licensing482
Franchising484
Joint ventures
486
Wholly owned subsidiaries
489
Selecting an entry mode
Core competencies and entry mode
Pressures for cost reductions and entry mode
490
491
493
473
Greenfield venture versus acquisition
Pros and cons of acquisitions
Pros and cons of greenfield ventures
Making a choice: Greenfield or acquisition?
Countertrade498
The incidence of countertrade
498
Types of countertrade
499
The pros and cons of countertrade
501
Key terms
510
Learning Objectives (LOs)
510
Opening Case: Burberry’s social media marketing
511
Introduction512
The globalisation of markets and brands
513
Market segmentation
514
502
Summary502
International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs):
Learning and assessment tasks
503
Closing Case: The Happy Snack Company: This happy,
healthy message is too good not to share
504
Endnotes507
CHAPTER 12 INTERNATIONAL MARKETING/BUSINESS ANALYTICS
International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs)
493
494
496
497
Product attributes
509
518
Cultural differences
Economic development
Product and technical standards
518
519
519
Distribution strategy
Differences between countries
Choosing a distribution strategy
521
522
524
CONTENTS IN FULL xi
hiL23674_fm_i-xxx.indd xi
08/06/19 05:52 PM
Communication strategy
Barriers to international communication
Push versus pull strategies
Global advertising
525
525
528
530
New product development
544
The location of R&D
Integrating R&D, marketing and production
Cross-functional teams
Building global R&D capabilities
545
546
547
547
Pricing strategy
Price discrimination
Strategic pricing
Regulatory influences on prices
533
533
534
536
Configuring the marketing mix
537
International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs):
Learning and assessment tasks
551
International market research
538
Closing Case: Youi: Selling the you
552
Business analytics
541
Endnotes555
Key terms
549
Summary549
CHAPTER 13 INTERNATIONAL PRODUCTION, OUTSOURCING AND LOGISTICS
International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs)
558
Learning Objectives (LOs)
558
Opening Case: Li & Fung Ltd: A factory of sorts,
now out of sorts
559
Introduction561
Strategy, production and logistics
563
Where to produce
Country factors
Technological factors
Product factors
Locating production facilities
566
566
567
574
574
The strategic role of foreign factories
Outsourcing production: Make-or-buy decisions
557
The advantages of ‘make’ decisions
580
The advantages of ‘buy’ decisions
583
Trade-offs585
Strategic alliances with suppliers
585
Managing a global supply chain
The role of just-in-time inventory
The role of information technology and the
internet
586
588
Key terms
592
589
Summary592
International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs):
Learning and assessment tasks
593
575
Closing Case: FMCG, soft dollars and lean supply chains
595
579
Endnotes597
CHAPTER 14 INTERNATIONAL HUMAN RESOURCE MANAGEMENT
International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs)
600
Learning Objectives (LOs)
600
Opening Case: Global mobility at Shell
601
Introduction602
599
Performance appraisal problems
Guidelines for performance appraisal
623
624
Compensation policy
National differences in compensation
Expatriate pay
624
624
625
International labour relations
The concerns of organised labour
Strategy of organised labour
Approaches to labour relations
The role of corporate social responsibility
628
629
629
631
632
Key terms
633
The strategic role of HRM
605
Staffing policy
Types of staffing policy
Expatriate management
606
607
611
Training and management development
Training for expatriate managers
Management development and strategy
617
618
619
Female participation in senior international management
Equal opportunity
Work–life balance
Mentorship and networking
619
621
622
622
International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs):
Learning and assessment tasks
635
Closing Case: Sodexo: Building a diverse
global workforce
636
Performance appraisal
623
Endnotes638
Summary633
Glossary641
Acronyms
651
Countries/Capitals
653
Index
657
xii GLOBAL BUSINESS TODAY
hiL23674_fm_i-xxx.indd
xii
08/06/19 05:52 PM
PREFACE
Global Business Today is intended primarily as an introductory
textbook for international/global business courses at tertiary
institutions at both the undergraduate and postgraduate level.
The authors have attempted to write a book that:
• presents a balanced global view
• goes beyond an uncritical presentation and shallow
explanation of the body of knowledge
• is well structured and well written, with tight integration and
flow between chapters
• focuses on managerial implications
• uses up-to-date examples and case studies
• examines international business in contexts relevant to the
students’ experiences with an Asia–Pacific focus
• makes important theories accessible and interesting
• incorporates ancillary resources that enliven the text and
make it easier to teach.
In order to be comprehensive, a textbook on international/global
business must:
• explain how and why the world’s countries differ
• present a thorough review of the economics and politics of
international trade and investment
• explain the functions and form of the international monetary
system
• examine the strategies and structures of international
businesses, for both multinational corporations and small to
medium-sized enterprises
• examine the need for a sustainable long-lived approach to
internationalisation
• examine the need for ethical and legal behaviour in
international business
• assess the specific characteristics of international business’s
various functions.
As the authors of this book, we have endeavoured to do all
of these things. We have thoroughly examined the structures
and strategies of international firms, as well as the functional
implications of international business for a variety of firms.
Many students will soon be working in fields that require an
understanding of the effects of international business on an
organisation’s strategy, structure and function. This book pays
close attention to these issues.
Comprehensiveness and relevance also require coverage
of the major current theories. The following insights have
therefore been included:
• the new trade theory and strategic trade policy
• theories of internationalisation, including ‘born globals’ and
international new ventures
• the ‘emerging markets’
• concepts of global inequality
• the work of Nobel Prize-winning economist Amartya Sen on
economic development
• the work of Hernando de Soto on the link between property
rights and economic development
• Samuel Huntington’s influential thesis on the ‘clash of
civilisations’
• the new growth theory of economic development
championed by Paul Romer and Gene Grossman
• empirical work by Jeffery Sachs and others on the
relationship between international trade and economic
growth
• Michael Porter’s theory on the competitive advantage of
nations
• Robert Reich’s work on national competitive advantage
• the work of Nobel Prize-winner Douglas North and others on
national institutional structures and the protection of property
rights
• Walden Bello’s call for deglobalisation, the failure of
globalisation to deliver universal benefits
• the ‘market imperfections’ approach to foreign direct
investment that has grown out of Ronald Coase’s and Oliver
Williamson’s work on transaction cost economics
• Christopher Bartlett’s and Sumantra Ghoshal’s research on
the transnational corporation
• the writings of C.K. Prahalad and Gary Hamel on core
competencies, global competition and global strategic
alliances
• Pankaj Ghemawat’s concept of semiglobalisation, and
his work on how cross-border expansion is affected by
differences in the various dimensions of distance
• Makoto Kanda’s work on long-lived firms
• insights into international business strategy that can be
derived from the resource-based view of the firm.
In light of the fast-changing nature of the international
business environment, the leading-edge theory and up-to-date
material included in this book make it a valuable resource in this
field.
PREFACE xiii
hiL23674_fm_i-xxx.indd xiii
08/06/19 05:52 PM
ABOUT THE AUTHORS
ABOUT THE INTERNATIONAL AUTHORS
CHARLES W.L. HILL is the Hughes M. Blake Professor of
International Business at the School of Business, University
of Washington. Professor Hill received his PhD in industrial
organisation economics in 1983 from the University of
Manchester’s Institute of Science and Technology (UMIST) in
Great Britain. In addition to his position at the University of
Washington, he has served on the faculties of UMIST, Texas
A&M University and Michigan State University.
Professor Hill teaches in the MBA and executive MBA
programs at the University of Washington and has received
awards for teaching excellence in both programs. He has also
taught on several customised executive programs.
Professor Hill has published more than 50 articles in
peer-reviewed academic journals, as well as four university
textbooks—one on strategic management, one on principles
of management, and the other two on international business
(one of which you are now holding). He serves on the editorial
boards of several academic journals and previously served as
consulting editor at the Academy of Management Review.
TOMAS M. HULT is the John W. Byington Endowed Chair,
Professor of Marketing and International Business, and Director
of the International Business Center in the Eli Broad College of
Business at Michigan State University.
Several studies have ranked Professor Hult as one of the
most cited scholars in the world in business and management
(e.g. Thomson Reuters’ Essential Science Indicators). He has
served as editor of Journal of the Academy of Marketing
Science and has published 50 articles in premier business
journals—Journal of International Business Studies, Academy
of Management Journal, Strategic Management Journal,
Journal of Management, Journal of Marketing, Journal of the
Academy of Marketing Science, Journal of Retailing, Journal
of Operations Management and Decision Sciences. Dr Hult
has also published several books, including Global Supply
Chain Management (2014), Total Global Strategy (2012) and
Extending the Supply Chain (2005).
Professor Hult is a well-known keynote speaker on global
supply chain management, global strategy, and marketing
strategy. He teaches in doctoral, master and undergraduate
programs at Michigan State University, and is a visiting professor
at Leeds University (United Kingdom) and Uppsala University
(Sweden). He also teaches frequently in executive development
programs and has developed a large clientele of the world’s top
multinational corporations.
xiv GLOBAL BUSINESS TODAY
hiL23674_fm_i-xxx.indd
xiv
08/06/19 05:52 PM
ABOUT THE LOCAL AUTHORS
RUMINTHA WICKRAMASEKERA is a Senior Fellow of the
Higher Education Academy, UK. He is Associate Professor in
International Business and the coordinator of one of the largest
International Business programs in Australia—Global Business
at Queensland University of Technology (QUT). He has nearly
20 years’ experience in teaching, developing and coordinating
international business subjects at a number of Australian
universities.
Rumintha has also been involved in several major projects
focusing on identifying the dynamics of the internationalisation
process of small to medium-sized enterprises, including his
PhD research, which examined the internationalisation of the
Australian wine industry.
He is the recipient of several teaching awards including the
QUT Vice-Chancellor’s Award for Excellence in Learning and
Teaching, and the Australian Government Office for Learning
and Teaching Citation for Outstanding Contributions to Student
Learning.
KIM S. MACKENZIE has been a teaching and research
member of the Queensland University of Technology (QUT)
Business School for over 10 years and has assisted with
the teaching, learning and curriculum development of many
International Business and Business Technology–related
units. Kim’s research interests focus on the innovative use
of internet-based technologies and their global business
implications. Her PhD (2011) explored the social, technical and
macro societal pressures influencing the business adoption
of social networking services (social media), which identified
the enormous impact that social technologies were having at
the global business level. Her explorative research has been
published in the Journal of Developing Areas (2015), Journal
of Accounting & Organizational Change (2013), Accounting,
Auditing & Accountability Journal (2013), The International
Journal of Digital Accounting Research (2013), Pacific
Accounting Review (2013) and Electronic Commerce Research
(2009).
CAMERON GORDON is currently an Adjunct Associate
Professor at the Research School of Management at the
Australian National University (ANU). He also holds concurrent
appointments with the Research School of Economics at the
ANU; the Social Policy Simulation Center at the City University
of New York; and the Faculty of Health (Centre for Research
and Action in Public Health) at the University of Canberra. Prior
to that, Dr. Gordon held permanent faculty appointments in
Finance at the City University of New York and Public Policy at
the University of Southern California. He has taught graduate
and undergraduate International Business courses for over
10 years. Dr. Gordon’s research focuses on organisational
governance, public–private partnerships, transport and logistics
management, and the economics and ethics of offshoring. He
has published over 50 peer-reviewed journal articles and a
2016 book Behavioural Approaches to Corporate Governance,
published by Routledge Press. Before entering academia, he
had a long public service career focusing on economic and
policy research at the US National Academy of Sciences (Board
of Infrastructure and Constructed Environment); US Congress
Joint Committee on Taxation; and the US Army Corps of
Engineers, Institute for Water Resources.
ABOUT THE AUTHORS xv
hiL23674_fm_i-xxx.indd xv
08/06/19 05:52 PM
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
As with any endeavour of this type, this edition has been the
result of a team effort.
We would like to acknowledge the contribution of Cameron
Gordon (Australian National University), whose ‘Country Focus’
vignettes and discussion questions appear in each chapter of
the book.
We would like to thank Maralyn McDowell (Queensland
University of Technology), Áron Perényi (Swinburne University
of Technology) and Jeremy Seward (La Trobe University) for
their detailed reviews of the material during development.
We would like to thank our case contributors. They have
added the touch of colour that comes with presenting real-life
situations:
• Makoto Kanda, Meiji Gakuin University—Kaihara:
Globalisation of a shinise, a long-lived company (Chapter 1)
• Áron Perényi, Swinburne University of Technology—Global
innovation through the mobility of ideas and talent (Chapter 1)
• Brent Burmester, University of Auckland—Make it Australian?
Free trade versus national identity (Chapter 3) & The elusive
Elena Egorova (Chapter 6)
• Professor Songhua Hu, Sun Yat-sen University—The growth
strategy of Haier (Chapter 10)
• Saskia de Klerk, University of the Sunshine Coast—The Happy
Snack Company: This happy, healthy message is too good not
to share (Chapter 11) & Youi: Selling the you (Chapter 12).
Thanks to Peter Liesch for his contributing authorship for the
fourth edition.
We are also indebted to our ancillary authors who have
worked hard to ensure that we have a strong ancillary package.
Numerous people deserve to be thanked for their assistance
in preparing this book. First, we want to extend our sincere
thanks to all the people at McGraw-Hill who have worked with
us on this project: Portfolio managers Matthew Coxhill and
Jillian Gibbs, Content developer Anne Harmer and Production
editor Lara McMurray.
Rumintha is grateful to all of those who assisted him in his
early work as well as his doctoral studies, and who have fostered
his fascination with and enthusiasm for learning and teaching
global/international business. He is especially indebted to
Professors Norman Philp, Geoff Bamberry, Eddie Oczkowski
and Gordon Boyce for their support and encouragement. To
Thomas Cronk, co-author of the first three editions, Rumintha
extends his sincere thanks for his generous support and
innovative ideas in continually improving the book. He would
also like to pass on his sincere thanks to the many students
and colleagues who made a major contribution to the book by
providing valuable feedback. Finally, he would like to send a
very special thanks to his family for their continued support and
encouragement.
xvi GLOBAL BUSINESS TODAY
hiL23674_fm_i-xxx.indd
xvi
08/06/19 05:52 PM
LearnSmart Advantage is a series of adaptive learning products fuelled by LearnSmart—the most widely used
and adaptive learning resource proven to strengthen memory recall, increase retention and boost grades.
Adaptive learning
No two students are the same, so why should their learning
experience be? Adaptive technology uses continual
assessment and artificial intelligence to personalise the
learning experience for each individual student. As the global
leader in adaptive and personalised learning technologies,
McGraw-Hill Education is pioneering ways to improve results
and retention across all disciplines.
SmartBook
Fuelled by LearnSmart, SmartBook is the first and only
adaptive reading experience available today. Starting with an
initial preview of each chapter and key learning objectives,
students read material and are guided to the topics they most
need to practise at that time, based on their responses to a
continuously adapting diagnostic. To ensure concept mastery
and retention, reading and practice continue until SmartBook
directs students to recharge and review important material
they are most likely to forget.
LearnSmart
LearnSmart maximises learning productivity and efficiency by
identifying the most important learning objectives for each student
to master at a given point in time. It knows when students are
likely to forget specific information and revisits that content to
advance knowledge from their short-term to long-term memory.
LearnSmart is proven to improve academic performance, ensuring
higher retention rates and better grades.
To find out more about SmartBook visit
www.mheducation.com.au/student-smartbook
hiL23674_fm_i-xxx.indd xvii
08/06/19 05:52 PM
McGraw-Hill Connect® is the only learning platform that continually adapts to you, delivering precisely
what you need, when you need it.
Proven effective
With Connect, you can complete your coursework anytime, anywhere.
Millions of students have used Connect and the results are in: research
shows that studying with McGraw-Hill Connect will increase the
likelihood that you’ll pass your course and get a better grade.
Connect support
Connect includes animated tutorials, videos and additional
embedded hints within specific questions to help you succeed.
The Connect Success Academy for Students is where you’ll find
tutorials on getting started, your study resources and completing
assignments in Connect. Everything you need to know about
Connect is here!
Visual progress
Connect provides you with reports to help you identify what you
should study and when your next assignment is due, and tracks your
performance. Connect’s Overall Performance report allows you to
see all of your assignment attempts, your score on each attempt, the
date you started and submitted the assignment, and the date the
assignment was scored.
To learn more about McGraw-Hill Connect®, visit
www.mheducation.com.au/student-connect
xviii GLOBAL BUSINESS TODAY
hiL23674_fm_i-xxx.indd
xviii
08/06/19 05:52 PM
WHAT’S NEW IN THE FIFTH EDITION
The success of the first four editions of Global Business Today:
Asia–Pacific Perspective was based in part upon the incorporation
of leading-edge research into the text, the discussion of current
events within the context of the appropriate theory, and the use
of examples, cases and statistics that were not only up-to-date
but also relevant to our students to illustrate global trends and
enterprise strategy. Building on these strengths, our goals for this
revised edition have been five-fold:
1. Incorporate new insights from recent scholarly research
wherever appropriate.
2. Ensure the content of the text covers all appropriate issues.
3. Ensure the text is as up-to-date and as relevant to the
student cohort as possible with regard to current events,
statistics, examples and case studies.
4. Make the link between principle and practice by drawing
out the implications of concepts and ideas for international
business management and operations.
5. Provide the opportunity for the students and their instructors
to identify and attain the learning goals of their international
business education.
As part of the revision process, changes have been made to
every chapter in the book and we have taken into account the
reviews by our peers and our students. All material and statistics
are as up-to-date as possible as of late 2018. We have added
discussion on current events wherever appropriate. Examples
include Brexit, the growth of sovereign wealth funds, climate
change, the rise of emerging markets, growing nationalism
and the changing power balance in international economic
institutions and the increasing prevalence of regional economic
integration, in particular free trade agreements. In Chapter 5, the
discussion of culture has been broadened by the inclusion of
Ed Shein’s definition of culture as well as the GLOBE and WVS
frameworks. All opening and closing cases are either new or
have been significantly revised with updates and, in some cases,
a new focus. The ‘Country Focus’ features have all been replaced
with new vignettes focusing on Australia’s top trading partners
and they come with questions to assist with class discussion. The
‘Management Focus’ features have been updated and new ones
added. Graphs and tables have been updated and provide useful
visual snapshots of important statistics throughout all chapters.
Strategically commissioned cases by those who are experts in
their fields give detailed coverage of topics within a chapter.
Our case mix includes American, Middle-Eastern, European and
South-East Asian examples.
A continued feature of this edition is the inclusion of
International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs) in each
chapter, accompanied by applicable learning and assessment
tasks. The specification of the IBGAs and tasks in each chapter
informs the students on what learning outcomes are expected
and how they can demonstrate the attainment of these outcomes.
The scope of the IBGAs makes clear that what is expected from
a study of international business, and tertiary education more
generally, is more than the ability to recall the correct answer to
‘what’, ‘how’ and ‘why’ questions. For the instructor and course
designer, the specification of the IBGAs and assessment tasks
enables them to demonstrate where and how the IBGAs are
developed and assessed. This transparency is inherently an
accountability measure, but it is also a necessary requirement
for attaining external accreditation for a course of study. IBGA
matters are outlined in more detail on pages xxviii–xxx.
RUMINTHA WICKRAMASEKERA
May 2019
WHAT’S NEW IN THE FIFTH EDITION xix
hiL23674_fm_i-xxx.indd xix
08/06/19 05:52 PM
ORGANISATION/CONTENT
PART ONE GLOBALISATION
CHAPTER 1 GLOBALISATION
PART TWO CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES:
TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
CHAPTER 2 THEORIES OF TRADE,
INVESTMENT AND INTERNATIONALISATION
CHAPTER 3 THE POLITICAL ECONOMY
OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
CHAPTER 4 FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND
THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
HOME
COUNTRY
FOREIGN
COUNTRY
PART THREE COUNTRY DIFFERENCES
CHAPTER 6
CHAPTER 7 ECONOMIC
POLITICAL AND LEGAL
ENVIRONMENT
ENVIRONMENTS
CHAPTER 5
DIFFERENCES
IN CULTURE
CHAPTER 8 ETHICS
AND CORPORATE
RESPONSIBILITY
CHAPTER 9 COUNTRY MARKET RESEARCH
PART FOUR COMPETING IN THE
GLOBAL MARKETPLACE
CHAPTER 10 THE STRATEGY OF INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS
CHAPTER 11
ENTERING FOREIGN
MARKETS
CHAPTER 12
INTERNATIONAL
MARKETING/
BUSINESS ANALYTICS
CHAPTER 13
INTERNATIONAL
PRODUCTION,
OUTSOURCING
AND LOGISTICS
CHAPTER 14
INTERNATIONAL
HUMAN RESOURCE
MANAGEMENT
xx GLOBAL BUSINESS TODAY
hiL23674_fm_i-xxx.indd
xx
08/06/19 05:52 PM
A weakness of many texts is that they lack a tight, integrated
flow of topics from chapter to chapter. Another is that they fail
to give an overview of the scope and sequence of the content.
An overview helps by clarifying expectations of what will be
explored, to identify what is already known and to develop links
between the two. It establishes an overall framework for the
distinction and the links between the major ideas before delving
into the specifics. The figure on the opposite page provides an
overview of the scope and sequence of material in this book.
variables, especially foreign exchange rates. There have been
a number of internationally negotiated monetary agreements in
an effort to provide greater stability to exchange rates and the
international monetary system. Chapter 4 describes and explains
the international monetary system, laying out the monetary
framework in which international business transactions are
conducted, and describes how the exposures to financial risks
are managed.
PART ONE GLOBALISATION
Once a business goes international it may move into a vastly
different operating environment. Many of the central issues of
international business strategy and structure and international
business operations arise out of country differences. In order to
examine the strategies that firms adopt to compete in the different
operational environments, it is vital to discuss these country
differences first. Chapters 5–8 examine in detail four dimensions
of countries’ environments: cultural, political–legal, economic and
ethical. A systematic analysis of a country’s business environment
is one requirement for deciding whether to choose that country
as a potentially rewarding place to conduct business and as
the basis for formulating appropriate international business
strategies. Based on the understandings of the previous four
chapters, and as a precursor to the discussion on strategic
choices in the following chapters, Chapter 9 details financing
trade and the framework and information sources necessary to
undertake a comprehensive country market research.
Chapter 1 examines the process of globalisation. ‘Globalisation’
refers to the growing interdependencies among people and
institutions in different countries. While business is itself a force
of globalisation, it also needs to respond to globalisation. In the
study of international business, we need to understand what
drives the process of globalisation, appreciate how it is changing
the face of international business and understand why it has
become a source of conflict and debate. Chapter 1 provides an
overview of the key issues of the globalisation of business to be
addressed in future chapters, and explains the overall plan of the
book.
PART TWO CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE,
INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
Globalisation is evidenced by increasing links between countries,
particularly via trade, investment and financial flows. Chapter 2
provides explanations of trade and investment, and the
internationalisation of business. No country permits the free
flow of trade and investment across its borders. Governments
seek to influence trade and investment in order to achieve
economic, social and political objectives. Chapter 3 investigates
the political economy of trade and investment. The theories
introduced in Chapter 2 are used in Chapter 3 as a basis for
assessing government interventions and moves to reduce
restrictions through international negotiations, as occur under
the auspices of the World Trade Organization and regional
trade agreements. The world financial markets are truly global
phenomena, with actions by one country often affecting financial
variables in another. A challenge for international business
is managing exposures to often volatile changes in these
PART THREE COUNTRY DIFFERENCES
PART FOUR COMPETING IN THE GLOBAL
MARKETPLACE
In Chapters 10–14, attention shifts from the environment to
the firm. Here we examine the strategies that firms adopt to
compete effectively in the international business environment,
including international market entry strategies, and explain how
firms can perform key functions—marketing and R&D; production
and logistics; and human resource management—in order to
compete and succeed in the international business environment.
Throughout the book, the relationship of new material to
topics discussed in earlier chapters is pointed out to reinforce
students’ understanding of how the material comprises an
integrated whole.
ORGANISATION/CONTENT xxi
hiL23674_fm_i-xxx.indd xxi
08/06/19 05:52 PM
TEXT AT A GLANCE
This fifth edition of Global Business Today is a pedagogically rich learning resource. The features
laid out on these pages are specially designed to encourage and enhance an understanding of
the text content and the attainment of a broad scope of learning outcomes. Some of the unique
features of this text include:
OPENING CASE
OPENING CASE
KAIHARA: GLOBALISATION OF A
SHINISE, A LONG-LIVED COMPANY
Fukuyama city in Hiroshima Prefecture, Japan, used to
be known as Bingo. The name was synonymous with
its ‘Bingo kasuri’, a Japanese cotton kimono cloth with
a splashed pattern. In 1893, Kaihara, a family business
manufacturing kasuri, was established by Sukejiro Kaihara
in Bingo. It remained a comparatively small operation
until its transformation into Kaihara Textile Mills Ltd
in 1951. Since then, the company has grown to become
a world-renowned supplier of high-quality denim for
leading jeans manufacturers/brands such as Levi’s, fastfashion retailers like GAP and premium brands like Hugo
Boss. The company has more than a 50 per cent share of
the blue denim market in Japan and exports more than
70 per cent of its products. The company’s successful
internationalisation is illustrative of a traditional Japanese
company that has used its core domestic technology as a
stepping stone to become globally competitive.
CLOSING CASE
Each chapter begins with an Opening Case
that sets the stage for the chapter content
and details the real challenges in the
conducting of international business.
presented Kaihara with an opportunity to expand
overseas. In 1951, a trading company from Aden, Yemen,
was seeking a manufacturer able to supply sarong cloth
blended with the Japanese kasuri. After a failed attempt
to source from a company in Nishiwaki, Hyogo Prefecture
(due to manufacturing limitations), the company
approached Kaihara. Sarongs for children needed 36-inch
wide cloth, while for adults 48-inch cloth was required,
necessitating the stitching of two 24-inch cloths. In order
to improve the quality of the end product and limit the
stitching needed, Kaihara developed a machine capable of
producing 48-inch wide cloth. This innovation resulted
in a worker being able to operate four machines at a time,
resulting in a ten-fold efficiency gain in comparison with
producers in Indonesia.
MOVE TO DENIM
CLOSING CASE
GLOBAL INNOVATION THROUGH THE
MOBILITY OF IDEAS AND TALENT
Kaihara grew rapidly due to the cost-effective production
of sarongs and a newly developed wool kasuri fabric
that satisfied customer demand for softer kasuri in the
At the time the company was established there were
Japanese market. However, a crisis hit the company:
numerous kasuri makers in Japan. Therefore, from its
inception the company’s founder decided to focus on
political instability in the Middle East and devaluation
Zinemath
cPlc
is
a
born
global
technology
starta Hungarian
engineer designed
andofbuilt
the high-end market, with higher quality products
of and
the British
poundmilitary
led to overstocked
inventory
up. Ita has
investors
from
Italy
and talent
the first
cannon
the emperor
of Byzantium
in the
kasuri
sarong
cloth for
equivalent
to a year’s
production.
The
garnering
20–50
per cent
price
premium
overacquired
from Australia
and targets the US market. Its
15th century,
warfare. This
later
company
had to revolutionising
find a way to overcome
the crisis.
competitors’
products.
revolutionary approach to developing virtual reality
enabled the Ottoman Empire to conquer large parts
Sadaharu
Kaihara,
the president,
informed
by one
After World
War
II, Kaihara,reality
like other
companies,
(VR) and
augmented
(AR)Japanese
technology
for
of Europe
(including
Hungary).was
Porcelain
(originally
of called
his friends,
‘Jeans
have become
for the
rebuiltuse
its in
business.
The company
focused
on production
cinematography,
real-time
broadcasting
and
‘china’)
production
sprungfashionable
up in Meissen,
youngsters
Since
they are
imported
from
innovations,
as developing
and patenting
medicalsuch
visualisation
is opening
up newan
business
Germany,ininJapan.
the 18th
century
after
engineers
were
automatic
dyeing machine.
In addition,
it developed new
abroad,
why
don’t you
try to manufacture
themfind
using
opportunities
and potentially
revolutionising
able to
re-create
the production
process and
your
company’s
Traditionally,
kasuri
was
products
for the domestic
market.industries
Other innovations
operations
across multiple
from
local
resources.technology?’
These are examples
of how
ideas
dyed
using
the Japanese
indigo
plant,oflater
substituted
followed;
for example,
Kaiharacare
produced
the first 36-inch
broadcasting
to health
and education.
travel
around
the world
by means
trade
and the
wide kasuri fabric using an electric loom. However, due
with
indigo made
from oil.
The oil-based
was also
movement
of people.
Nowadays,
in the indigo
modern
to changing
market demand
used
for
denim,
and
Kaihara
had
expertise
in
using
trade,
with exceptions
grantedfrom
onlyWesternisation
under extreme and
pressure, may
not
be
the
optimal
policy
global innovation system, international education,the
Global
innovation
a significant
decrease
themay
wearing
kimonos,
artificial
dye. In
addition,
denim
had synergy
according
to the
theoryinbut
be theof best
policythe
that the country
is likely
to recruitment
get.41
collaboration,
and production
entrepreneurship
drive
company
hadmovement
limited sales
Instead,
innovation
with
weaving
technology.
Therefore,
Sadaharu
Global
of success.
ideas is as
old as this
global
trade
thekasuri
exchange
and sharing
of ideas
and other
resources
provided
theand
company
with
production
capacity
to
Kaihara
wenttotodevise
Tokyonew
to observe
the uptake
of jeans by
itself,
the two
are the
definitely
related.
A good
necessary
technologies
and products,
serviceexample
larger markets,
international
markets.
younger
of this isincluding
the technology
transfer
facilitated theand
access generation.
markets. He saw a significant market for
denim and decided to diversify into denim production.
the Silk
Road. In
ancient
times,inChinese
silk was
Whileby
kimono
wearing
was
in decline
Japan, ikat
Systems of innovation are described by the
transported
to Egypt.
Duringtextiles)
the Middle
(a dyeing
method used
to pattern
used Ages,
in this
In concept
1969, theofcompany
cheese-dyed
indigo
the rippleintroduced
helix, which
identifies the
intercontinental
tradecountries
route was
for the
denim
to of
thecomplex
Japanesetechnological
market. However,
the denim
Indonesia,
India and other
forresponsible
saris and sarongs
source
innovation
as an
transfer of technologies and ideas between Asia
outcome of collaboration between universities
and Europe. In the absence of long-haul flights, and
(research institutes), governments and industry
with
tools of navigation and propulsion for
4 PART
1 limited
GLOBALISATION
(businesses). These ‘interactions’ manifest by
seafaring, the American side of the Pacific was not
transferring intangible and tangible resources, such
accessible. (Although Maori reached all the way to the
knowledge,
people,
time on
money. to
Magnesium
allow the
mass production
ofasthe
industry, ideas,
the then
chairman
of task
AMCand
admitted
islandsalloys
of Aotearoa,
andeconomic
Chinese explorers
may have
Forreality
example,
governments
provide
grant funding
to
of
strong,
thin-walled,
lightweight shapes and objects.
the
of the
time that the
persistent
low
magnesium
arrived
at the
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd
4 shores of Australia much earlier, these
07/27/19 03:02 PM
universities,
on value
the condition
of workingdollar
together
Similargreat
aluminium
objects
wouldpermanent
be 50 pertrade
cent routes.)
heavier.
prices,
the high
of the Australian
and to
cheap
efforts did
not yield
help them
innovate.
Businesses
directly
contract
When it is used with aluminium it improves the strength,
metal
imports
from China
wouldmay
most
likely preclude
By means
of thisweld-ability
trade route,and
people
travelled,
universities
to conduct
research for them,
or help
corrosive
resistance,
tear-ability
of learned any
new investment
in magnesium
smelting
in Australia.
and transferred
across different
parts
themprophetic
to collectthose
ideas and
recruit talent
aluminium.
In the lateknowledge
1990s, magnesium
was hailed
How
sentiments
were. through
the world.
envoy
of the
the demand
Byzantine
emperor,
collaboration with students (class projects, internships,
as theofmetal
of the An
future,
with
from
the
Inevents).
the meantime,
AMC
looked to provide
move on.
By 2006, it
Justinian,
smuggled
silkexpected
worm eggs
of China,
And finally,
governments
funding
world’s
automotive
industry
to out
be immense.
had
changed
business
model
as a reflection
hidden inspawned
bamboo a
sticks,
to start
silk production in
for the
higherits
education
sector
andand,
for research
This optimism
number
of mineral-processing
ofinstitutes
the newto
direction,
it changed
name to Advanced
the
Middle
East
in
the
6th
century.
Marco
Polo,
the
provide research
andits
development
proposals in Australia, a process that turns raw
Magnesium
Limited public
(AML).good,
The Brisbane-based
AML’s
Italian
merchant
born
in
Venice,
travelled
to
China
services
supporting
and
to
train
the next
magnesite into finished magnesium. The largest proposal
principal
activities
were
researching,
developing,
back
many
things like
noodles in the
generation
of experts
andnow
professionals
to enable
them
at the and
timebrought
was that
of the
Australian
Magnesium
manufacturing
newand
proprietary
magnesium
13th/14th
centuries.
The Ottoman
acquired
to contribute toand
theselling
economic
social development
Corporation
(AMC).
It proposed
buildingEmpire
a $1.7 billion,
alloys
and
technologies
to
die
casters
for
end
use
in
thetonnes
secretsper
of year,
gunpowder
around
the at
14th
century,
of the country.
90 000
processing
plant
Stanwell,
the automotive, electronics and hardware industries.
near Rockhampton, Queensland. As it was unable to
AML no longer sought to manufacture magnesium
purchase an existing technology in what was now a very
or its proprietary alloys itself. Instead, it outsourced
competitive global market, AMC with the assistance
the manufacture of its alloys under licence to alloy
of the CSIRO developed its own low-cost process
producers in China, Japan and Europe—AML’s main
technology. It built and operated a demonstration plant
regional markets.
to prove the technology to potential investors. To the
CHAPTER 1 GLOBALISATION 49
regional and national economies, the project promised
In 2008–09, AML made another change to its business
2000 jobs and $500 million in revenue per year.
model. It identified a number of weaknesses with
the licensing agreements with manufacturers. AML
During 2000–03, AMC set about raising capital and
realised that it lacked control over its supply 07/27/19
chain 03:02 PM
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 49
commenced construction. However, signs of trouble
and as a consequence, the quality of the product
soon began to appear. Construction costs rose
and the quality of service provided to its customers
above expectations and there was a shortfall in the
protectionist
right-wing politicians
such
asreturned
Donald Trump.
For over half a century, the US and other developed
was
falling. Consequently,
in 2009,
AML
to
capital raising. The state government of Queensland
Will their mercantilist
views (see
Chapter
an
countries championed free trade and globalisation. It
manufacturing
its magnesium
alloys
itself.2)It bring
entered
provided $100 million to guarantee dividend payments
endato
globalisation?
Is globalisation
theakey
reason for
brought unprecedented growth and prosperity to millions into
joint
venture to build
and operate
greenfield
to investors for three years. It provided another
the loss of manufacturing
in the
developed
countries,
as
of people around the world. However, it hollowed out
magnesium
facility in China,
Henan Keweier
Alloy
$50
for infrastructure
assistance.
The national
suggested
protectionist
politicians?
themillion
manufacturing
sector and
increased income
Materials
Co.byLtd
(HNKWE), of
which AML owned 53 per
government
provided
$100
million leading
to guarantee
loans
inequality in
developed
countries,
to the rise
of
cent. HNKWE supplied AML’s alloys to all its customers
and another $50 million for CSIRO to develop the new
in China, Europe, the United States and Japan. China
processing technology.
is the world’s biggest producer of both primary
SOURCE: T. Meyer and G. Sitaraman ‘A Trade Policy for All: Market Liberalization Should Be a Means, Not an End’, Foreign Affairs, 26 June 2018,
magnesium ingot (90 per cent of the global supply) and
After
four years, with the plant in the very early phases
accessed via www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/2018-06-26/trade-policy-all, on 3 July 2019.
magnesium alloys. AML’s executive chairman at the time
of construction, in June 2003 the project collapsed and
of establishing the joint venture declared, ‘[T]he ideal
was mothballed. Shareholders lost $500 million and
location in Henan province, the availability of skilled
taxpayers lost $240 million after salvaging some assets.
labour and the support of both local and provincial
The blowout in the construction costs was widely
governments should ensure that the company makes
broadcast as the cause of the collapse, but perhaps
Many of the former Communist nations of Europe and Asia seem to have shown a
significant market inroads over the next 12 months’.
there were more fundamental causes. In an assessment
ACCUMULATION OF TECHNOLOGIES
Each chapter ends with a Closing Case
that is designed to illustrate the relevance
of the chapter material to the practice of
international business, as well as to provide
continued insight into how real companies
handle those issues.
MANAGEMENT FOCUS
TRYING TO PICK A WINNER: GOVERNMENT
SUPPORT OF THE MAGNESIUM INDUSTRY
There is at least one Management Focus
box in every chapter. Like the Opening
Cases, the purpose of these is to illustrate
the relevance of chapter material to the
practice of international business.
ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
RISE OF PROTECTIONISM
commitment to democratic politics and free market economies. If this continues, the
opportunities for international businesses will continue to be enormous. For half a century,
these countries were essentially closed to Western international businesses. Now they
present a host of export and investment opportunities. Just how this will play out over the
CHAPTER 3 THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
next decade or two is difficult to say. The economies of many of the former Communist
states are still relatively undeveloped, and their continued commitment to democracy
and free market economies cannot be taken for granted. Disturbing signs of growing
unrest and totalitarian tendencies continue to be seen in several Eastern European and
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd 121
07/27/19
Central Asian states, including Russia, which under the presidencies of Vladimir Putin and
Dmitry Medvedev have shown signs of shifting back towards greater state involvement in
economic activity. Findings from Freedom in the World 2015, Freedom House’s annual report
on the state of global freedom, reveal that democracy declined worldwide for the tenth
year in 2015, particularly in the Middle East.36 Thus, the risks involved in doing business in
such countries are high, but so may be the returns.
The 2007–09 GFC caused a reassessment of the extent to which governments
should intervene in Western industrialised economies. To this point in time,
the dominant ideology was one of free markets, private ownership and reduced
government regulation. The events of the GFC, however, brought into question the efficacy
of such a model. For fear of systemic collapse, governments became convinced that they had
to usurp the market and intervene. The US and the UK governments bought controlling
interests in private businesses—in effect, for a country such as the United Kingdom, this
meant reversing the privatisation trend by renationalising parts of industry. In the United
States, for example, the government bought 61 per cent of General Motors (GM), once one
of the largest, private non-financial multinationals in the world, and in addition provided
loans from taxpayer funds to assist GM through bankruptcy. The UK government took
control of three financial institutions—the Royal Bank of Scotland, Lloyd’s Banking Group
MANAGEMENT FOCUS
ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
121
Learning is easier and clearer if the subject
matter is communicated in an interesting,
informative and accessible manner. The
Another Perspective boxes allow interesting
anecdotes and alternative perspectives
to be woven into the narrative of the text.
They also provide additional context to the
chapter topics.
03:41 PM
xxii GLOBAL BUSINESS TODAY
hiL23674_fm_i-xxx.indd
xxii
08/06/19 05:52 PM
EMERGING MARKETS
INDIA’S IT SOFTWARE SECTOR
Some 25 years ago, a number of small software
enterprises was established in Bangalore, India. Typical
of these enterprises was Infosys Technologies, which
was started by seven Indian entrepreneurs with about
$1000 among them. Infosys now has annual revenues
of $7.4 billion and some 155 600 employees, but it is
just one of more than a hundred software companies
clustered around Bangalore, which has become the
epicentre of India’s fast-growing information technology
sector. From a standing start in the mid-1980s, by 2012
this sector was generating export sales of $68 billion.
The growth of the Indian software sector has been
based on four factors. First, the country has an
abundant supply of engineering talent. Every year,
Indian universities graduate some 400 000 engineers.
Second, labour costs in India have historically been
low. As recently as 2008, the cost to hire an Indian
graduate was roughly 12 per cent of the cost of
hiring an American or Australian graduate (this is now
changing, with salaries increasing in India). Third, many
Indians are fluent in English, which makes coordination
between Western companies and India easier. Fourth,
due to time differences, Indians can work while many
other advanced English-speaking countries are asleep.
EMERGING MARKETS
Initially, Indian software enterprises focused on the
low end of the software industry, supplying basic
software development and testing services to Western
companies. But as the industry has grown in size and
sophistication, Indian companies have moved up the
market. Today, the leading Indian companies compete
directly with the likes of IBM and EDS for large
software development projects, business process
outsourcing contracts, and information technology
consulting services. Over the past 15 years, these
markets have boomed, with Indian enterprises
capturing a large slice of the pie. One response of
Western companies to this emerging competitive
threat has been to invest in India to garner the same
kind of economic advantages that Indian companies
enjoy. IBM, for example, has invested $2 billion in its
Indian operations and now has 150 000 employees
located there, more than in any other country.
Microsoft, too, has made major investments in India,
including a research and development (R&D) centre in
Hyderabad that employs 4000 people and was located
there specifically to tap into talented Indian engineers
who did not want to move overseas.
FOCUS ON
MANAGERIAL IMPLICATIONS
INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS GRADUATE
ATTRIBUTES (IBGAs)
SOURCES: ‘America’s pain, India’s gain: outsourcing’, The Economist, 11 January 2003, p. 59; ‘The world is our oyster’, The Economist, 7 October 2006,
Throughout
we have
now
the2007,
Australian
appreciates
towards
pp. 9–10; ‘IBM and globalization:
hungrythis
tiger,chapter
dancing elephant’,
The Economist,
7 April
pp. 67–69;dollar
P. Mishra,
‘New billing model
may hitparity,
India’s
LO 4.4
alluded
on several
occasions
to the
illustrated
moving19down
left-hand column of
software exports’,
Live Mint,
14 February
2013; ‘India’s
outsourcing
business: on
the turn’, Theby
Economist,
Januarythe
2013.
potential impact on international
Tables 4.3A and 4.3B. If the manufacturer passes
business of changes in foreign exchange rates. It is
through 100 per cent of the impact of the exchange
This chapter’s content, learning resources
and case studies provide you with the
critical that international companies understand the
rate change, as in Table 4.3A, US prices rise. If the
opportunity
to
develop
a
number
of
International
Business
(IBGAs),
influence of exchange rates on the profitability of trade
exchange rate
went Graduate
to parity, itAttributes
would result
in a
including
the
following:
share.
Their
share hascontracts.
almost halved
over in
theexchange
past decade
as developing
economies
suchofas60 per cent. If the exchange
and
investment
Changes
rates
significant
price rise
about changes
the prices
of traded
goods
rate
went
$1.40, the
price increase would be
the bring
BRIC nations
attract ainlarger
share. As
we shall
see later in this
book,
thetosustained
flow
and services.
Setting
price to nations
remain is
competitive
14 perfor
cent.
With agrowth.
price rise in the US, sales would
of foreign
investment
into the
developing
an important stimulus
economic
IBGA1
Discipline
Knowledge and
Skills to fall and market share to decline. The
maintain economy
market
share
in foreign
markets
be expected
Just and
as Australia’s
has relied
on FDI
to fuelisitsalso
development,
particularly via the
complicated
bymining
exchange
rateattracting
changes,
as adverse
the fall,
and the extent to which the exporter
IBGA2
Criticalmore
Analysis
development
of its
sector,
FDI bodes wellextent
for theoffuture
of countries
put at
riskand
apparently
profitable
is willing
to pass through the exchange
suchchanges
as Brazil,can
Russia,
India
China,
who
are thedeals.
leading beneficiaries
of and
theseable
trends.
IBGA5
Communication
In this section, we look at the
impact
of
exchange
rate
change,
depends
on a number
Onesystem
such inequalities benefit everyone. Rawls
accepts
that inequalities
canofbefactors.
just if the
IBGA7 that
Global
Perspective
rate changes on international
business
operations
in
factor
is
the
sensitivity
of More
customers
to price
changes.
produces inequalities is to the advantage of everyone.
precisely,
he formulates
more detail, and how
companies
may
manage
these principle,
If USwhich
customers
farm machinery
for non-price
IBGA9
Citizenship
what
hemultinational
calls
the difference
is that buy
inequalities
are justified
if they benefit
The
changing
nature
of
the
enterprise
impacts. We begin by looking at the relationship
reasons, such as unique capability, the fall in sales
the position of the least advantaged person. So, for example, wide variations in income
between exchange
rates
and the
pricing
of goods has
in productive
will notactivities
be as great when prices
rise. Another factor
A multinational
enterprise
(MNE)
any
business
MULTINATIONAL
andis wealth
can bethat
considered
just if the
market-based system that
produces this unequal
foreign
markets.
We follow
discussion
of the trends in
is the
ofofcompetition. IfENTERPRISE
other American
and
(MNE)
in two
or more
countries.
Sincewith
the a1960s,
two
notable
the amount
character
distribution
also
benefits
least-advantaged
members
ofmanufacturers
society.
can
argue
that a well
AnyOne
business
that
has
productive
risks to which
business
canbeen
be exposed
as aof
result
ofthe
foreign farm
machinery
offer
similar
multinational
enterprises
have
(1)
the
rise
non-US
multinationals;
(2)by
the
market-based
and free and
trade,
promoting
growth,
benefit
activities
two
or more
countries
exchange rate changes andregulated,
the strategies
they mayeconomy
machines,
a price
rise
is likelyeconomic
to
see ain marked
fall
growth of mini-multinationals.
1.1
the process
and
driversInof
globalisation
and
the
theExplain
least-advantaged
members
ofinsociety.
principle,
at least,
the
inherent
employ to mitigate these risks.
market share.
A third
factor
is inequalities
the impact of
the
opportunities
and challenges
it creates
for‘rising
business.
in such
systems are therefore
just
(in other
words,
the
tide’
of wealth
created by
exchange
rate
change
on
the
costs
of production.
If a
market-based
economy
and
free
trade
‘lifts
all
boats’,
even
those
of
the
most
disadvantaged).
a
large
proportion
of
inputs
to
the
production
of
1.2
how the global economy has changed
over 1theGLOBALISATION
past the 27
EXCHANGE RATES
ANDIllustrate
SETTING
CHAPTER
farm
machines
in Australia
are imported,
costs
InPRICE
the context
of international
business
ethics,
Rawls’ theory
creates anthe
interesting
50
years.
imported inputs
will
decrease
as a result
perspective.
could askofthemselves
whether
the
policies they
adopt of
in the
foreign
With dramatic swings in exchange
rates,Managers
particularly
appreciation
of theveil
Australian
dollar.
a result,
the
Justify
the
labelling
of the
century
as
the
Emerging
in a freely floating1.3
exchangeoperations
rate
regime,
setting
would
be considered
just21st
under
Rawls’
of ignorance.
Is As
it just,
for example,
can be
lowered
andRawls’
the foreign
prices for internationally traded
goods
is aCentury.
challenge
to pay
foreign
workers
less thanex-factory
workers inprice
the firm’s
home
country?
theoryprice
would
Markets
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 27
07/27/19 03:02 PM
rise can
be reduced.
for international business management.
extent
suggest it is, The
as long
as the inequality
benefits
the least-advantaged members of the global
1.4 business
Debate
the
impact
of globalisation on issues such as job security,
to which an international
adjusts
prices
in
society (which is what economicIf theory
suggests). Alternatively,
it is difficult
to imagine
all the price-sensitivity
factors align
adversely
against
a income
foreign market
as the and the
inequality
environment.
the exporter
may be
forced to
accept
veilexporter,
of ignorance
would design
a system
where
foreign
EXCHANGE RATE PASS-THROUGH that managers operating under athe
result of an exchange
The extent to which an international
lower
mark-ups.
This
illustrated
in Tablediffers
4.3B. If in
employees
werehow
paid the
subsistence
wages
to of
work
longishours
inbusiness
sweatshop
conditions
1.5
Compare
management
international
rate change is called
business adjusts prices in a foreign
the materials.
US market for this
type of
farm machinery
is very
which
they
were
exposed to toxic
working
conditions
are clearly
unjust
from
the
management
of
domesticSuch
business.
rate
passmarket as the result of an exchange exchange
price-sensitive,
as to
illustrated
here,Similarly,
the exporter
may
in
Rawls’
framework
and,
therefore,
it
is
unethical
adopt
them.
operating
rate change
through.
be forced to price to what the market determines—in
Most chapters include an Emerging Markets
box that examines the nature of these
markets and economies, their evolving role
in the global economy and the implications
for international business management.
FOCUS ON MANAGERIAL IMPLICATIONS
Showing how the material covered in the text is
relevant to the actual practice of international business
is important. This is done explicitly in Chapters 2–7,
which focus on the practice of managing international
business rather than just the environmental issues.
LEARNING OBJECTIVES (LOs)
under a veil of ignorance, most people would probably design a system that imparts
this case, US$21 875. In other words, the exporter has
We can illustrate the type ofsome
pricing
dilemmafrom environmental
protection
degradation to important global commons, such
no market power to adjust prices upwards and must
confronted by exporters and the pass-through concept
as the oceans, atmosphere and tropical rainforests. To the extent that this is the case, it
take the US dollar price as a given. In this situation,
with the numerical examples in Tables 4.3A and 4.3B.
follows that it is unjust, and by extension
unethical, for
companies
to pursue
actions that
when the Australian
dollar
appreciates,
the impact
Suppose the ex-factory price of the Australian
contribute towards extensive degradation
of these
commons.
Thus,
Rawls’ veil
of the
ignorance
of the exchange
rate
change is
on mark-ups
and
produced farm machinery is A$35 000 and the current
is a conceptual
toolinthat contributes
to theprice.
moralThe
compass
that managers
can
useas
to help
ex-factory
pass-through
is 0 per
cent,
exchange rate is A$1.60 = US$1.00.
The price
themrate
navigate
through
ethical
dilemmas. exports are priced to the market
motor-vehicle
the US market at this exchange
is US$21
875, difficult the
conditions. If the impact of exchange rate appreciation
ignoring all transaction costs and assuming the
is such that it causes substantial cuts to ex-factory
manufacturer and all agents through the supply chain
prices, a scenario arises that the export venture is no
are satisfied that the existing mark-ups at these
longer a sound business proposition. Of course, if the
prices give acceptable sales and profits. Suppose
196
PART 2
On 1 December 2018, Meng Wanzhou, the chief
Chinese tech company Huawei,
was detained in Vancouver, Canada, at the request
of US authorities. US prosecutors accused Wanzhou
of helping Huawei to cover up violations of economic
sanctions on Iran. In response, the Chinese
government arrested and detained a number of
Canadians in China. The underlying controversy
motivating this tit-for-tat was US distrust of Huawei as
a technology company and its decision, soon followed
by other close US allies, to limit the company’s ability
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 3
to participate as a provider of the roll-out of nextgeneration 5G mobile networks.
PART 3
INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS
GRADUATE ATTRIBUTES (IBGAs):
LEARNING AND ASSESSMENT TASKS
378
IBGA1: DISCIPLINE KNOWLEDGE
AND SKILLS
1. ‘Japan is a neo-mercantilist nation. It protects industries
where it has no competitive advantage in the world
economy, such as domestic agriculture, while demanding
that other countries open those markets where Japanese
producers have a competitive advantage, such as cars.’
Discuss this statement.
2. Unions in developed nations often oppose imports
from low-wage countries such as Bangladesh and
advocate trade barriers to protect jobs from what they
often characterise as ‘unfair’ import competition. Is such
competition ‘unfair’? Do you think that this argument is
in the best interests of: (a) the unions; (b) the people they
represent; and/or (c) the country as a whole?
3. Drawing upon the new trade theory and Porter’s
model of national competitive advantage, outline the
case for government policies that would build national
competitive advantage in a particular industry. What
kinds of policies would you recommend that the
government adopt? Are these policies at variance with
the basic free trade philosophy?
IBGA3: PROBLEM SOLVING
4. One of the most significant factor endowments is
education, with important measures being the literacy
rate and the literacy rate gap between the genders.
Which of the following countries do you think has the
highest literacy rate and which country has the largest
literacy gap between males and females: (a) Iraq (b)
Rwanda (c) Chile (d) India?
IBGA4: ETHICAL DECISION MAKING
5. ‘The world’s poorest countries are at a competitive
disadvantage in every sector of their economies. They
have little to export. They have no capital, their land is
of poor quality, they often have too many people given
the available work opportunities and they are poorly
educated. Free trade cannot possibly be in the interests
of such nations!’ Discuss.
IBGA5: COMMUNICATION
6. You are the international manager of an Australian or
a New Zealand business that has just developed a
PART 2
COUNTRY FOCUS
Politics obscured the question of whether Huawei had in
07/26/19
fact subverted sanctions against Iran. These had
been09:04 PM
imposed under United Nations Security Council (UNSC)
resolutions 1696 (2006), 1737 (2006), 1747 (2007),
1803 (2008) and 1929 (2010) and were designed to stop
Iran from conducting its uranium enrichment program.
The Iranian government
said that
activities were for3
CHAPTER
1 itsGLOBALISATION
civilian nuclear power, but the international community
claimed that it was in fact for the development of atomic
weapons. Individual nations such as the US imposed
their own additional sanctions. International companies
07/27/19 03:02 PM
were thus forbidden from providing a whole range
of goods and services to Iran, especially sensitive
Every chapter has a Country Focus box that
provides students with the background on
the political, economic, cultural and ethical
aspects of Australia’s top 14 trading partners
as they deal with global business issues.
COUNTRY DIFFERENCES
hiL23674_ch08_351-390.indd
96
Each chapter starts with a list of the
chapter’s learning objectives and they flag
what you should know when you have
worked through the chapter. The text within
the chapter that is related to a learning
objective has the globe symbol beside it.
COUNTRY FOCUS
IRAN: VIOLATING SANCTIONS
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd
financial officer196of
378
LEARNING OBJECTIVES
07/29/19 08:54 PM
revolutionary new personal computer that can perform
the same functions as PCs but costs only half as much
to manufacture. Your CEO has asked you to formulate a
recommendation for how to expand into the European
Union market. Your options are: (a) to export from your
home market; (b) to license a European company to
manufacture and market the computer in Europe; and (c)
to set up a wholly owned subsidiary in Europe. Evaluate
the pros and cons of each alternative and write a brief
report suggesting a course of action to your CEO.
7. The UNCTAD World Investment Report and its World
Investment Directory provide quick electronic access to
comprehensive statistics on foreign direct investment
and the operations of transnational corporations.
Compile a list of the largest transnational corporations
in terms of their FDI and identify their home country
(i.e. headquarters country). Then provide a 15-minute
commentary about the characteristics of countries that
have the greatest number of transnational companies.
IBGA6: SOCIAL INTERACTION
8. Your company is considering opening a new factory in
an Asian country, and management is evaluating the
specific country locations for this direct investment.
The pool of candidate countries has been narrowed to
China, India and Thailand. Form a small group of four
or five peers and prepare a short report comparing the
FDI environment and location advantage of these three
countries.
IBGA2: CRITICAL ANALYSIS
9. CASE ANALYSIS Read the Opening Case, ‘Bangladesh’s
textile trade’ again, and answer the following questions.
a. How has Bangladesh benefited from free trade and
globalisation?
INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS GRADUATE
ATTRIBUTES: LEARNING AND ASSESSMENT TASKS
Graduate attributes are the qualities, skills and
understandings a student is expected to develop
throughout their course of study. It is a part of sound
teaching and learning practice to spell out to students in
advance an aligned set of learning goals, learning tasks
and assessment tasks. Educational institutions also are
being asked to demonstrate explicitly to both students
and external agencies where and how in their curriculum
they are developing specified graduate attributes and
assessing their attainment. This text sets out a framework
for developing and assessing graduate attributes for
international business studies. This framework is
discussed in more detail in the following section.
b. What did the end of the quota system mean for that
country?
c. Using Porter’s diamond of competitive advantage,
explain Bangladesh’s competitive advantage in the
production of textiles.
d. How important are Bangladesh’s supporting
industries to its textile trade?
10. CASE ANALYSIS Read the following Closing Case and
answer the questions that follow.
TEXT AT A GLANCE xxiii
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd
hiL23674_fm_i-xxx.indd xxiii
96
07/29/19 08:49 PM
08/08/19 11:30 AM
CASE AND VIGNETTE MATRIX
PART ONE GLOBALISATION
CHAPTER 1 GLOBALISATION
OPENING CASE
KAIHARA: GLOBALISATION OF A SHINISE, A LONG-LIVED COMPANY
ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
RISE OF PROTECTIONISM
EMERGING MARKETS
INDIA’S IT SOFTWARE SECTOR
MANAGEMENT FOCUS
THE GLOBALISATION OF PRODUCTION AT BOEING
WHO MAKES THE APPLE IPHONE?
COUNTRY FOCUS
CHINA: BELT AND ROAD INITIATIVE
CLOSING CASE
GLOBAL INNOVATION THROUGH THE MOBILITY OF IDEAS AND TALENT
PART TWO CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
CHAPTER 2 THEORIES OF TRADE, INVESTMENT AND INTERNATIONALISATION
OPENING CASE
BANGLADESH’S TEXTILE TRADE
EMERGING MARKETS
BRAZIL’S EMBRAER
MANAGEMENT FOCUS
HOLLOWING OUT THE MANUFACTURING-BASED ECONOMY
COUNTRY FOCUS
INDIA: LONG-TERM OPPORTUNITIES FOR BILATERAL TRADE AND INVESTMENT
CLOSING CASE
LOGITECH’S GLOBAL APPROACH
CHAPTER 3 THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
OPENING CASE
UNEASE OVER CHINA’S RARE EARTH TRADE POLICIES
ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
FREE TRADE AND EFFICIENCY VS FAIR TRADE AND JUSTICE
A LICENCE TO PROFIT
PATENTS VERSUS PATIENTS
EMERGING MARKETS
THE BRICS: ELECTRICAL APPLIANCES AND CONTRARY ENERGY-EFFICIENCY POLICIES
MANAGEMENT FOCUS
TRYING TO PICK A WINNER: GOVERNMENT SUPPORT OF THE MAGNESIUM INDUSTRY
SANCTIONS, U-TURNS AND ACCUSATIONS OF MONEY LAUNDERING AT STANDARD CHARTERED
COUNTRY FOCUS
USA: THE NEW PROTECTIONISM
CLOSING CASE
MAKE IT AUSTRALIAN? FREE TRADE VERSUS NATIONAL IDENTITY
CHAPTER 4 FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
OPENING CASE
THE MEXICAN PESO, THE JAPANESE YEN AND POKÉMON GO
ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
THE RISE OF CRYPTOCURRENCIES
GROWING PAINS WITH THE EURO
WHAT ABOUT THE STARBUCKS INDEX: A GOOD IDEA?
SHOULD COUNTRIES BE FREE TO SET CURRENCY POLICY?
CAN DOLLARISATION SAVE VENEZUELA?
EMERGING MARKETS
CHINA’S EXCHANGE RATE REGIME
MANAGEMENT FOCUS
EMBRAER AND THE GYRATIONS OF THE BRAZILIAN REAL
COUNTRY FOCUS
EGYPT AND THE IMF
IMF AND ICELAND’S ECONOMIC RECOVERY
CLOSING CASE
THE FLUCTUATING VALUE OF THE YUAN GIVES CHINESE BUSINESS A LESSON IN FOREIGN
EXCHANGE RISK
xxiv GLOBAL BUSINESS TODAY
hiL23674_fm_i-xxx.indd
xxiv
08/06/19 05:52 PM
PART THREE COUNTRY DIFFERENCES
CHAPTER 5 DIFFERENCES IN CULTURE
OPENING CASE
EVOLVING CULTURE AT PANASONIC
ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
ONLINE VIEW OF OTHER CULTURES
RELIGIOUS FUNDAMENTALISM
ADAPTING TO SUIT THE LOCAL PALATE
STICKY PROBLEMS IN CULTURE RESEARCH
EMERGING MARKETS
ISLAMIC BANKING IN MALAYSIA
A TALE OF TWO COUNTRIES
MANAGEMENT FOCUS
DMG ENTERTAINMENT
COUNTRY FOCUS
BREAKING INDIA’S CASTE SYSTEM AND GENDER DISCRIMINATION
INDONESIA: CROSS-CULTURAL AND GEOPOLITICAL
CLOSING CASE
COGNITION CONSULTING: EXPORTING NEW ZEALAND’S EDUCATIONAL EXPERTISE AND CULTURE
CHAPTER 6 POLITICAL AND LEGAL ENVIRONMENTS
OPENING CASE
TRANSFORMATION IN SAUDI ARABIA
ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
DO YOU AGREE WITH THE UNIQUE SYSTEM OF ISLAMIC BANKING?
HOW IMPORTANT ARE INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS?
EMERGING MARKETS
THE DECLINE OF ZIMBABWE
INDIVIDUAL RIGHTS AND FREEDOMS IN THE BRICS
MANAGEMENT FOCUS
DID WALMART VIOLATE THE FOREIGN CORRUPT PRACTICES ACT?
STARBUCKS WINS KEY TRADEMARK CASE IN CHINA
COUNTRY FOCUS
RUSSIA: EASING BUSINESS ENVIRONMENT OR UNCERTAIN FUTURE?
CLOSING CASE
THE ELUSIVE ELENA EGOROVA
CHAPTER 7 ECONOMIC ENVIRONMENT
OPENING CASE
BRAZIL’S STRUGGLING ECONOMY
ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
DISCONNECT OF THE VIRTUAL AND THE PHYSICAL WORLDS
IF WE ON EARTH WERE A COMMUNITY OF 100 PEOPLE . . .
EMERGING MARKETS
THE DEVELOPMENT PERFORMANCE OF EMERGING MARKET ECONOMIES
MANAGEMENT FOCUS
FONTERRA AND THE CHANGING DEMAND FOR DAIRY PRODUCTS IN THE EMERGING MARKETS OF ASIA
COUNTRY FOCUS
CANADA AND AUSTRALIA: SIMILAR YET DIFFERENT?
CLOSING CASE
ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT IN BANGLADESH
CHAPTER 8 ETHICS AND CORPORATE RESPONSIBILITY
OPENING CASE
SUSTAINABILITY INITIATIVES AT NATURA COSMETICS, THE BODY SHOP AND AESOP
ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
SUSTAINABILITY REPORTING
MODERN SLAVERY ACT (AUSTRALIA)
ARE HUMAN RIGHTS A MORAL COMPASS?
TACKLING TAX AVOIDANCE
MANAGEMENT FOCUS
CORPORATE SOCIAL RESPONSIBILITY AT STORA ENSO
PRESSURE ON NIKE CONTINUES
‘EMISSIONSGATE’ AT VOLKSWAGEN
CASE AND VIGNETTE MATRIX xxv
hiL23674_fm_i-xxx.indd xxv
08/06/19 05:52 PM
COUNTRY FOCUS
IRAN: VIOLATING SANCTIONS
CLOSING CASE
WOOLWORTHS’ CORPORATE RESPONSIBILITY STRATEGY
CHAPTER 9 COUNTRY MARKET RESEARCH
OPENING CASE
SPOTIFY AND SOUNDCLOUD
ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
ARE FIRST-MOVER ADVANTAGES ALWAYS A GOOD THING?
EMERGING MARKETS
TATA MOTORS AND EXPORTING
MANAGEMENT FOCUS
EXPORTING OR LICENSING?
EMBRAER AND BRAZILIAN IMPORTING
TWO MEN AND A TRUCK
COUNTRY FOCUS
PAKISTAN: THE COSTS OF CORRUPTION
CLOSING CASE
JOLLIBEE: A MULTINATIONAL COMPANY FROM THE PHILIPPINES
PART FOUR COMPETING IN THE GLOBAL MARKETPLACE
CHAPTER 10 THE STRATEGY OF INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS
OPENING CASE
RED BULL’S GLOBAL STRATEGY
ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
EDUCATION AS A PART OF YOUR VALUE CHAIN
LONG-LIVED COMPANIES
EMERGING MARKETS
PEARL RIVER PIANO COMPANY
MANAGEMENT FOCUS
IKEA: EVOLUTION OF STRATEGY
CISCO SYSTEMS AND FUJITSU
COUNTRY FOCUS
NEW ZEALAND: AN ADJACENCY PLAY
CLOSING CASE
THE GROWTH STRATEGY OF HAIER
CHAPTER 11 ENTERING FOREIGN MARKETS
OPENING CASE
INTERNATIONAL MARKET ENTRY AT STARBUCKS
ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
EXPORTING OR LICENSING?
SO, YOU THINK YOU WANT TO OWN A FRANCHISE?
ALDI IN AUSTRALIA
IS COUNTERTRADE AN APPROPRIATE WAY OF TRADING TODAY?
EMERGING MARKETS
JCB IN INDIA
COUNTRY FOCUS
MALAYSIA OPENS UP SOME TRADE
MANAGEMENT FOCUS
THE NEED TO GO INTERNATIONAL
AUSTRALIAN TURNTABLE COMPANY
TESCO’S INTERNATIONAL GROWTH STRATEGY
CLOSING CASE
THE HAPPY SNACK COMPANY: THIS HAPPY, HEALTHY MESSAGE IS TOO GOOD NOT TO SHARE
CHAPTER 12 INTERNATIONAL MARKETING/BUSINESS ANALYTICS
OPENING CASE
BURBERRY’S SOCIAL MEDIA MARKETING
ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
MARKETING FAILURES—VEGEMITE’S ISNACK 2.0
LOST IN TRANSLATION
IS THE KIWIFRUIT A KIWI FRUIT?
DESTINATION AND COUNTRY BRANDING
FAKE NEWS AND ALTERNATIVE FACTS
EMERGING MARKETS
UNILEVER: SELLING TO INDIA’S POOR
MANAGEMENT FOCUS
GLOBAL BRANDING, MARVEL STUDIOS AND WALT DISNEY
IS THE GOOGLE ADVERTISING MODEL VIABLE IN THE LONG TERM?
COUNTRY FOCUS
SPAIN: BUILDING AUSTRALIA’S INFRASTRUCTURE
CLOSING CASE
YOUI: SELLING THE YOU
xxvi GLOBAL BUSINESS TODAY
hiL23674_fm_i-xxx.indd
xxvi
08/06/19 05:52 PM
CHAPTER 13 INTERNATIONAL PRODUCTION, OUTSOURCING AND LOGISTICS
OPENING CASE
LI & FUNG LIMITED: A FACTORY OF SORTS, NOW OUT OF SORTS
ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
CHANGING CAREER ROLES AND OPPORTUNITIES
DIFFERENT STAGE, DIFFERENT SCALE
THE GREENING OF CAR MANUFACTURING
OFFSHORING LEGAL SERVICES
REVERSE LOGISTICS
RFID AND LIVESTOCK
EMERGING MARKETS
THE ‘CHINA-PLUS-ONE’ STRATEGY
MANAGEMENT FOCUS
HP SINGAPORE’S EVOLVING ROLE
COUNTRY FOCUS
THE PACIFIC ISLANDS: A KEY PARTNER IN AUSTRALIAN AGRICULTURE
CLOSING CASE
FMCG, SOFT DOLLARS AND LEAN SUPPLY CHAINS
CHAPTER 14 INTERNATIONAL HUMAN RESOURCE MANAGEMENT
OPENING CASE
GLOBAL MOBILITY AT SHELL
ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
LINKING HR ACROSS THE GLOBE
THE FUTURE OF HR MOBILITY MANAGEMENT
SENDING WOMEN ON INTERNATIONAL ASSIGNMENTS
WHICH COUNTRY DO YOU WANT TO GO TO?
EMERGING MARKETS
THE COST OF WORKING IN CHINA
MANAGEMENT FOCUS
MCDONALD’S GLOBAL COMPENSATION PRACTICES
COUNTRY FOCUS
SOUTH AFRICA: THE APARTHEID LEGACY
CLOSING CASE
SODEXO: BUILDING A DIVERSE GLOBAL WORKFORCE
CASE AND VIGNETTE MATRIX xxvii
hiL23674_fm_i-xxx.indd xxvii
08/06/19 05:52 PM
INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS GRADUATE
ATTRIBUTES
While individual educational institutions and courses of study will
seek to develop attributes peculiar to their own situation, there are
many generic attributes expressed in the institutional statements
of learning goals. The following concepts are common in these
statements:
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
Discipline Knowledge and Skill
Critical Analysis
Problem Solving
Ethical Decision Making
Communication
Social Interaction
Global Perspective
Life-long Learning
Citizenship.
It is evident that a study of international business, by its very nature,
can make a significant contribution to the development of these
generic attributes.
For teaching and learning purposes (including the assessment
of learning), a more operational expression of the concepts is
needed. The International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs)
as defined below provide the operational expression of these
concepts as they apply to an international business education.
The concepts listed above have been selected as the basis of
the development of the IBGAs used throughout this textbook
and its accompanying teaching and learning resources.
IBGAs need to be aligned with the learning objectives, and
the learning and assessment activities of a specific unit of study,
to ensure the development of the generic attributes. Learning
objectives, alone or in combination, provide indicators of the
attainment of the graduate attributes. A sample of such indicators
is provided below for each IBGA. Alignment occurs in this textbook
according to the IBGA chapter matrix below. While each chapter
by way of its subject matter, learning objectives, suggested
learning tasks and stimulus material potentially provides a vehicle
for developing all IBGAs, the alignment matrix recognises that
certain subject matter lends itself to the development of specific
IBGAs. The matrix also acknowledges that two of the IBGAS
are so generic that they can be assigned to all chapters. These
IBGAs are IBGA1: Discipline Knowledge and Skills and IBGA5:
Communication. Case analysis is used in each chapter, so IBGA2
Critical Analysis is also assigned to each chapter.
IBGA1 DISCIPLINE KNOWLEDGE AND SKILLS
Apply a coherent body of theoretical and practical knowledge and
skills to understand international business.
Indicator: You can:
• e
xplain the various methods used by governments to restrict
imports
• describe the circumstances under which a firm may choose
to enter a foreign market using licensing rather than FDI
• using the table of data provided, calculate the export price
in the foreign currency if the firm adopts a 100 per cent
pass-through pricing strategy.
IBGA2 CRITICAL ANALYSIS
Using a combination of insight, reason and practised skills,
formulate a considered judgement on the value of data, experiences,
arguments and proposals relating to international business issues.
Indicator: You can:
• s ummarise the data collected from returning expatriate staff
on the adequacy of their overseas allowances
• compare and contrast the public interest arguments
underpinning the national government’s decision to prohibit
one but permit another foreign takeover in the Australian
mining industry
• assess the viability of a business opportunity for the sale of
kangaroo meat to South Korea.
IBGA3 PROBLEM SOLVING
Define problems and their causes confronting international
business managers, and use a range of abilities, approaches and
resources to reach decisions and make recommendations.
Indicator: You can:
• find sources of data on foreign competitors
• outline how you would prepare yourself for a short-term work
assignment to a subsidiary in a foreign country about which
you know very little
• develop strategies that enhance the opportunities and limit
the threats for your business as a consequence of Australia
becoming a part of an expanded ASEAN Free Trade Area.
xxviii GLOBAL BUSINESS TODAY
hiL23674_fm_i-xxx.indd
xxviii
08/06/19 05:52 PM
IBGA4 ETHICAL DECISION MAKING
IBGA7 GLOBAL PERSPECTIVE
Be aware of the different value systems, including one’s own,
under which an international business may operate. Recognise
and value the moral dimensions of international business decisions
and actions.
Indicator: You can:
Understand and respect the economic, cultural and biological
diversity and interdependence of global life.
Indicator: You can:
• r ecognise instances when the accepted rules of conduct
regarding facility payments are broken
• accept responsibility for the consequences of your actions
• defend a code of practice for foreign suppliers that takes
account of company profits, fairness, sustainability and
Indigenous perspectives.
IBGA5 COMMUNICATION
Make connections that create meaning for others, including
cross-cultural connections. Choose language, media and formats
suitable for the message and the audience.
Indicator: You can:
• d
ebate in a public forum the effectiveness of trade
sanctions to bring about changes to the policies of a foreign
government
• conduct online a job interview with a candidate who is from a
non-English-speaking background and is located offshore
• write a report for management that explains the impact
on the supply chain of your company of increasing global
terrorism.
IBGA6 SOCIAL INTERACTION
Know how to get things done in groups.
Indicator: You can:
• elicit the views of others and help reach conclusions
• recognise the strength of others and build positive relations
• provide leadership within a team context by taking
responsibility for organisation, planning, influencing and
negotiating.
• e
xplain the concept of decoupling in the context of the
Global Financial Crisis
• compare world economic and political systems
• assess the use of ‘food miles’ as a measure of the carbon
footprint of a dairy food processor that exports to distant
foreign markets.
IBGA8 LIFE-LONG LEARNING
Maintain an intellectual interest and a critical perspective on
international business issues.
Indicator: You can:
• identify what you need to learn about international business
• manage time and prioritise activities to achieve your goals
• initiate ways and means of attaining and evaluating your
learning outcomes.
IBGA9 CITIZENSHIP
Engage actively with communities in ways that are sensitive to
their culture and responsive to their needs.
Indicator: You can:
• o
rganise a program of speakers for a conference for
international business graduates with the theme ‘Competing
with Integrity in International Business’
• represent on their behalf the point of view and interests of
Indigenous landholders who are seeking to form a strategic
alliance with a foreign company to develop a tourist resort
and golf course on their communal land
• identify opportunities for collaboration between suitable
NGOs and mine management on projects to improve the
general and vocational education of miners and their families
at a remote offshore mining site.
INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS GRADUATE ATTRIBUTES xxix
hiL23674_fm_i-xxx.indd xxix
08/06/19 05:52 PM
IBGA–CHAPTER ALIGNMENT
CHAPTER
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
1: Discipline Knowledge and Skills
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
2: Critical Analysis
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
3: Problem Solving
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
4: Ethical Decision Making
✓
✓
✓
✓
IBGA
5: Communication
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
✓
8: Life-long Learning
9: Citizenship
✓
✓
6: Social Interaction
7: Global Perspective
✓
✓
✓
✓
xxx GLOBAL BUSINESS TODAY
hiL23674_fm_i-xxx.indd
xxx
08/06/19 05:52 PM
1
© aapsky/Shutterstock
GLOBALISATION
CHAPTER 1
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 1
GLOBALISATION
08/06/19 07:40 PM
© RODRIGO A TORRES/Glow Images
CHAPTER 1
GLOBALISATION
2
PART 1
GLOBALISATION
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 2
08/06/19 07:40 PM
INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS GRADUATE
ATTRIBUTES (IBGAs)
This chapter’s content, learning resources and case studies provide you with the
opportunity to develop a number of International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs),
including the following:
IBGA1
IBGA2
IBGA5
IBGA7
IBGA9
Discipline Knowledge and Skills
Critical Analysis
Communication
Global Perspective
Citizenship
LEARNING OBJECTIVES (LOs)
1.1
1.2
1.3
1.4
1.5
Explain the process and drivers of globalisation and the
opportunities and challenges it creates for business.
Illustrate how the global economy has changed over the past
50 years.
Justify the labelling of the 21st century as the Emerging
Markets Century.
Debate the impact of globalisation on issues such as job security,
income inequality and the environment.
Compare how the management of international business differs
from the management of domestic business.
CHAPTER 1
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 3
GLOBALISATION
3
08/06/19 07:40 PM
OPENING CASE
KAIHARA: GLOBALISATION OF A
SHINISE, A LONG-LIVED COMPANY
Fukuyama city in Hiroshima Prefecture, Japan, used to
be known as Bingo. The name was synonymous with
its ‘Bingo kasuri’, a Japanese cotton kimono cloth with
a splashed pattern. In 1893, Kaihara, a family business
manufacturing kasuri, was established by Sukejiro Kaihara
in Bingo. It remained a comparatively small operation
until its transformation into Kaihara Textile Mills Ltd
in 1951. Since then, the company has grown to become
a world-renowned supplier of high-quality denim for
leading jeans manufacturers/brands such as Levi’s, fastfashion retailers like GAP and premium brands like Hugo
Boss. The company has more than a 50 per cent share of
the blue denim market in Japan and exports more than
70 per cent of its products. The company’s successful
internationalisation is illustrative of a traditional Japanese
company that has used its core domestic technology as a
stepping stone to become globally competitive.
presented Kaihara with an opportunity to expand
overseas. In 1951, a trading company from Aden, Yemen,
was seeking a manufacturer able to supply sarong cloth
blended with the Japanese kasuri. After a failed attempt
to source from a company in Nishiwaki, Hyogo Prefecture
(due to manufacturing limitations), the company
approached Kaihara. Sarongs for children needed 36-inch
wide cloth, while for adults 48-inch cloth was required,
necessitating the stitching of two 24-inch cloths. In order
to improve the quality of the end product and limit the
stitching needed, Kaihara developed a machine capable of
producing 48-inch wide cloth. This innovation resulted
in a worker being able to operate four machines at a time,
resulting in a ten-fold efficiency gain in comparison with
producers in Indonesia.
ACCUMULATION OF TECHNOLOGIES
Kaihara grew rapidly due to the cost-effective production
of sarongs and a newly developed wool kasuri fabric
that satisfied customer demand for softer kasuri in the
Japanese market. However, a crisis hit the company:
political instability in the Middle East and devaluation
of the British pound led to overstocked inventory of
kasuri sarong cloth equivalent to a year’s production. The
company had to find a way to overcome the crisis.
At the time the company was established there were
numerous kasuri makers in Japan. Therefore, from its
inception the company’s founder decided to focus on
the high-end market, with higher quality products
garnering a 20–50 per cent price premium over
competitors’ products.
After World War II, Kaihara, like other Japanese companies,
rebuilt its business. The company focused on production
innovations, such as developing and patenting an
automatic dyeing machine. In addition, it developed new
products for the domestic market. Other innovations
followed; for example, Kaihara produced the first 36-inch
wide kasuri fabric using an electric loom. However, due
to changing market demand from Westernisation and
a significant decrease in the wearing of kimonos, the
company had limited sales success. Instead, this innovation
provided the company with the production capacity to
service larger markets, including international markets.
While kimono wearing was in decline in Japan, ikat
(a dyeing method used to pattern textiles) used in
Indonesia, India and other countries for saris and sarongs
4
PART 1
MOVE TO DENIM
Sadaharu Kaihara, the president, was informed by one
of his friends, ‘Jeans have become fashionable for the
youngsters in Japan. Since they are imported from
abroad, why don’t you try to manufacture them using
your company’s technology?’ Traditionally, kasuri was
dyed using the Japanese indigo plant, later substituted
with indigo made from oil. The oil-based indigo was also
used for denim, and Kaihara had expertise in using the
artificial dye. In addition, denim production had synergy
with kasuri weaving technology. Therefore, Sadaharu
Kaihara went to Tokyo to observe the uptake of jeans by
the younger generation. He saw a significant market for
denim and decided to diversify into denim production.
In 1969, the company introduced cheese-dyed indigo
denim to the Japanese market. However, the denim
GLOBALISATION
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 4
08/06/19 07:40 PM
was dyed on both sides while the American-made
product was dyed only on the outer surface. The
company quickly adapted. In 1979 it developed the first
Japanese consecutive indigo-dyeing machine or ropedyeing machine. The machine increased production
rates by a hundred-fold. The company named the
machine ‘endurance’, symbolising the company’s
enduring commitment to innovation. The machine
was built using the company’s expertise accumulated
in kasuri manufacturing. It reinforced the company’s
commitment to high-quality products, including denim,
and strengthened its core competency by developing
its own technology, building on its historical roots as a
kasuri manufacturer.
In addition, geographical considerations necessitated the
development of the company’s own technology. Kaihara
is located deep in the mountains far away from the city
centre. If a machine breaks down, it takes a long time
for a repair person to attend to the fault. Yoshiharu
Kaihara, the fourth president of the company, stated that
it took a few days to rectify a fault if they asked others
to fix it. Therefore, the company’s staff needed to fix
things themselves to save time and minimise production
downtime. Thus it was imperative for Kaihara to
accumulate knowledge within the company.
Copyright © 2019. McGraw-Hill Education (Australia) Pty Limited. All rights reserved.
LEARNING FROM LEVI STRAUSS
Because of the high quality of its denim and large
production capacity, Kaihara was able to expand its
business in Japan. To keep up with demand, it had to
increase its production capacity by introducing new
machines. In 1974 it installed 68 Toyota Gu8 weaving
machines, followed by 120 Sulzer weaving machines in
1978. The company also installed finishing machines in
the 1980s, making it possible to integrate many stages of
denim production. This investment in machinery enabled
the company to produce large volumes of high-quality
denim with consistent quality.
Integrated production processes enabled higher quality
control. High-quality threads are required to produce
high-quality denim. High-quality threads also facilitate
improved production efficiency, by limiting downtime
for weaving machines due to broken threads. Denim
uses thicker cotton-based threads. Efficient production of
threads can contribute to increased denim productivity,
so in 1991 Kaihara built a spinning factory. With this
factory it achieved a fully integrated denim production
process from spinning to dyeing, weaving and finishing.
Kaihara procures cotton from Australia, Syria and the
United States among other countries. Due to varying
growing conditions the quality of the cotton is
inconsistent. The company thus mixes cottons from
various countries to minimise variations in quality and
to ensure consistently higher quality denim. The skill
behind the blending process is another core competency
of the company.
The opportunity to expand its business into major
international markets came from Levi Strauss, the US
jeans company. In 1972, the company explored Hong
Kong as a potential site for sewing jeans. In addition, it
was exploring new suppliers. Levi’s purchased denim
from a relatively unknown Japanese company and
recognised the quality of Kaihara’s product.
Specifications from Levi’s were stricter than expected,
providing a steep learning curve to meet world standards
for quality and new methods of quality control. Levi’s
procured its denim from many suppliers and standardised
the quality by using multidimensional standards such
as colour, thickness and elasticity. To meet Levi’s
specifications, Kaihara collected data during every step of
the production process, leading to a data-driven scientific
method of quality control.
MADE IN JAPAN
Kaihara has maintained its factories in Fukuyama with
employees recruited from the local area. ‘Made in Japan’
is comparatively expensive compared with competitors
with factories in emerging countries. Yoshiharu Kaihara
explored the possibility of building a factory in China, but
realised that it would result in higher costs due to the
cost of logistics, rejected products and limited flexibility
in production. As the company focused on the premium
end of the market, it required a higher level of quality, and
with frequent changes to production as fashion trends
emerged, producing locally in Japan had greater advantages.
The company educates and trains its employees as multiskilled workers. There are no exceptions—even office
staff can operate the machines. The workforce is nimble
and quick to respond to urgent orders from customers.
Workers are expected to continuously improve the
production process so that rejected products known as
B or C class cloth are minimised. In addition, workers
have a high work ethic. In turn, the company recognises
workers’ contributions and rewards them by giving
bonuses at the end of the financial year when targeted
production volumes and revenue have been achieved.
CHAPTER 1
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 5
GLOBALISATION
5
08/06/19 07:40 PM
‘PROPOSALS’-BASED SALES
Based on accumulated knowledge, Kaihara proactively
develops and introduces new types of denim to jeans
and apparel manufacturers. New products must meet
the three Fs: fabric-materials, fit-silhouette or style, and
finish-after-washing product quality. The company thinks
that a good ‘proposal’ has a story behind it, including
the three Fs. Kaihara produces 700–800 samples a year
for the ‘proposals’ and on average around one-quarter are
accepted. Some samples are developed in-house, others
are made due to requests from customers. According to
the company president, the company has many failures,
since three-quarters of the ‘proposals’ are unsellable, but
it is a necessary investment to ensure continued success.
Corporation was established. There were two major
reasons to expand production overseas: to supply global
customers; and to internationalise to maintain production
capacity in the future, as the company is located in rural
Japan where there are significant issues of depopulation
and an ageing population.
The company chose Thailand not only because it was
a suitable place for production, but also as it was seen
as a good place for targeting emerging Asian markets
that would demand higher quality jeans in the future.
Kaihara did not compromise on quality in setting up its
Thai factory, installing the most advanced machines and
training local workers to meet Japanese standards.
Professor Makoto Kanda
Meiji Gakuin University
© The Asahi Shimbun/Contributor/Getty Images
According to the company president, the company
invests in people and facilities, taking a long-term
perspective, not short-term financial performance. The
company is family owned and does not need to respond
to shareholders with short-term interests.
GLOBAL SUPPLY AND PRODUCTION
In 1998 the company started business with UNIQLO, a
Japanese SPA, or specialty store retailer of private label
apparel, a subsidiary of Fast Retailing Corporation. As
UNIQLO expanded globally, Kaihara was required to
establish a global supply chain. Initially, it supplied from
its Japanese factories, but found it necessary to build
another factory abroad and in 2014 Kaihara (Thailand)
SOURCES: Kaihara, Company History: Onko Soushin (Creating the New With Knowing the Old) (in Japanese), 2000, www.kaihara-denim.com/english/company/
history.html; T. Takai, ‘Innovation of shinise, the long-lived company: Kaihara 1-3’ (in Japanese), Seisansei Shinbun (Productivity Newspaper), No. 2550-2552,
2018; www.kaihara-denim.com/english/company/history.html accessed on 25 January 2018.
INTRODUCTION
Over the past three decades, a fundamental shift has been occurring in the world
economy. We have moved away from a world in which national economies were
relatively self-contained entities, isolated from each other by barriers to cross-border trade
and investment; by distance, time zones and language; and by national differences in
government regulation, culture and business systems. In addition, countries have moved
towards a world where barriers to cross-border trade and investment have declined;
perceived distance has shrunk due to advances in transportation and telecommunications
technology; material culture is starting to look similar; and national economies have
merged into an interdependent, integrated global economic system. The process by which
6
PART 1
GLOBALISATION
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 6
08/06/19 07:40 PM
this occurred is commonly referred to as globalisation, and international business is the
main facilitator of this process. However, recently we have seen a rise in anti-globalisation
and a more protectionist/nationalistic approach to trade, a return to mercantilism?
The Opening and Closing Cases (‘Kaihara: Globalisation of a shinise, a long-lived
company’ and ‘Global innovation through the mobility of ideas and talent’) and the
global dispersal of production for Boeing’s 787 Dreamliner, outlined in the Management
Focus, are examples of the trend towards globalisation. In 1970, independent suppliers
produced only 5 per cent of the value of a Boeing commercial jet. With the advent of
the 787 Dreamliner, this figure reached 65 per cent, and many of those suppliers were
scattered around the globe. Part of Boeing’s rationale was that 80 per cent of its sales
went to foreign airlines, and winning orders in this global marketplace required that it
outsource some production to other nations. Boeing also believed that it made sense to
outsource production of component parts to independent suppliers if they were the best
in the world at performing that particular activity, no matter where they were located. In
Boeing’s view, the result of such a strategy would be greater efficiency and lower costs,
which would help Boeing compete on price against its global rival in the commercial
aircraft business, Airbus. As the case makes clear, however, there are risks involved in
embracing globalisation to the extent that Boeing did. Coordinating a globally dispersed
supply chain turned out to be a logistical nightmare, and was partly responsible for
delaying the launch of the 787 by more than four years, which cost Boeing dearly. The
Boeing example illustrates, therefore, that managers need to carefully think through
their strategy for competing in the global marketplace of the 21st century, balancing the
benefits of embracing globalisation against the associated risks. This is a theme that we
shall return to repeatedly throughout this text.
More generally, globalisation now has an impact upon almost everything we do. In
this interdependent global economy, an Australian is driving home from work in a Ford
ute—the brand of a US multinational, designed in Japan and manufactured in Thailand
by a joint venture of Ford and Mazda, using a Mazda design. Components come from
the United States and Japan using Korean steel and Malaysian rubber, and from sheet
metal produced by an Australian company’s subsidiary in Thailand. On the way to work,
the Australian driver fills the car with fuel at a BP service station owned by a British
multinational company. The fuel could have been made from oil pumped out of a well off
the coast of Africa by a French oil company that transported it to refineries in Singapore
in a ship owned by a Greek shipping line. While driving home, the Australian rings her
stockbroker on a hands-free mobile phone that was assembled in China using chip sets
produced in Taiwan. She tells her stockbroker to purchase shares in CSL, an Australian biopharmaceutical company transformed from a government-owned enterprise to a privately
owned global company, now with 14 000 employees operating in 30 countries.1 Playing
on the car radio (made in Malaysia by a Japanese company) is a popular hip-hop song
composed by a Swede and sung in English by a group of Danes who signed a recording
contract with a French music company to promote their record worldwide. The driver
pulls into a fast-food restaurant to buy a meal of Portuguese-style, flame-grilled periperi chicken from a South African Nando’s franchise owned and run by a Vietnamese
immigrant. On the way home, a news announcer on the car radio informs the driver
that anti-globalisation protests at a meeting of the World Economic Forum in Davos,
Switzerland, have turned violent. One protester has been killed. The announcer then
turns to the next item, a story about how interest rates in the United States have been
increased by the US Federal Reserve, which overnight sparked a decline in the value of
the Australian dollar on the foreign exchange markets. The driver muses that now might
be the time to replace her old ute with a new imported one if the dollar looks likely to
continue to depreciate in value.
CHAPTER 1
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 7
GLOBALISATION
7
08/06/19 07:40 PM
This is the world in which we live. It is a world where the volume of goods, services
and investments crossing national borders has expanded faster than world output
consistently for more than half a century. It is a world where US$16 trillion of goods and
US$4.8 trillion of services are sold annually across national borders.2 (As no global currency
exists, when aggregating and comparing international monetary values, there is a need to
adopt a single national currency as the unit of measurement. The most widely used unit of
MANAGEMENT FOCUS
THE GLOBALISATION OF
PRODUCTION AT BOEING
© WESTEND61 GmbH/Alamy Stock Photo
Messier–Dowty makes the aircraft’s landing gear;
German manufacturer Diehl Luftfahrt Elektronik supplies
the main cabin lighting; Sweden’s Saab Aerostructures
makes the access doors; Japanese company Jamco
makes parts for the lavatories, flight decks interiors and
galleys; Mitsubishi Heavy Industries of Japan makes
the wings; KAA of Korea makes the wing tips; Boeing
Aerostructures Australia (BAA) makes the movable
trailing edges and inboard flaps; and so on.
Executives at Boeing Corporation, America’s largest
exporter, like to say that building a large commercial
jet aircraft such as the 747 or 787 involves bringing
together more than a million parts in flying formation.
Fifty years ago, when the early models of Boeing’s
venerable 737 and 747 jets were rolling off the
company’s Seattle area production lines, foreign
suppliers accounted for only 5 per cent of the aircraft
parts, on average. Boeing was vertically integrated
and manufactured many of the major components that
went into its planes. The largest parts produced by
outside suppliers were the jet engines; two of the three
suppliers were US companies and the lone foreign
manufacturer was the British company Rolls Royce.
Fast-forward to the modern era and things look very
different. For its latest aircraft, the super-efficient
787 Dreamliner, 50 outside suppliers spread around
the world account for 65 per cent of the value of the
aircraft: Italian company Alenia Aeronautica makes
the centre fuselage and horizontal stabiliser; Kawasaki
of Japan makes part of the forward fuselage and
the fixed trailing edge of the wing; French company
8
PART 1
Why the change? One reason is that 80 per cent
of Boeing’s customers are foreign airlines, and to
sell into those nations it often helps to be giving
business to those nations. The trend started in 1974
when Mitsubishi of Japan was given contracts to
produce inboard wing flaps for the 747. The Japanese
reciprocated by placing big orders for Boeing jets.
A second rationale was to disperse component part
production to those suppliers that are the best in
the world at their particular activity. Over the years,
for example, Mitsubishi has acquired considerable
expertise in the manufacture of wings, so it was logical
for Boeing to use Mitsubishi to make the wings for the
787. Similarly, the 787 is the first commercial jet aircraft
to be made almost entirely out of carbon fibre, so
Boeing tapped Japan’s Toray industries, a world-class
expert in sturdy but light carbon-fibre composites, to
supply materials for the fuselage. A third reason for
the extensive outsourcing on the 787 was that Boeing
wanted to unburden itself of some of the risks and
costs associated with developing production facilities
for the 787. By outsourcing, it pushed some of those
risks and costs onto suppliers, which had to undertake
major investments in capacity to ramp up to produce
parts for the 787.
So what did Boeing retain for itself? Engineering
design, marketing and sales, and final assembly at
GLOBALISATION
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 8
08/06/19 07:40 PM
its Everett plant north of Seattle—all activities where
Boeing maintains it is the best in the world. Of the
major component parts, Boeing makes only the
tail fin and wing to body fairing (which attaches the
wings to the fuselage of the plane). Everything else is
outsourced. As the 787 moved through development
in the 2000s, however, it became clear that Boeing had
pushed the outsourcing paradigm too far. Coordinating
a globally dispersed production system this extensive
turned out to be very challenging. Parts turned up late,
some parts didn’t ‘snap together’ the way Boeing had
envisioned and several suppliers ran into engineering
problems that slowed down the entire production
process. As a consequence, the delivery date for the
first jet was pushed back more than four years and
Boeing had to pay millions of dollars in penalties for
late deliveries. In fact the problems at one supplier,
Vought Aircraft in North Carolina, were so severe that
Boeing ultimately agreed to acquire the company and
bring its production in-house. Vought was co-owned by
Alenia of Italy and made part of the main fuselage.
Boeing has overcome these issues and the
787 Dreamliner is now being used by airlines such
as Qantas for their long-haul routes due to its fuel
efficiency and passenger comfort.
measurement is the US dollar. The US dollar is used extensively as a medium of exchange, a
foreign currency reserve and a unit of account in international transactions.)
It is a world requiring more effective collaboration and action at a global level among
national governments on issues such as climate change, terrorism, flu pandemics and
financial crises.
Today’s world is a world of integration and interdependence. The symbols of material
and popular culture are increasingly global: from Coca-Cola and Toyota to Sony PlayStations,
Samsung mobile phones, reality TV shows, Google, IKEA stores and Apple iPhones and
iPads. In this world, products are made from inputs that come from all over the world. It
is a world where an economic crisis in the tiny Greek economy causes uncertainty about
the economic stability of the world’s largest economy, the
United States; where a mortgage crisis in the housing sector
in the US economy can lead to the bankruptcy of the
economy of Iceland and a change of Iceland’s government;
where a major flood in Thailand closes Thai factories which
in turn disrupts global supply chains in the automotive
industry and causes factories in other parts of the world
to close. As the internet penetrates more regions of the
world and information flows become mostly instantaneous
and almost costless, global integration is becoming more
individualised, rather than being just institution to
institution or B2B.3 It is a world where we can share music
files internationally with our peers, buy an item from
overseas on an online auction site, coordinate the activities
of suppressed political dissidents in a foreign country, and
Fears of a slowdown in the Chinese economy and the fall in
have our identity stolen by a foreign criminal gang. It is
the value of Chinese shares saw the ASX lose a staggering
$60 billion in a day.
also a world in which vigorous and vocal groups protest
CHAPTER 1
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 9
GLOBALISATION
9
08/06/19 07:40 PM
© IDEALINK PHOTOGRAPHY/Alamy Stock Photo
SOURCES: K. Epstein and J. Crown, ‘Globalization bites Boeing’, Bloomberg Businessweek, 12 March 2008; H. Mallick, ‘Out of control outsourcing ruined
Boeing’s beautiful Dreamliner’, The Star, 25 February 2013; P. Kavilanz, ‘Dreamliner: where in the world its parts come from’, CNN Money, 18 January
2013; S. Dubois, ‘Boeing’s Dreamliner mess: simply inevitable?’, CNN Money, 22 January 2013; A. Scott and T. Kelly, ‘Boeing’s loss of a $9.5 billion deal
could bring jobs back to the US’, Business Insider, 14 October 2013; ‘Boeing talks up 787’s Australian link’, accessed via www.news.com.au/finance/
business/boeing-talks-up-787s-australian-link/story-e6frfkur-1226217631114 on 12 September 2015; ‘Boeing 787 Dreamliner’ accessed via
www.boeing.com/commercial/787/ on 1 April 2019.
OUTSOURCING
The tasks that were previously
performed in-house are now
purchased from another firm
OFFSHORING
A form of outsourcing; it means
that a task previously performed
in one country is now being
undertaken abroad
LO 1.1
GLOBALISATION
The shift towards a more integrated
and interdependent world economy
PART 1
against globalisation, which they blame for a list of ills, from job losses and unemployment
in developed nations, and poverty in developing economies, to environmental degradation,
climate change and the Americanisation of popular culture.
There is no clearer evidence that we live in one economic world than the advent and
fallout of the 2007–09 Global Financial Crisis (GFC) or the stock market volatility caused by
events in Greece and China.
As globalisation unfolds, it transforms industries and creates anxiety among those who
believed their jobs were once protected from foreign competition. Historically, while many
workers in manufacturing industries worried about the impact that foreign competition
might have on their jobs, workers in service industries felt more secure. Now, this too, is
changing. Advances in information and communications technology, lower transportation
costs and the rise of skilled workers in emerging and developing countries mean that
many services no longer need to be performed where they are delivered. Offshoring is an
increasing trend. Offshoring is a particular form of outsourcing. Outsourcing means that
tasks that were previously performed in-house are now purchased from another company.
Offshoring means that a task previously performed in one country is now being undertaken
abroad. The offshoring trend can be seen in many service industries such as data entry,
customer service calls, software development and the preparation of legal briefs and tax
returns. For example, Indian accountants, trained in the tax rules and processes of other
countries, perform work for foreign accounting companies.4 They access individual tax
returns stored on computers in the foreign country, perform routine calculations and save
their work so that it can be inspected by a local accountant, who then bills clients. As the
best-selling author Thomas Friedman argued, the world is becoming flat.5 People living
in developed nations no longer have the playing field tilted in their favour. Increasingly,
enterprising individuals based in India, China, Brazil or Eastern Europe have the same
opportunities to better themselves as those living in Western Europe, Japan, North
America, Australia or New Zealand.
In this book, we take a close look at the issues introduced here, and at many more.
We explore how changes in regulations governing international trade and investment,
when coupled with changes in political and economic systems and technology, have
dramatically altered the competitive playing field confronting many businesses. We
discuss the resulting opportunities and threats, and review the different strategies that
managers can pursue to exploit the opportunities and counter the threats. The Opening
Case identified the choices that Kaihara management has made over time as it engaged
with internationalisation and the impact of globalisation; for example, choices over what
product it should produce to sustain international competitiveness. We consider whether
globalisation benefits or harms national economies, and we look at what economic theory
has to say about the outsourcing or offshoring of manufacturing and service jobs to places
such as India and China, and at the benefits and costs of outsourcing—not just to entire
economies but also to businesses and their employees. First, though, we need to get a
better overview of the nature and process of globalisation, and that is the function of the
current chapter.
WHAT IS GLOBALISATION?
As used in this book, the term globalisation refers to the shift towards a more integrated
and interdependent world economy. Globalisation in general has several facets ranging over
political, cultural, economic and ecological issues; but in the business world the focus is on
the globalisation of markets and of production.
GLOBALISATION
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 10
08/06/19 07:40 PM
COUNTRY FOCUS
CHINA: BELT AND ROAD INITIATIVE
© tcly/Shutterstock
Africa, and on to Europe. Six other economic corridors
have been identified to link other countries to the Belt
and the Road.’ The project’s name evokes the famous
Silk Road of the Middle Ages, a network of informal but
significant trading routes between Europe and Asia
whereby silk, spices and other goods were moved from
east to west, and famously chronicled by the European
explorer and trader Marco Polo.
When one thinks of globalisation it is often in terms
of the developed world, especially the United States
and Western Europe. There is a good reason for this
since most current international institutions (such as
the United Nations, the International Monetary Fund
and the World Bank) were founded at the behest of the
United States after World War II and the United States
remains the largest economy in the world, with a major
portion of the world’s wealth and income concentrated
in Western countries.
However, this economic predominance has been
slowly shifting. China is now the second-largest
world economy, with current projections indicating a
continuing increase in the developing world’s share of
world GDP over the next 50 years. A similar shift can
be seen in international institutions, such as China’s
Belt and Road Initiative (BRI). As the World Bank states:
‘The initiative aims to strengthen infrastructure, trade,
and investment links between China and some 65
other countries that account collectively for over 30 per
cent of global GDP, 62 per cent of population, and 75
per cent of known energy reserves. The BRI consists
primarily of the Silk Road Economic Belt, linking China
to Central and South Asia and onward to Europe,
and the new Maritime Silk Road, linking China to the
nations of South-East Asia, the Gulf Countries, North
The Chinese government has been approaching
countries throughout Asia and Africa offering foreign
aid, loans and investments to develop ports, roads and
other infrastructure to facilitate the movement of goods
along the trading routes, and encouraging cooperation
and broader exchange between participating nations.
However, the initiative has engendered some
controversy for a number of reasons. China has been
accused of exploiting economically and politically weak
nations through the use of loans and other means that
might appear to offer beneficial investment but that
may saddle recipient nations with heavy debt burdens
later on (and, by extension, political dependence
on the Beijing government). Many loans are being
extended by China’s policy banks, with much of the
money going not to local contractors but to Chinese
enterprises that will actually do the work locally.
Additionally, there is some question as to whether the
BRI will end up mainly funnelling trade and investment
flows to the benefit of China rather than the other
participating countries.
BRI funding will also be provided through another
Chinese initiative, the Asian Infrastructure
Investment Bank (AIIB), which was started by China
but is funded by countries globally. The AIIB is
China’s supplement to the World Bank. Many Western
nations, especially the United States (which refused to
participate in the AIIB, although invited to by China),
view the BRI and AIIB with suspicion, seeing them as
ways for Beijing to assert its geopolitical will through
economic means.
These critiques have merit and the debate continues.
However, it must be remembered that the BRI is just
CHAPTER 1
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 11
GLOBALISATION
11
08/06/19 07:40 PM
another example of a rising nation (China in this case)
seeking to influence international economic and
political order. Powerful nations will always seek to
advance their own particular interests but hopefully
they will also try to offer gains to other countries,
ending in a ‘win–win’ outcome for all.
Cameron Gordon
Australian National University
SOURCES: ‘Belt and Road Initiative’, The World Bank, 29 March 2018 accessed via www.worldbank.org/en/topic/regional-integration/brief/belt-androad-initiative on 30 April 2019; G. Wade, ‘China’s “One Belt, One Road” initiative’ accessed via www.aph.gov.au/About_Parliament/Parliamentary_
Departments/Parliamentary_Library/pubs/BriefingBook45p/ChinasRoad on 30 April 2019; ‘China’s belt and road initiative’ accessed via www.lowyinstitute.
org/sites/default/files/documents/Understanding%20 China%E2%80%99s%20Belt%20and%20Road%20Initiative_WEB_1.pdf on 30 April 2019.
The globalisation of markets
GLOBALISATION OF MARKETS
The merging of historically distinct
and separate national markets into
one huge global marketplace
TEST PREP
Preparing for a test?
Use LearnSmart to
help you remember
what you’ve learned.
12
PART 1
The globalisation of markets refers to the merging of historically distinct and separate
national markets into one huge global marketplace. Falling barriers to cross-border trade
have made it easier to sell internationally. It has been argued for some time that the
tastes and preferences of consumers in different nations are beginning to converge on
some global norm, thereby helping to create a global market.6 The global acceptance of
consumer products such as Prada fashions (home country: Italy), Coca-Cola soft drinks
(United States), Sony PlayStation games (Japan), McDonald’s hamburgers (United States),
Nescafé coffee (Switzerland) and IKEA furniture (Sweden) are frequently held up as
prototypical examples of this trend. It is estimated that the best 10 ‘global’ brands by
value are, in descending order, Apple, Google, Amazon, Microsoft, Coca-Cola, Samsung,
Toyota, Mercedes-Benz, Facebook and McDonald’s.7 As consumers, we readily recognise
these brands, but there are also many ‘global’ brands and companies in the industrial and
business-to-business markets that are not as well known. Examples include the Taiwan
Semiconductor Manufacturing Company (one of the world’s largest dedicated independent
semiconductor manufacturers), ZPMC (formerly Shanghai Port Machinery Company, China,
one of the world’s largest container-port equipment manufacturers—it is so large that it
has 26 specially converted bulk cargo ships to transport its heavy cranes and equipment
around the globe),8 and the diversified resources company BHP (Australia). In fact, the
most global of markets currently are not the markets for consumer products, where
national differences in tastes and preferences and other factors are still often important
enough to act as a brake on globalisation, but markets for industrial goods and materials
that serve a universal need. These include the markets for commodities such as iron ore,
oil and wheat; for industrial products such as microprocessors, computer memory chips
and software; for commercial jet aircraft; and for financial assets such as foreign currency,
US Treasury bills, Eurobonds and futures. The companies in these industries, both
consumer and industrial, are more than just beneficiaries of the globalisation of markets:
they are also facilitators of it. By offering the same basic product worldwide, they enjoy
cost advantages but they also help to create a global market.
In many global markets, the same companies frequently confront each other as
competitors in nation after nation. Coca-Cola’s rivalry with PepsiCo is a global one, as are
the rivalries between Ford and Toyota, Boeing and Airbus, Nike and Adidas in sporting
goods, Caterpillar and Komatsu in earth-moving equipment, and Samsung and Apple. If
a company moves into a nation not currently served by its rivals, many of those rivals
are sure to follow to prevent their competitor from gaining an advantage.9 As companies
follow each other around the world, they bring with them what they have learned in other
national markets. They bring many of the assets that served them well in these markets,
GLOBALISATION
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 12
08/06/19 07:40 PM
including their products, operating strategies, marketing strategies and brand names. This
creates some homogeneity across markets. Thus, greater uniformity replaces diversity. In
an increasing number of industries, it is no longer meaningful to talk about ‘the German
market’, ‘the Australian market’, ‘the Brazilian market’ or ‘the Japanese market’ because for
many companies there is only the global market.
A company does not have to be the size of the multinational giants whose brands are
mentioned above to facilitate and benefit from the globalisation of markets. For some time,
small Australian companies have been enjoying success in the global economy. Forty-four
per cent of all goods exporters are small companies; that is, less than 20 employees.10
Typical of the growth of a small to medium-sized exporter is the story of the Victorianbased company Gekko Systems, an innovator in mining technology and mineral processing,
particularly in gold mining. Its headquarters is located in Ballarat, Victoria. One companydeveloped innovation is a process for treating ore underground, which means that only
the most valuable portion is brought to the surface. As a result of this technology, mining
operating costs can be cut by 25 per cent. Within months of establishment, 30 per cent
of Gekko’s products were exported. After 10 years, its workforce grew to 75, doubling in
two years. In the area of the processing of gold alone, it now employs globally a staff of 30
technicians and professionals. It exports to 30 countries and has opened regional offices in
South Africa, Canada and Chile where mining and mineral processing are major industries.11
The situation with respect to small companies is similar in several other nations. In the
United States, 34 per cent of total US exports are initiated by small to medium-sized
companies (less than 500 employees). Ninety-eight per cent of all US exporters are small
to medium-sized companies.12 In Germany, a staggering 98 per cent of all of its small to
medium-sized companies have exposure to international markets, via either exports or
international production.13
Despite the global prevalence of Toyota motor vehicles, McDonald’s hamburgers, Samsung
phones, Apple iPads and the like, it is important not to push too far the view that national
markets are giving way entirely to the global market, particularly in relation to consumer
goods and services. As we shall see in later chapters, significant differences still exist
among national markets along many relevant dimensions including consumer tastes and
preferences, distribution channels, culturally embedded value systems, political systems,
economic development and legal regulations. These differences frequently require companies
to customise marketing strategies, product features and operating practices to best match
conditions in a particular country. For example, motor vehicle companies will design and
promote different car models in different nations, depending on a range of factors, such as
local fuel costs, design standards, income levels, road conditions, environmental concerns
and cultural values. It should not have come as a complete surprise that the Tata Group, the
Indian-based global conglomerate, brought to the market the Nano, touted as the world’s
cheapest car. Average incomes in India are low, but as the economy is rapidly growing and
standards of living rise, the local demand for an affordable car is expected to rise substantially.
The globalisation of production
Globalisation of production refers to the sourcing of goods and services from locations
around the globe to take advantage of national differences in the cost and quality
of factors of production (such as labour, technology, land and capital). By doing this,
companies hope to lower their overall cost structure or improve the quality or
functionality of their product offering, thereby allowing them to compete more effectively.
Part of Boeing’s rationale for outsourcing so much production to foreign suppliers is
that these suppliers are the best in the world at their particular activity. A global web of
GLOBALISATION OF PRODUCTION
Sourcing goods and services from
locations around the globe to take
advantage of national differences
in the cost and quality of various
factors of production
FACTORS OF PRODUCTION
Components of production such as
labour, technology, land and capital
CHAPTER 1
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 13
GLOBALISATION
13
08/06/19 07:40 PM
suppliers yields a better final product, which enhances the chances of Boeing winning a
greater share of total orders for aircraft than its global rival Airbus Industries. Boeing also
outsources some production to foreign countries to increase the chance that it will win
significant orders from airlines based in that country. The Japanese airline ANA was the
first customer for the 787 when the plane entered service in late 2011. ANA has ordered
66 planes to date.14 China is a huge potential market for aviation manufacturers. Boeing
outsourced to Chinese companies the building of the rudder, wing-to-body fairing panels
and leading edge of the vertical fin for the new 787 Dreamliner. Komatsu, the world’s
second largest manufacturer of construction and mining equipment, does not outsource
production to the extent that Boeing does. Instead, Komatsu employs a mother plant/
daughter plant strategy to exploit the endowments of different locations around the globe.
MANAGEMENT FOCUS
WHO MAKES THE APPLE IPHONE?
In its early days, US-based Apple usually didn’t look
beyond its own backyard to manufacture its devices.
By 2004, however, Apple had largely turned to foreign
manufacturing. The shift to offshore manufacturing
reached its peak with the iconic iPhone, which Apple
first introduced in 2007. All iPhones contain hundreds
of parts, an estimated 90 per cent of which are
manufactured abroad. Advanced semiconductors
come from Germany and Taiwan, memory from Korea
and Japan, display panels and circuitry from Korea
and Taiwan, chip sets from Europe, and rare metals
from Africa and Asia. Apple’s major subcontractor,
the Taiwanese multinational Foxconn, performs final
assembly in China. However, in the future Foxconn is
likely to manufacture the LCD panels in Wisconsin.
Apple still employs some 47 000 people in the United
States, and it has kept important activities at home,
including product design, software engineering and
marketing. Furthermore, Apple claims that its business
supports another 304 000 jobs in the United States
in engineering, manufacturing and transport. For
example, the glass for the iPhone is manufactured at
Corning’s US plants in Kentucky and New York. But
an additional 700 000 people are involved in the
engineering, building and final assembly of its products
outside the United States, and most of them work at
subcontractors like Foxconn.
When explaining its decision to assemble the iPhone
in China, Apple cites a number of factors. While it is
true that labour costs are much lower in China, Apple
executives point out that labour costs only account for
14
PART 1
a very small proportion of the total value of its products
and are not the main driver of location decisions. Far
more important, according to Apple, is the ability of
its Chinese subcontractors to respond very quickly
to requests from Apple to scale production up and
down. In a famous illustration of this capability, in 2007
Steve Jobs demanded that a glass screen replace
the plastic screen on his prototype iPhone. Jobs
didn’t like the look and feel of plastic screens, which
at the time were standard in the industry, nor did he
like the way they scratched easily. This last-minute
change in the design of the iPhone put Apple’s market
introduction date at risk. Apple had selected Corning
to manufacture large panes of strengthened glass,
but finding a manufacturer that could cut those panes
into millions of iPhone screens wasn’t easy. Then a bid
arrived from a Chinese factory. When the Apple team
visited the factory, they found that the plant’s owners
were already constructing a new wing to cut the glass
and installing equipment. ‘This is in case you give us
the contract’, the manager said. The plant also had
a warehouse full of glass samples for Apple, and a
team of engineers available to work with Apple. They
had built onsite dormitories so that the factory could
run three shifts seven days a week in order to meet
Apple’s demanding production schedule. The Chinese
company got the bid.
Another critical advantage of China for Apple was that
it was much easier to hire engineers there. Apple
calculated that about 8700 industrial engineers were
needed to oversee and guide the 200 000 assembly-line
GLOBALISATION
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 14
08/06/19 07:40 PM
nine months to find that many engineers in the United
States. In China it took 15 days.
© Denis Rozhnovsky/Alamy Stock Photo
Also important is the clustering together of factories in
China. Many of the factories providing components for
the iPhone are located close to Foxconn’s assembly
plant. As one executive noted, ‘The entire supply chain
is in China. You need a thousand rubber gaskets?
That’s the factory next door. You need a million screws?
That factory is a block away. You need a screw made a
little bit different? That will take three hours.’
workers involved in manufacturing the iPhone. The
company had estimated that it would take as long as
All this being said, there are drawbacks to outsourcing
to China. Several of Apple’s subcontractors have
been targeted for their poor working conditions.
Criticisms include low pay of line workers, long hours,
mandatory overtime for little or no additional pay, and
poor safety records.
SOURCES: C. Duhigg and D. Barboza, ‘In China, human costs that are built into an iPad’, The New York Times, 26 January 2012; C. Duhigg and
K. Bradsher, ‘How US lost out on iPhone work’, The New York Times, 22 January 2012; ‘Apple takes credit for over half a million US jobs’, Apple
Intelligence, 2 March 2012, http://9to5mac.com/2012/03/02/apple-takes-credit-for-514000-u-s-jobs/#more-142766; Forbes, www.forbes.com/sites/
connieguglielmo/2012/03/02/apple-touts-itself-as-big-job-creator-in-the-u-s/#7628e89a1a60 accessed on 2 April 2019; ‘Foxconn announces North
American headquarters in Wisconsin’, 16 June 2018, www.reuters.com/article/us-usa-foxconn/foxconn-announces-north-american-headquarters-inwisconsin-idUSKBN1JC0FW accessed on 20 April 2019.
Its nine mother plants undertake research and development and produce a specific
range of the more technology-intensive and high value-added products. They are located in
the more technologically endowed countries such as Japan, Germany, Sweden, Italy and the
United States. The Japanese-based mother plants produce the most strategic and innovative
component parts that give Komatsu market leadership in segments of the global market for
construction and mining equipment. The 34 daughter plants are located around the world
in locations closer to the customer. They undertake assembly tasks and the manufacture of
low-technology, low value-added products using components and operational techniques
developed in the mother plants.
Early outsourcing and offshore production efforts were primarily confined to
manufacturing enterprises, such as those undertaken by Boeing and Komatsu. Increasingly,
however, companies are taking advantage of modern communications technology,
particularly the internet, to outsource service activities to low-cost producers in other
nations and to provide more timely services to customers—from data entry, call centres
and architectural designs to software development, legal services and medical services.
Radiologists in either Sydney or London diagnose and report on images sent to them from
radiology departments in UK and Australian hospitals and clinics. With about a 10 to ­
12-hour time difference, images can be read ‘overnight’ and reports made available the
next day to the attending doctor. Telephone reports and typed reports can be made
available within the hour, if requested. Being able to switch diagnosis and reporting
between the United Kingdom and Australia means that a pool of radiologists is always
available in their ‘awake’ hours, 24/7. Hospitals and clinics, such as those in regional areas,
are spared the expense of employing or developing a roster of their own radiologists.
One Australian company, Imaging Partners Online (IPO), provides such tele-radiology
CHAPTER 1
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 15
GLOBALISATION
15
08/06/19 07:40 PM
services using UK and Australian–qualified radiologists.15 While there is a growing demand
for tele-radiology services internationally, the ability to outsource medical services is heavily
restricted by national and state licensing and accreditation rules. Currently in Australia and
the United Kingdom, the only people authorised to read and diagnose scans in Australia
for UK patients are radiologists who qualified in Britain, are registered in Britain and living
in Australia. The only ones who can read and diagnose scans of Australian patients in the
United Kingdom must live there but be accredited and licensed in Australia. Dispersing
value-creation activities offshore can compress the time and lower the costs required to
deliver many services. Many such activities are outsourced to emerging and developing
nations, where skilled and unskilled labour is cheaper. However, cost considerations may
not be a sufficient motive. In the case of tele-radiology, the timely delivery of quality
service is the key to successful business in this area.
A consequence of the trend exemplified by companies such as Boeing and IPO is that it
is becoming irrelevant to talk about ‘Chinese products’, ‘Australian products’, ‘US products’
or ‘Korean products’. Increasingly, the outsourcing of productive activities to different
international suppliers and locations results in the creation of products that are global
in nature; that is, ‘global products’.16 But as with the globalisation of markets, companies
must be careful not to push the globalisation of production too far. As we will see in
later chapters, substantial impediments still make it difficult for companies to achieve
the optimal dispersion of their productive activities to locations around the globe. These
impediments include formal and informal barriers to trade between countries, barriers to
foreign direct investment (FDI), transportation and supply chain management costs, and
issues associated with economic and political risk. For example, government regulations and
professional ethics can limit the ability of hospitals to outsource the process of interpreting
medical images and of lawyers to outsource the preparation of legal briefs to emerging and
developing nations where the skilled professionals are cheaper.
Nevertheless, the globalisation of markets and production will continue. International
companies are important actors in this trend, their very actions fostering increased
globalisation. These companies, however, are merely responding in an efficient manner to
changing conditions in their operating environment—as well they should.
THE EMERGENCE OF GLOBAL INSTITUTIONS
GENERAL AGREEMENT ON
TARIFFS AND TRADE (GATT)
An international treaty that
committed signatories to lowering
barriers to the free flow of
goods across national borders; a
predecessor to the WTO
WORLD TRADE
ORGANIZATION (WTO)
The organisation that succeeded the
General Agreement on Tariffs and
Trade and now acts to police the
world trading system
16
PART 1
As markets globalise and an increasing proportion of business activity transcends
national borders, institutions are needed to help manage, regulate and police the
global marketplace, and to promote the establishment of multinational treaties to
govern the global business system. Over the past 60-plus years, a number of important
global institutions have been created to help perform these functions, including the
General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) and its successor the World Trade
Organization (WTO); the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and its sister institution the
World Bank; the United Nations (UN); the Group of Twenty (G20); and, more recently, the
China-backed Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank (AIIB). These institutions were created
by a voluntary agreement between individual nation-states and, apart from the G20, their
functions are enshrined in international treaties and agreements.
The World Trade Organization (WTO) (like its predecessor GATT) is primarily
responsible for policing the world trading system and making sure nation-states adhere
to the rules laid down in trade treaties signed by WTO member states. As of 2015, 164
members and observers that collectively accounted for 97 per cent of world trade were
WTO members, thereby giving the organisation enormous scope and influence. Over its
entire history, as did GATT, the WTO has promoted the lowering of barriers to cross-border
GLOBALISATION
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 16
08/06/19 07:40 PM
trade and investment. In doing so, the WTO has been the instrument of its member
states, which have sought to create a more open global business system unencumbered
by barriers to trade and investment between countries. Without an instrument such as
the WTO, the globalisation of markets and production is unlikely to have proceeded as
far as it has. However, as we shall see in this chapter and in Chapter 3 when we look
more closely at the WTO, critics charge that the organisation is usurping the national
sovereignty of individual nation-states and that it is failing to respond to fundamental shifts
in the global economy.
The International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World Bank were both created in 1944
by 44 nations that met at Bretton Woods, New Hampshire, in the United States. One of
the strong motives for forming these institutions and GATT, was to prevent recurrence
of the trade wars that had erupted during the 1920s and 1930s. During this period,
international trade and investment were severely restricted by the unilateral, retaliatory
imposition of tariffs and exchange rate devaluations as governments sought to protect
their own economies from the ravages of the Great Depression. The IMF was established
to maintain order in the international monetary system; the World Bank was set up to
promote economic development. In the 75 years since their creation, both institutions have
emerged as significant players in the global economy. The World Bank (or more formally the
International Bank of Reconstruction and Development) is the less controversial of the two
sister instruments. It has focused on providing financial and technical assistance to improve
living standards and reduce poverty in developing countries. In 2018, it had 189 member
countries across a diverse range of activities including providing an ebola recovery and
reconstruction project in Liberia, supporting the education of girls in Bangladesh, improving
health care delivery in Mexico, helping East Timor to rebuild upon independence and
helping to improve the delivery of local infrastructure services in northeastern Sri Lanka.17
The IMF, now with 189 members, is often seen as the lender of last resort to nationstates whose economies are in turmoil and whose currencies are losing value against
those of other nations. Repeatedly during the past decade, for example, the IMF has lent
money to the governments of troubled states, including Argentina, Indonesia, Mexico,
Russia, South Korea, Thailand, Turkey and Iceland. More recently the IMF has taken a very
proactive role in helping countries to cope with the fallout of the eurozone. However, IMF
loans come with strings attached: in return for loans, the IMF requires borrower nationstates to adopt specific economic policies aimed at returning their troubled economies to
stability and growth. These requirements have sparked controversy. Some critics charge
that the IMF’s policy recommendations are often inappropriate; others maintain that by
telling governments what economic policies they must adopt, the IMF, like the WTO, is
usurping the sovereignty of nation-states. Another criticism common to both the WTO
and the IMF is that their decision-making structures have failed to reflect the shifting
economic power in the global economy towards emerging economies, particularly the BRIC
group of countries (Brazil, Russia, India and China). We shall look at the debate over the
role of the IMF and the international monetary system in Chapter 4.
The United Nations (UN) was established on 24 October 1945 by 51 countries
committed to preserving peace through international cooperation and collective security.
Today, nearly every nation in the world belongs to the United Nations and membership
now totals 193 countries. When states become members of the United Nations, they agree
to accept the obligations of the UN Charter, an international treaty that establishes basic
principles of international relations. According to the Charter, the UN has four purposes:
•
to maintain international peace and security
•
to develop friendly relations among nations
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY
FUND (IMF)
The international institution set up
to maintain order in the international
monetary system
WORLD BANK
The international organisation
set up to promote economic
development, primarily by offering
low-interest loans to governments
of poorer nations
BRIC
Brazil, Russia, India and China; a
group of emerging economic powers
in the global economy
UNITED NATIONS (UN)
An international organisation
made up of 193 countries charged
with keeping international peace,
developing cooperation between
nations and promoting human rights
CHAPTER 1
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 17
GLOBALISATION
17
08/06/19 07:40 PM
© Eric Crama/Shutterstock
UNITED NATIONS CONFERENCE
ON TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT
(UNCTAD)
A UN body that promotes the
integration of developing countries
into the world economy as a means
of attaining sustainable economic
development
•
to cooperate in solving international problems and in promoting respect for human rights
•
to be a centre for harmonising the actions of nations.
Although the UN is perhaps best known for its peacekeeping role, one of the
organisation’s central mandates is the promotion of higher standards of living, full
employment and the conditions for economic and social progress and development—all
issues that are central to the creation of a vibrant global economy. As much as 70 per
cent of the work of the UN system is devoted to accomplishing this mandate. This effort
GROUP OF TWENTY (G20)
is clearly evident in the work performed by the United Nations Conference on Trade
An international forum comprising
the government representatives
and Development (UNCTAD). Established in 1964, UNCTAD promotes the integration of
of the G8 and other economies,
developing countries into the world economy as a means of attaining sustainable economic
including the emerging economies
development. The UN works closely with other international institutions such as the World
such as Brazil, China and India, as
a reflection of their rising global
Bank. Guiding the work is the belief that eradicating poverty and improving the wellbeing
economic and political power
of people everywhere are necessary steps in creating conditions for lasting world peace.18
Established in 1999, the Group of Twenty (G20) comprises the finance ministers and
ASIAN INFRASTRUCTURE
INVESTMENT BANK (AIIB)
central bank governors of the 19 largest economies in the world, plus representatives from the
A new multilateral development
European Union and the European Central Bank. Collectively, the G20 represents 90 per cent
bank focusing on funding
of global GDP and 80 per cent of international global trade. Originally established to formulate
infrastructure in Asia
a coordinated policy response to financial crises in developing
nations, in 2008 and 2009 it became the forum through
which major nations attempted to launch a coordinated
policy response to the GFC that started in the United States
and then rapidly spread around the world, ushering in the
first serious global economic recession since 1981.
The Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank (AIIB) is a
multilateral development bank (MDB) backed by China.
The bank was created to overcome an infrastructure gap in
Asia that is estimated to be over US$8 trillion, and partly
in response to the slow phase of reform and the lack of
recognition given by the existing organisations such as
the World Bank, IMF and ADB (Asian Development Bank)
to the new economic realities of the rise of the emerging
economies such as China. The United States opposed the
setting up of the bank on the grounds of lack of clarity on
corporate governance. However, 57 countries signed up
to the Prospective Founding Members (PFMs) meeting in
The G20 is not without controversy. Several anti-globalisation June 2015, including some of the United States’ closest allies
demonstrations have been held in host cities.
(Australia, Germany, Israel and the United Kingdom).19
LO 1.1
DRIVERS OF GLOBALISATION
As outlined in the previous discussion on the globalisation of markets and production,
the actions of consumers and international business facilitate globalisation—for example,
the consumer’s willingness to accept and source products globally, the outsourcing of
production by business to take advantage of national differences in resource endowments,
and the increased pressure on business to compete globally and match the market moves
of their rivals, These individual consumer and company actions or micro factors, however,
are sustained by two macro factors that underlie the trend towards greater globalisation.20
The first is the decline in barriers to the free flow of goods, services and capital that
has occurred since the end of World War II. The second factor is technological change,
particularly the dramatic developments in recent years in information and communication
technologies (ICT) and transportation technologies.
18
PART 1
GLOBALISATION
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 18
08/06/19 07:40 PM
As noted earlier, during the 1920s and 1930s many of the world’s nation-states erected
INTERNATIONAL TRADE
formidable barriers to international trade and foreign direct investment (FDI). International
When a company exports goods or
trade occurs when a company exports goods or services to buyers in another country.
services to buyers in another country
Foreign direct investment (FDI) occurs when a company invests resources in business
FOREIGN DIRECT
activities outside its home country, giving it some control over those activities. Many of
INVESTMENT (FDI)
the barriers to international trade took the form of high tariffs on imports of manufactured
When a firm invests resources in
goods. The typical aim of such tariffs was to protect domestic industries from foreign
business activities outside its home
competition. One consequence, however, was ‘beggar-thy-neighbour’ retaliatory trade
country, giving it some control over
those activities
policies, with countries progressively raising trade barriers against each other. (We look at
the issue of ‘beggar-thy-neighbour’ policies further in Chapters 3 and 4.) Ultimately, this
policy depressed world demand and contributed to the Great Depression of the 1930s.
Having learned from this experience, the advanced industrial nations of the West
committed themselves after World War II to removing barriers to the free flow of goods,
services and capital between nations.21 This goal was enshrined in the General Agreement
on Tariffs and Trade. Under the umbrella of GATT (now subsumed under the WTO), eight
completed rounds of negotiations among member states have worked to lower barriers to the
free flow of goods and services, the most notable to date being the Uruguay Round, signedoff in December 1993.22 Table 1.1 summarises the impact of GATT agreements on average
tariff rates for non-agricultural goods (i.e. manufactured goods).
As can be seen, the average rates have fallen significantly
since 1950 and now stand at less than 4 per cent. This
reduction in tariff rates achieved by the once dominant
economic powers and exporters—the United States, Japan
and countries of the European Union—has not been matched
universally, however. For example, in 2018, Australia’s average
tariff rate on manufacturing imports was 11.0 per cent,
China’s was 9.1 per cent, Brazil’s 30.8 per cent, India’s 34.6
per cent and Indonesia’s 35.6 per cent.23 This discrepancy in
tariffs between the old and the emerging economic powers
such as the BRIC group has been a hindrance to achieving
agreement in current trade negotiations at the WTO.
In late 2001, the WTO launched the current round of
talks, the Doha Round, aimed at further liberalising the
global trade and investment framework. The talks were
The United Nations has the important goal of improving the
wellbeing of people around the world.
scheduled initially to last three years, but they haltingly
TABLE 1.1
Average tariff rates on manufactured products as percentage of value
1913
1950
1990
2017
France
21
18
5.9
1.9
Germany
20
26
5.9
1.9
Italy
18
25
5.9
1.9
Japan
30
—
5.3
2.1
5
11
5.9
1.9
20
9
4.4
1.9
—
23
5.9
1.9
44
14
4.8
3.0
The Netherlands
Sweden
United Kingdom
United States
SOURCE: The 1913–1990 data are from ‘Who Wants to Be a Giant?’, The Economist: A Survey of the Multinationals, 24
June 1995, pp. 3–4; the 2017 data is from the World Bank, World Development Indicators.
CHAPTER 1
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 19
GLOBALISATION
19
08/06/19 07:40 PM
© blurAZ/Shutterstock
Declining trade and investment barriers
continue—as they have stalled on a number of occasions due to opposition from several key
nations. (These issues are discussed further in Chapter 3.)
The lowering of barriers to international trade enables companies to view the world,
rather than a single country, as their market. The lowering of trade and investment barriers
also allows companies to base production at the optimal location for that activity. Thus, a
company might design a product in one country, produce component parts in two other
countries, assemble the product in yet another country, and then export the finished
product around the world.
The role of technological change
The lowering of trade barriers made globalisation of markets and production a theoretical
possibility. Technological change has made it a tangible reality. Since the end of World War II,
the world has seen major advances in communication, information processing and transportation
technologies, including the explosive emergence of the internet and the world wide web.
Microprocessors and telecommunications
MOORE’S LAW
The premise that the power of
microprocessor technology doubles
and its cost of production drops by
half every 18 months
Perhaps the single most important innovation has been the development of the microprocessor,
which has enabled the explosive growth of high-power, low-cost computing, vastly increasing
the amount of information that can be processed by individuals and companies. The
microprocessor also underlies many recent advances in telecommunications technology. Over
the past 30 years, global communications have been revolutionised by developments in satellite,
optical fibre and wireless technologies, and the internet and the web. These technologies rely
on the microprocessor to encode, transmit and decode the vast amount of information that
flows along these electronic highways. The cost of microprocessors continues to fall, while
their power increases (a phenomenon known as Moore’s Law, which predicts that the power of
microprocessor technology doubles and its cost of production falls by half every 18 months).24
The internet and the world wide web
The rapid growth of the web is the latest expression of communications development. In
1990, fewer than one million users were connected to the internet. By 1995, the figure
had risen to 50 million. By 2019, this figure had reached 4.4 billion users, or about 56 per
cent of the world’s population.25 China has the largest internet population in the world
and the largest population of online shoppers. Included in the expanding volume of webbased traffic is a growing percentage of cross-border trade in both goods and services.
Advances in ICT have enabled many small companies to sell into international markets
as they can reach a wide audience without the expense of setting up ‘bricks-and-mortar’
shop fronts. ICT has facilitated an increase in the offshoring of production. It has provided
the means to coordinate the flow of component parts along the networks that comprise
the global supply chains of modern production systems.
Viewed globally, the web is emerging as an equaliser. It rolls back some of the constraints
of location, scale and time zones.26 The web makes it much easier for buyers and sellers to
find each other, wherever they may be located and whatever their size. It allows businesses,
both small and large, to expand their global presence at a lower cost than ever before. It
makes a virtue out of different time zones, enabling teams located in different time zones
around the world to continue to provide a service as if they were a 24/7 operation.
Transport technology
In addition to developments in communication technology, several major innovations in
transport technology have occurred since World War II. In economic terms, the most
important are probably the development of commercial jet aircraft and superfreighters, and
the introduction of containerisation, which simplifies trans-shipment from one mode of
20
PART 1
GLOBALISATION
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 20
08/06/19 07:40 PM
•
the efficiency of the clearance process by border control agencies
•
the quality of trade and transport infrastructure (ports, roads, rail, ICT)
•
the ease of arranging competitively priced shipments
•
the competence and quality of transport operators and customs brokers
•
the ability to track consignments
•
timeliness of delivery.27
Implications for the globalisation of production and markets
As transport costs associated with the globalisation of production declined, dispersal of
production to geographically separate locations became more economical. As a result of
the technological innovations discussed above, the real costs of information processing and
communication have fallen dramatically in the past three decades. These developments make
it possible for a company to create and then manage a globally dispersed and networked
production system, further facilitating the globalisation of production. A worldwide
communications network has become essential for many international businesses.
For example, computer maker Dell revolutionised supply-chain management when
it adopted a ‘direct make-to-order’ business model to computer manufacturing while its
competitors were continuing to use ‘make-to-stock’ processes. The adoption of this new
strategy was made possible by the technological advances in transport and ICT, and it
promoted Dell for a time to the status of number one computer company globally. Dell uses
the internet to coordinate and control a globally dispersed production system to such an
extent that it is able to hold only three days of inventory at its assembly locations. Dell’s
internet-based system records orders for computer equipment as they are submitted by
CHAPTER 1
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 21
GLOBALISATION
21
08/06/19 07:40 PM
© hxdyl/Shutterstock
transport to another. The advent of commercial jet travel,
by reducing the time needed to get from one location
to another, has effectively shrunk the globe. Australian
and New Zealand producers of merchandise exports,
geographically distant from the large northern-hemisphere
markets, retain competitiveness as the time and costs to
these markets are reduced. For example, with the advent of
jet travel and ‘cold chain’ logistics technologies, Australian
and New Zealand aquaculture producers can supply the
high-margin live fish and crustacean markets of Asia.
Reliable delivery of goods within narrow time windows
is important to a firm’s ability to participate and compete
not only in fresh food markets, but also in the just-in-time
supply-chain regimes of global manufacturing. As a result
Before the advent of containerisation, it could take several
days and several hundred stevedores to unload a ship and
of the efficiency gains associated with containerisation,
reload goods on to trucks and trains.
transport costs have plummeted. This makes it much more
economical to ship goods around the globe by air and by
sea, thereby helping to drive the globalisation of markets and production.
Access to jet aircraft and container ships, however, is only part of the story in facilitating
trade expansion and export diversification or attracting foreign direct investment to a
particular location. The potential cost savings of these transport technologies are lost if, for
example, the bureaucracy of customs checks or the poor quality of the port infrastructure
causes a container to sit on a loading dock for an inordinate amount of time. The World
Bank identifies factors that affect what it calls ‘logistics performance’, any one of which
might explain a disruption to trade and add to trade costs:
customers via the company’s website and then immediately transmits the resulting orders for
components to various suppliers around the world, which have a real-time look at Dell’s order
flow and can adjust their production schedules accordingly. Given the low cost of airfreight,
Dell can use air transport to speed up the delivery of the critical components to meet
unanticipated demand shifts without delaying the shipment of the final product to consumers.
Dell also uses modern information and communication technologies as a marketing
tool. In 2010, Dell launched its Social Media Listening Command Center (LCC). This centre
monitors the questions and opinions about Dell and its products that people express on all
forms of social media, from Facebook and Twitter to blogs, forums and news sites. Every
day, Dell monitors and analyses nearly 25 000 conversations about Dell—and these are just
the ones in English.28 Dell redesigned the keypad of one of its best selling laptops because
the buzz on social media was that the apostrophe was positioned awkwardly and needed
to be shifted. The buzz of social media, of course, crosses national borders, thus further
promoting the globalisation of markets. We examine issues in international marketing and
international supply chain management in more detail in Chapters 12 and 13.
In addition to the globalisation of production, technological innovations have also
facilitated the globalisation of markets. Low-cost global communications networks such
as the world wide web, have helped create electronic global marketplaces. For example,
an Indian legal company sells its services to a mining multinational, Rio Tinto, on a global
basis. Since commencing in 1995, Amazon.com has become the world’s largest online
retailer. Faster, low-cost transport has made it more economical to ship products around
the world, thereby helping to create global markets. For example, due to the tumbling
costs of transporting goods by air, roses grown in Ecuador can be cut and sold in cities
of Europe and the United States two days later while they are still fresh. This has given
rise to an industry in Ecuador that did not exist 20 years ago and now supplies a global
market for roses. In addition, low-cost jet travel has resulted in the mass movement of
people between countries. This has reduced the cultural distance between countries and
is bringing about some convergence of consumer tastes and preferences. At the same time,
global communication networks and global media such as CNN and the BBC are creating
a worldwide culture. In any society, the media are primary conveyors of culture: as global
media develops and social media becomes more popular, we must expect the evolution of
something akin to a global culture. A logical result of this evolution is the emergence of
global markets for consumer products. The first signs of this are already apparent. It is as
easy to find a McDonald’s restaurant in Beijing as it is in New York, to buy an iPad in Rio
de Janeiro as it is in Berlin, and to buy Prada accessories in Melbourne as it is in Milan.
Despite these trends, we must be careful not to overemphasise their importance.
While modern communication and transportation technologies are ushering in the ‘global
village’, significant national differences remain in culture, consumer preferences and
business practices. In competition with CNN and BBC for global viewers is the influential
Arab news and public affairs broadcaster, Al Jazeera. Based in Qatar and owned by the
Emirate of Qatar, it reaches an estimated audience of 40 million in the Arab world. It has
uncensored independence, which is unusual for a broadcaster in the Arab world.29 The
success of Al Jazeera suggests that the creation of a global culture still has some way to go.
To accommodate two different cultural traditions, there are two news operations, Al Jazeera
Arabic and Al Jazeera English; and Al Jazeera itself has had to confront national cultural
difference. The Al Jazeera English network is virtually locked out of the United States. It
can be accessed by the internet, but none of the major cable TV networks will carry its
programs. It is thought of as ‘an anti-American network’. To gain a more significant foothold
in the United States, Al Jazeera was forced to acquire its own, albeit small, cable network.30
A company that ignores differences between countries does so at its peril. We shall stress
this point repeatedly throughout this book and elaborate on it in later chapters.
22
PART 1
GLOBALISATION
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 22
08/06/19 07:40 PM
THE CHANGING SHAPE OF THE GLOBAL ECONOMY
LO 1.2, 1.3
Hand in hand with the trend towards globalisation has been a fairly dramatic change in
the shape of the global economy over the past 50 years. As late as the 1960s, four stylised
characteristics described the global economy. The first was the United States, Western
European and Japanese dominance in the world economy and world trade picture,
particularly US dominance. The second was the dominance by these same countries in
world foreign direct investment. Related to this, the third fact was the dominance of large,
multinationals from these countries on the international business scene. The fourth was
that roughly half the globe—the centrally planned economies of the Communist world—was
off-limits to Western international businesses. As will be explained below, all four of these
qualities either have changed or are now changing rapidly. The following will be examined:
•
the changing world output and world trade picture
•
the changing foreign direct investment picture
•
the changing nature of the multinational enterprise
•
the changing world order.
The changing world output and world trade picture
In the early 1960s, the United States was by far the world’s dominant industrial power.
In 1963, the United States accounted for 40.3 per cent of world output. Since then, there
has been a shift in the world’s economic centre of gravity. By 2015, the United States
accounted for 16.1 per cent of world output, still by far the world’s largest industrial power
but down significantly in relative size since the 1960s (see Table 1.2). Nor was the United
States the only developed nation to see its relative standing slip. Germany, France and
the United Kingdom—all nations that were among the first to industrialise—experienced
significant declines. The change in the position of these countries was not an absolute
decline, since these economies continued to grow. Rather, it was a relative decline,
reflecting the faster economic growth of several other economies, particularly in China
and India. In the 1970s, the world pattern of production and trade could be described
as bipolar, dominated by the United States and the Western European countries. By the
beginning of the 1990s, it was shifting to a more tripolar pattern with the rise of the
Japanese economy. As can be seen from Table 1.2, Japan’s share of world production had
leapfrogged that of individual European countries and remains dominant, despite Japan
incurring periods of negative economic growth over the decade of the 2000s. By the end
of the 2000s, however, the tripolar pattern is no longer clear. As can be seen in Table 1.2,
the United States and the integrated economies of the European Union, as a single entity,
still dominate, but China and India now each contribute more to global production than
any one of the Western European countries. Their share of world output has also surpassed
that of Japan. Brazil and Russia are also now contributing as much as the individual
Western European economies. A new pattern of world production has emerged.
As emerging economies such as China, India, Russia and Brazil continue to grow, a
further relative decline in the share of world output and world exports accounted for by
the United States and other long-established industrialised nations seems likely. By itself,
this is not bad. The relative decline of the United States reflects the growing economic
development and industrialisation of the world economy, as opposed to any absolute
decline in the robustness of the US economy. A strong US economy and market remain
necessary to support the growth and development of these emerging economies.
Running parallel to the declining economic dominance of the world economy by
nations such as the United States, the United Kingdom, Japan and Germany is a decline in
CHAPTER 1
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 23
GLOBALISATION
23
08/06/19 07:40 PM
TABLE 1.2
The changing pattern of world output and trade
SHARE OF WORLD
COUNTRY
United States
GDP OUTPUT (%), 1963
GDP OUTPUT (%), 2014
EXPORTS (%), 2014
40.3
16.1
10.0
Germany
9.7
3.4
7.5
France
6.3
2.4
3.6
Italy
3.4
2.0
2.7
United Kingdom
6.5
2.4
3.6
Japan
5.5
4.4
3.7
China
na
16.3
10.5
India
na
6.8
2.1
Russia
na
3.3
2.4
Brazil
na
3.0
1.1
SOURCES: IMF, World Economic Outlook, October 2015, accessed via www.imf.org/​external/​pubs/​f t/weo/​2015/​01/​pdf/​
text.pdf on 12 September 2015; data for 1963 derived from N. Hood and J. Young, The Economics of the Multinational
Enterprise, New York, Longman, 1973; GDP output data based on purchasing power parity figures, which adjust the
value of GDP to reflect the cost of living in various economies—exports comprise goods and services.
GROUP OF EIGHT (G8)
An international forum comprising
the government representatives of
eight Western industrial economies:
Canada, France, Germany, Italy,
Japan, the United Kingdom, the
United States and a relatively new
member, Russia
the political power of these nations in the major global economic forums. One illustration
is the rise to prominence of the G20 at the expense of the G8. Along with institutions
such as the IMF, the G20 has become the premium forum when collective economic
leadership and problem solving are called for to address such global issues as energy security,
climate change and international financial regulation. The Group of Eight (G8) comprises
representatives of the governments of Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, Russia, the
United Kingdom and the United States. It represents 900 million people. Where once
the market-capitalist democracies of the G8 (that excludes Russia at the time) dominated
global economic leadership, authoritarian states such as China, Russia and Saudi Arabia are
now exerting more influence. There is also no certainty that the world’s democracies will
naturally stick together. For example, on the matter of climate change, four of the most
economically and politically strategic democracies—Brazil, South Africa, India and Turkey—
sided with China over caps on greenhouse emissions. Their status as a developing economy
was more important to them than their status as a democracy.31 While authoritarian
governments and developing countries continue to harbour concerns about the inequities of
US-led, Western-world global capitalism, and as their influence in economic forums increases,
continuing globalisation and trade liberalisation are not guaranteed. The freedom to pursue
international business opportunities may well be curbed by increased state intervention.
Forecasts are not always correct, but there is a shift in the economic geography of the
world. For international businesses, the implications of this changing economic geography
are clear: many of tomorrow’s economic opportunities will be found in the developing
nations of the world, despite their attendant risks, and many of tomorrow’s most capable
competitors will also emerge from these regions.
The changing foreign direct investment picture
In the 1960s, US companies accounted for 66.3 per cent of worldwide FDI flows. British
companies were second, accounting for 10.5 per cent. As a consequence, companies from
the United States and the United Kingdom accumulated a considerable stock of productive
assets abroad. Over time as the barriers to the free flow of goods, services and investment
fell and as other countries began to prosper and increase their share of world output, nonUS companies increasingly began to invest across national borders. The motivation for
24
PART 1
GLOBALISATION
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 24
08/06/19 07:40 PM
a
ia
Ind
on
om
i
De
ve
lop
ing
ec
Ch
in
es
n
pa
Ja
es
at
St
ed
Un
it
Un
it
ed
Ki
ng
do
m
much of this foreign direct investment by non-US companies was the desire to disperse
production activities to optimal locations and to build a direct presence in major foreign
markets. Thus, beginning in the 1970s, European and Japanese companies began to
shift labour-intensive manufacturing operations from their home markets to developing
nations where labour costs were lower. In addition, many Japanese companies invested in
North America and Europe, often as a hedge against
unfavourable currency movements and the possible
40%
35%
imposition of trade barriers. For example, Toyota, the
30%
Japanese motor vehicle company, rapidly increased its
25%
investment in motor vehicle production facilities in
20%
the United States and Europe during the late 1980s
15%
10%
and early 1990s. Toyota executives believed that an
5%
increasingly strong Japanese yen would price Japanese
0%
motor vehicle exports out of foreign markets; therefore,
production in the most important foreign markets, as
opposed to exports from Japan, made sense. Toyota also
undertook these investments to head off the growing
political pressures about automotive industry job losses
in the United States and Europe to restrict Japanese
2000
2010
2017
motor vehicle imports in those markets.
The consequence of these developments is illustrated in Figure 1.1, which shows the
changing share of FDI stock sourced from selected economies and regions over the period
2000 to 2017. Individual economies such as the United States, the United Kingdom and Japan
are still the dominant sources of FDI, but this dominance has declined in the past two-anda-half decades. The stock of FDI accounted for by companies from developing countries has
increased more than twofold. Companies from developing East Asia and South-East Asia
account for most of this growth, particularly companies from Hong Kong, Singapore, mainland
China, Taiwan and South Korea. Hong Kong ranks among one of the world’s largest sources of
FDI as companies based there launch into neighbouring mainland China and East Asia.
Not all FDI flows and stock are initiated and held by privately-owned, commercial
businesses. A relatively new type of investor has appeared on the scene, the sovereign
wealth fund (SWF). A sovereign wealth fund is a government-controlled fund that manages
and invests government savings. The investment strategies and objectives tend to be
different from those of the traditional, privately-owned multinational enterprise. Australia’s
Future Fund and Singapore’s Temasek Holdings are examples. Although SWFs have been
in existence since the 1950s, especially in oil-producing countries, they have grown
considerably in number and size in the past decade. Sovereign wealth funds, including
those managed by the governments of major oil-exporting developing countries and
emerging economic powers such as China, had a total of some US$7.1 trillion in assets. (The
largest SWF is the Norwegian government’s Pension Fund Global—worth $945 billion.32)
Despite their very small contribution to FDI, SWFs have attracted what appears to be
a disproportionate amount of scrutiny by authorities. There are several reasons for this
close scrutiny.33 Much of the recent growth in SWFs has come from the large balance of
payments surpluses run, in particular, by China and other East Asian economies. These
economies have been accumulating foreign exchange reserves on an unprecedented scale
as a result of intervention by their governments to maintain what are considered to be
undervalued exchange rates for their currencies. Low exchange rates favour their exporters
at the expense of foreign exporters. Exchange rates and balance of payments surpluses are
discussed in more detail in Chapter 4.
Figures 1.2 and 1.3 illustrate two other important trends in the global economy: the
first is the strong growth in cross-border flows in FDI, albeit with volatile swings through
FIGURE 1.1
Source of FDI stock; percentage of
world total of FDI stock, 2000, 2014
and 2017, selected economies.
SOURCE: Calculated by the author
from data in UNCTAD, World Investment
Report 2018, Annex Tables, accessed via
https://unctad.org/en/PublicationsLibrary/
wir2018_en.pdf on 26 March 2019.
SOVEREIGN WEALTH FUND (SWF)
A government-controlled fund that
manages and invests government
savings
CHAPTER 1
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 25
GLOBALISATION
25
08/06/19 07:40 PM
FIGURE 1.2
FDI inflows, 1991–2017,
by economy type, annual,
US$ million.
2 500 000
SOURCE: Calculated by the author
from data in UNCTAD, World
Investment Report 2018, Annex
Tables, accessed via https://
unctad.org/en/PublicationsLibrary/
wir2018_en.pdf on 26 March 2019.
2 000 000
Transition economies
Developed economies
Developing economies
1 500 000
1 000 000
500 000
SOURCE: Calculated by the author from
data in UNCTAD, World Investment Report
2018, Annex Tables, accessed via https://
unctad.org/en/PublicationsLibrary/
wir2018_en.pdf on 26 March 2019.
99
20
00
20
01
20
02
20
03
20
04
20
05
20
06
20
07
20
08
20
09
20
10
20
11
20
12
20
13
20
14
20
15
20
16
20
17
98
19
97
19
96
19
95
19
19
19
94
92
93
19
25
Percentage of total world
FIGURE 1.3
FDI inflows, 2000, 2011 and 2017,
selected countries, percentage of
world total.
19
19
91
0
20
15
10
5
0
Australia
2000
Brazil
China
2011
2017
India
Russia
UK
US
peaks and troughs. The second is the growing importance of developing and transition
nations (the latter are the nations of Central and Eastern Europe, including Russia) as the
destination of FDI. Throughout the 1990s, the amount of investment directed at both
developed and developing nations increased dramatically, a trend that reflects the increasing
internationalisation of business corporations. There was a dramatic slump during the global
economic recession in 2001–03 and again during the GFC of 2007–09, but on both occasions
FDI recovered and continued on its long-term growth trend. The second trend, shown in
Figure 1.2, is the increasing amount of FDI since 1991 directed to developing economies; also,
since the economic and political reforms in the former Communist countries of Central and
Eastern Europe, post-1990 there has been an increase in FDI to these transition economies.
This change in the destination of FDI is also shown in Figure 1.3. While the United States
and the United Kingdom have tended to attract the largest share of FDI, it is a declining
26
PART 1
GLOBALISATION
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 26
08/06/19 07:40 PM
EMERGING MARKETS
INDIA’S IT SOFTWARE SECTOR
Some 25 years ago, a number of small software
enterprises was established in Bangalore, India. Typical
of these enterprises was Infosys Technologies, which
was started by seven Indian entrepreneurs with about
$1000 among them. Infosys now has annual revenue
of $7.4 billion and some 155 600 employees, but it is
just one of more than a hundred software companies
clustered around Bangalore, which has become the
epicentre of India’s fast-growing information technology
sector. From a standing start in the mid-1980s, by 2012
this sector was generating export sales of $68 billion.
The growth of the Indian software sector has been
based on four factors. First, the country has an
abundant supply of engineering talent. Every year,
Indian universities graduate some 400 000 engineers.
Second, labour costs in India have historically been
low. As recently as 2008, the cost to hire an Indian
graduate was roughly 12 per cent of the cost of
hiring an American or Australian graduate (this is now
changing, with salaries increasing in India). Third, many
Indians are fluent in English, which makes coordination
between Western companies and India easier. Fourth,
due to time differences, Indians can work while many
other advanced English-speaking countries are asleep.
Initially, Indian software enterprises focused on the
low end of the software industry, supplying basic
software development and testing services to Western
companies. But as the industry has grown in size and
sophistication, Indian companies have moved up the
market. Today, the leading Indian companies compete
directly with the likes of IBM and EDS for large
software development projects, business process
outsourcing contracts, and information technology
consulting services. Over the past 15 years, these
markets have boomed, with Indian enterprises
capturing a large slice of the pie. One response of
Western companies to this emerging competitive
threat has been to invest in India to garner the same
kind of economic advantages that Indian companies
enjoy. IBM, for example, has invested $2 billion in its
Indian operations and now has 150 000 employees
located there, more than in any other country.
Microsoft, too, has made major investments in India,
including a research and development (R&D) centre in
Hyderabad that employs 4000 people and was located
there specifically to tap into talented Indian engineers
who did not want to move overseas.
SOURCES: ‘America’s pain, India’s gain: outsourcing’, The Economist, 11 January 2003, p. 59; ‘The world is our oyster’, The Economist, 7 October 2006,
pp. 9–10; ‘IBM and globalization: hungry tiger, dancing elephant’, The Economist, 7 April 2007, pp. 67–69; P. Mishra, ‘New billing model may hit India’s
software exports’, Live Mint, 14 February 2013; ‘India’s outsourcing business: on the turn’, The Economist, 19 January 2013.
share. Their share has almost halved over the past decade as developing economies such as
the BRIC nations attract a larger share. As we shall see later in this book, the sustained flow
of foreign investment into developing nations is an important stimulus for economic growth.
Just as Australia’s economy has relied on FDI to fuel its development, particularly via the
development of its mining sector, attracting more FDI bodes well for the future of countries
such as Brazil, Russia, India and China, who are the leading beneficiaries of these trends.
The changing nature of the multinational enterprise
A multinational enterprise (MNE) is any business that has productive activities
in two or more countries. Since the 1960s, two notable trends in the character of
multinational enterprises have been (1) the rise of non-US multinationals; and (2) the
growth of m
­ ini-multinationals.
MULTINATIONAL
ENTERPRISE (MNE)
Any business that has productive
activities in two or more countries
CHAPTER 1
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 27
GLOBALISATION
27
08/06/19 07:40 PM
Multinationals
In the 1960s, global business activity was dominated by large US multinational corporations.
With US firms accounting for about two-thirds of foreign direct investment during the
1960s, one would expect most multinationals to be US enterprises. In 1973, 48 per cent
of the world’s 260 largest multinationals were US companies. Figure 1.1, however, implies
that the dominance of US multinationals in terms of holdings of FDI assets has declined.
In terms of the size of the multinationals, the ranks of the world’s largest multinationals
are still dominated by US companies and companies from other developed nations. Names
of such companies that are globally recognisable include General Electrics (US), Toyota
Motor Corporation (Japan), Vodafone Group (UK), Siemens AG (Germany), Veolia (France)
and BHP (Australia/United Kingdom). While most of the largest multinationals originate in
the developed countries, multinationals from developing countries are beginning to make
their presence felt in the global economy. Some of the names of multinationals may not be
as recognisable universally as those from the developed countries but include Hutchinson
Whampoa (Hong Kong), Vale SA (Brazil), Cemex (Mexico), Petronas (Malaysia), Citic Group
(China), Tata Steel (India), Rusal (Russia) and Sappi (South Africa).
Among the developing countries, Asia remains by far the major home-region for
multinationals. As the number of multinational enterprises from the world’s developing
countries grows, we can expect these enterprises to emerge as important competitors in
global markets. There will be a further shift of the axis of the world economy away from North
America and Western Europe and a threat to the long-term dominance of Western companies.
The rise of mini-multinationals
Another trend in international business has been the growth of small and medium-sized
multinationals (mini-multinationals).34 When people think of international businesses,
they tend to think of firms such as GE, Vodafone, Toyota, Rio Tinto and so on—large,
complex multinational corporations with operations that span the globe. Although most
international trade and investment is still conducted by such large companies, many small
and medium-sized businesses are becoming increasingly involved in international trade
and investment as highlighted by the Opening Case. As we noted previously, the rise of
the internet has lowered the barriers that small companies face in providing products and
services internationally and in building international sales.
For example, Comvita, with its headquarters and original manufacturing base at
Paengaroa, New Zealand, is a natural health and wellness company that manufactures
therapeutic apicultural products, including the unique Manuka honey-based products
with their exceptional antibacterial qualities. It began as a small two-person local operation
in 1974, but is now a listed company. It is the world’s largest manufacturer and marketer
of Manuka honey, and also produces a diversified range of products in health food, health
care, beauty and personal care and medi-honey. In 2007, the company had a staff of 120
worldwide, which has now grown to 500 in eight countries. More than half of the staff
is located outside New Zealand. Nearly 70 per cent of its NZ$153 million annual sales is
generated in foreign markets.35
The changing world order
Between 1989 and 1991, a series of remarkable democratic revolutions swept the Communist
world. For reasons that are explored in more detail in Chapters 6 and 7, in country after
country throughout Eastern Europe and eventually in the Soviet Union itself, Communist
Party governments collapsed. The Soviet Union is now receding into history, having been
replaced by 15 independent republics. Czechoslovakia has divided itself into two states, while
Yugoslavia dissolved after a bloody civil war, thankfully now over, into five successor states.
28
PART 1
GLOBALISATION
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 28
08/06/19 07:40 PM
ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
RISE OF PROTECTIONISM
For over half a century, the US and other developed
countries championed free trade and globalisation. It
brought unprecedented growth and prosperity to millions
of people around the world. However, it hollowed out
the manufacturing sector and increased income
inequality in developed countries, leading to the rise of
protectionist right-wing politicians such as Donald Trump.
Will their mercantilist views (see Chapter 2) bring an
end to globalisation? Is globalisation the key reason for
the loss of manufacturing in developed countries, as
suggested by protectionist politicians?
SOURCE: T. Meyer and G. Sitaraman, ‘A Trade Policy for All: Market Liberalization Should Be a Means, Not an End’, Foreign Affairs, 26 June 2018,
accessed via www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/2018-06-26/trade-policy-all on 3 July 2019.
Many of the former Communist nations of Europe and Asia seem to have shown a
commitment to democratic politics and free market economies. If this continues, the
opportunities for international businesses will continue to be enormous. For half a century,
these countries were essentially closed to Western international businesses. Now they
present a host of export and investment opportunities. Just how this will play out over the
next decade or two is difficult to say. The economies of many of the former Communist
states are still relatively undeveloped, and their continued commitment to democracy
and free market economies cannot be taken for granted. Disturbing signs of growing
unrest and totalitarian tendencies continue to be seen in several Eastern European and
Central Asian states, including Russia, which under the presidencies of Vladimir Putin and
Dmitry Medvedev have shown signs of shifting back towards greater state involvement in
economic activity. Findings from Freedom in the World 2015, Freedom House’s annual report
on the state of global freedom, reveal that democracy declined worldwide for the tenth
year in 2015, particularly in the Middle East.36 Thus, the risks involved in doing business in
such countries are high, but so may be the returns.
The 2007–09 GFC caused a reassessment of the extent to which governments
should intervene in Western industrialised economies. To this point in time,
the dominant ideology was one of free markets, private ownership and reduced
government regulation. The events of the GFC, however, brought into question the efficacy
of such a model. For fear of systemic collapse, governments became convinced that they had
to usurp the market and intervene. The US and the UK governments bought controlling
interests in private businesses—in effect, for a country such as the United Kingdom, this
meant reversing the privatisation trend by renationalising parts of industry. In the United
States, for example, the government bought 61 per cent of General Motors (GM), once one
of the largest, private non-financial multinationals in the world, and in addition provided
loans from taxpayer funds to assist GM through bankruptcy. The UK government took
control of three financial institutions—the Royal Bank of Scotland, Lloyd’s Banking Group
and Northern Rock. In Australia, the government offered the major banks guaranteed access
to capital to maintain public confidence in the financial sector. Again, a complete move to
free market economies with declining state intervention cannot be taken for granted.
CHAPTER 1
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 29
GLOBALISATION
29
08/06/19 07:40 PM
LO 1.3
The global economy of the 21st century:
The emerging markets century?
Opportunities and risks
As discussed above, the past quarter of a century has seen rapid changes in the global
economy. Barriers to the free flow of goods, services and foreign investment have been
coming down. The volume of cross-border trade and investment has been growing more
rapidly than global output, indicating that national economies are becoming more closely
integrated into a single, interdependent, global economic system. As their economies
advance, more nations are joining the ranks of the developed world. A generation ago,
countries such as South Korea and Taiwan were viewed as second-tier developing nations.
Now they boast large economies, and their companies are major players in many global
industries. The move towards a global economy has been further strengthened by the
widespread adoption of liberal economic policies by countries that had firmly opposed
them for two generations or more. Thus, in keeping with the normative prescriptions of
liberal economic ideology, in country after country, we have seen state-owned businesses
privatised, widespread deregulation adopted, markets opened to more competition, and
commitment increased to removing barriers to cross-border trade and investment. This
suggests that over the next few decades, countries such as the Czech Republic (Czechia),
Mexico, Poland, Brazil, China, India, Turkey and South Africa may build powerful marketoriented economies. In short, current trends indicate that the world is moving rapidly
towards an economic system that is more favourable for international business.
But it is always hazardous to use established trends to predict the future. The world
may be moving towards a more global economic system, but globalisation is not inevitable.
Countries may pull back from the recent commitment to liberal economic ideology if their
experiences do not match their expectations. Also, greater globalisation brings with it risks
of its own. The GFC of 2007–09 and the emergence of SWFs have spawned a rise in trade
and investment protectionist sentiment. Clearly, such reversals make it a tougher world
for international businesses. In addition, there are many powerful voices that are critical of
globalisation. These critics blame globalisation for many of today’s ills, including job losses,
growing income inequality, food insecurity and climate change. The responses to resolve
these ills by the anti-globalisation forces tend to have two common threads. They are, one,
to increase the level of oversight and regulation of cross-border trade and investment at
a domestic or global level; and, two, to de-globalise—that is, to re-orient economies away
from global markets and global production chains and towards local and regional markets
and production.37 Should the anti-globalisation forces win the ears of the policymakers, the
outcomes would be anathema to international business.
Emerging market economies
There is little doubt that if a business is intending to expand internationally, it would
have in its sights the economies of the likes of China and India. Their large size in terms
of population and national production, their above-average rates of economic growth,
their rising living standards, their attraction to foreign investors and the increasing
presence of their multinationals on the world stage should certainly grab the attention
of any international business manager investigating business opportunities. (Concepts
and measures of economic growth and development and the comparative economic
performance of nations are examined in more detail in Chapter 7.) As noted above, the
rapid growth of the developing and emerging economies is changing the shape of the
global economy. This is clearly illustrated by the comparative growth rates of the world’s
two largest economies, the United States and China. If China continues to grow at current
rates, which average nearly double the rate of US economic growth, China’s economy will
30
PART 1
GLOBALISATION
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 30
08/06/19 07:40 PM
be larger than the US economy. The US per capita income, however, is still expected to
be four times larger than that of China.38 The economies like those of China and India are
developing and a business that enters these markets could grow with them.
Map 1.1 identifies 25 countries classified as emerging market economies. The vast
majority of these countries are common to the lists developed by the official organisations
such as the IMF and the equity-index vendors such as MSCI and FTSE according to their
definition of emerging markets. The status of a country as a developed or developing/
emerging economy, however, can change over time. Lists will also differ because the
assignment of the status relies on subjective judgement. The assignment of weights to each
criterion is a subjective judgement. Many of the criteria listed above are qualitative. The
debate over the status of South Korea is an example of the possibility of a change in status.
The status of countries such as Greece must also be in some doubt as a consequence of the
eurozone crisis. It is currently ranked as a developed country, but the eurozone crisis has
exposed many structural weaknesses of the economy and its apparent incapacity to sustain
any economic growth even with the substantial financial bailouts from the IMF and its
fellow EU members. The Economist perhaps best sums up why there is no definitive list of
emerging markets:
Emerging markets is a useful term precisely because it is imprecise. Coined for the
convenience of investors looking for somewhere exciting to put their money, it covers a
bewildering range of economies with little in common, except that they are not too rich,
not too poor and not too closed to foreign capital.39
The quote from The Economist contains a note of caution for the international business
manager. While emerging markets do have common features and they are changing the
shape of global markets, they are also different to each other in many ways. They are also
different to developed markets. As they emerge, they are not simply a small clone of an
advanced economy that shows economic potential and is growing up rapidly. Each market
is a product of idiosyncratic historical, political, legal, economic and cultural forces within
MAP 1.1
The 25 countries classified as
emerging market economies
SOURCE: Based on Grant Thornton
International Ltd, ‘Emerging markets
opportunity index: high growth economies’,
International Business Report 2012, 2012.
China
India
Russia
Brazil
Mexico
Turkey
Indonesia
Poland
Malaysia
Thailand
Argentina
Chile
Hungary
South Africa
Peru
Emerging economies, BRIC
Vietnam
Nigeria
Romania
Colombia
Venezuela
Iran
Egypt
Philippines
Bangladesh
Taiwan
Emerging economies, non-BRIC
CHAPTER 1
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 31
GLOBALISATION
31
08/06/19 07:40 PM
the country. Operating conditions in each market will be different. Understanding these
conditions and learning how to work with them in the specific market is the key to taking
advantage of the growth opportunities that emerging markets offer in the 21st century.
Chapters 5, 6, 7 and 8 explain in more detail the different political, legal, economic, cultural
and ethical dimensions of markets that international business has to navigate and the
strategies that international business adopts to deal with these differences.
LO 1.4
THE GLOBALISATION DEBATE
Is the shift towards a more integrated and interdependent global economy a good
thing? Many influential economists, politicians and business leaders seem to think so.40
They argue that falling barriers to international trade and investment are the twin
engines driving the global economy towards greater prosperity. They say that increased
international trade and cross-border investment will result in lower prices for goods and
services. They believe that globalisation stimulates economic growth, raises the incomes
of consumers, and helps to create jobs in all countries that participate in the global
trading system. The arguments of those who support globalisation are covered in detail in
Chapters 2, 3, 6 and 7. As we shall see, there are good theoretical reasons for believing that
declining barriers to international trade and investment do stimulate economic growth,
create jobs and raise income levels. Nevertheless, despite the existence of a compelling
body of theory and evidence, globalisation has its critics.41 Here, we look at the nature of
protests against globalisation and briefly review the main themes of the debate concerning
its merits. In later chapters, we elaborate on many of the points mentioned below.
Anti-globalisation protests
Street demonstrations against globalisation date back to December 1999, when more
than 40 000 protesters blocked the streets of the US city of Seattle in an attempt to
shut down a WTO meeting being held there. The protests were marred by a number of
violent events which captured the attention of the international media. The demonstrators
were protesting against a wide range of issues, including job losses in industries under
attack from foreign competitors, downward pressure on the wage rates of unskilled
workers, environmental degradation, and the cultural imperialism of the global media and
multinational enterprises. Local cultures and values were seen as being dominated by what
some protesters called the ‘culturally impoverished’ interests and values of the United
States. All of these ills, the demonstrators claimed, could be laid at the feet of globalisation.
The WTO was meeting to try to launch a new round of talks to cut barriers to crossborder trade and investment. As such, it was seen as a promoter of globalisation and a
legitimate target for the anti-globalisation protesters.
In subsequent years, in the Seattle tradition, most meetings of a global nature, be they
the meetings of the World Economic Forum, the G20 or a Climate Change Conference,
have attracted vehement anti-globalisation protests. There were many familiar protest
messages: the corporate corruption of political systems and the takeover of democracy;
the manipulation of globalisation for the benefit of corporations; the destruction of the
environment and the exhaustion of natural resources by global capitalism; and the pursuit
by governments of business-friendly policies post-GFC that have cut social services
and resulted in huge job losses. While violent protests may give the anti-globalisation
movement a bad name, it is clear from the scale of the demonstrations that support for
the cause goes beyond a core of anarchists. Larger segments of the population in many
countries now believe that globalisation does have detrimental effects on living standards
32
PART 1
GLOBALISATION
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 32
08/06/19 07:40 PM
and the environment. Indeed, the support for US President Donald Trump was primarily
based on his assertion that trade deals had exported US jobs overseas and created
unemployment and low wages in the country.
Both theory and evidence, however, suggest that many of these concerns may be
exaggerated, but politicians and business have not been able to communicate this message
clearly. There are significant gains that are real, although they may not be as easily
identified or dramatised by the media as a story on local job losses. Witness to the gains
are the opportunities that globalisation has afforded small firms such as Gekko, Comvita
and Imaging Partners Online, and the income and jobs that have been created for the IT
workers in India (see Emerging Markets: ‘India’s IT software sector’).
Globalisation, jobs and income inequality
Concerns over job losses, job insecurity, lower wages and growing income inequality
are frequently voiced by globalisation opponents. The critics argue that falling trade and
investment barriers allow companies to move manufacturing activities to countries where
wage rates are much lower.42 This offshoring causes job losses and depresses wages. Indeed,
due to the entry of China, India and the Eastern European states into the global trading
system (along with population growth), estimates suggest that the pool of global labour
may have quadrupled between 1985 and 2005, with most of the increase taking place
after 1990.43 Other things being equal, critics argue that this enormous expansion in the
global labour force, when coupled with expanding international trade, will depress wages
in developed nations, particularly the wage rates of lower-paid, less-skilled manufacturing
workers in developed countries. As noted above, over the last two decades, the same fears
have been expressed about service jobs. Technological advances now mean that many
services that were previously non-tradeable are now tradeable. More skilled, white-collar
jobs increasingly have been outsourced to nations with lower labour costs. Evidence seems
to support the critics. In most developed countries, the wages share of national income
(in contrast to the profits share) has declined since 1980 and income inequality within
developed nations has risen.44 What is hotly debated, however, is whether globalisation
and offshoring are the main causes of these phenomena.
Supporters of globalisation reply that critics miss the essential point about free trade—
that is, the benefits outweigh the costs.45 Supporters argue that free trade will result in
countries specialising in the production of those goods and services that they can produce
most efficiently, while importing goods and services that they cannot produce as efficiently.
When a country embraces free trade, there is always some dislocation at the sector level—
for example, lost jobs in clothing manufacturing or lost call-centre jobs at banks—but
the whole economy is better off as a result. According to this view, it makes little sense
for Australia to produce low-wage, low-skilled textiles and clothing at home when they
can be produced at a lower cost in China, Thailand or Indonesia. Importing textiles from
China leads to lower prices for clothes in Australia, which enables consumers to spend
more of their money on other items. At the same time, the increased income generated
in China from textile exports increases income levels and—as the industrial sector and the
middle class expand in that country—the Chinese are able to purchase more products from
Australia, such as iron ore, food staples, elaborately transformed manufactures, professional
services, educational services, tourism services and mining equipment.
The same argument can be made to support the outsourcing of services to low-wage
countries. By outsourcing customer service call centres and back-office jobs to India, China
or the Philippines, financial institutions can reduce their cost structure and, thereby, their
prices for financial services to their Australian customers. Australians can spend more
of their money on other goods and services. Moreover, for every event of offshoring in a
CHAPTER 1
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 33
GLOBALISATION
33
08/06/19 07:40 PM
developed country, there is a converse event of ‘onshoring’ in a developing country. The
increase in income levels in India, China and the Philippines allows the growing middle
class in these countries to purchase more Australian goods and services, which helps
to create jobs at home. In this manner, supporters of globalisation argue that free trade
benefits all countries that adhere to a free trade regime.
There is another mechanism by which globalisation affects jobs other than via this
income effect. While globalisation will put certain jobs at risk, it will create other jobs. In
developed regions such as Australia, North America and Western Europe, supporters claim
that most attention focuses on the jobs lost from offshoring and import competition but
ignores the jobs created through increased productivity and increased exports. A study in
the United States estimated that the number of jobs potentially at risk of being offshored
from that country to low-wage, labour-abundant countries was about 15–20 million (about
40 per cent of these were in the manufacturing sector), but predicted that these job losses
would be offset in aggregate terms by job gains from services exporting.46 The net effect
on jobs from offshoring, therefore, is the result of two opposing effects—the ‘relocation
effect’ and the ‘scale effect’.47 When jobs are offshored (e.g. the back-office jobs of banks),
jobs are lost. This is the relocation effect. When offshoring these jobs results in the business
being more productive and more efficient, enabling it to be more competitive and increase
sales and employment, this job creation is the scale effect. A study of 17 OECD countries
found that offshoring within the same industry has no overall effect on employment
because the new jobs created by increased sales (the scale effect) offset jobs due to the loss
of labour-intensive work, the relocation effect.48
Jobs to be offshored are relatively low-wage, low-skilled intensive jobs, whereas jobs
to be gained are in relatively high-wage, high-skilled intensive services in which the
developed countries have a comparative advantage—for example, finance, entertainment
and higher education. An example of these high-end services which developed countries
are onshoring or exporting is tertiary education. The OECD countries continue to attract
the lion’s share of foreign students by a considerable margin with the United States and
the United Kingdom dominating the market. Companies in OECD countries will also be
retaining the high-skilled tasks in their home base for strategic reasons. Companies are
unlikely to offshore the high-skilled jobs that underpin their ‘core competencies’ in areas
such as marketing, finance, R&D and design. International trade figures appear to support
the notion that there is both job loss and job creation in offshoring. The United States
and other developed economies are net exporters of services and in many cases these
net surpluses have been increasing rather than decreasing.49 In other words, developed
countries may offshore certain jobs, but they are also able to create and onshore other jobs.
There is a theory of trade that supports this way of thinking, embodied in the principle
of comparative advantage as compared to absolute advantage, which is discussed in more
detail in the next chapter.
As noted above, the critics of globalisation argue that globalisation causes wages in
developed countries to fall and the gap in incomes between the low-wage, low-skilled
worker and the high-wage, high-skilled worker to rise. The result is rising income
inequality. Rising income inequality will also occur in the developing countries. Supporters
of globalisation concede the point with respect to the evidence of growing income
inequality, but would debate whether globalisation is the culprit. Technological change
also plays a major role.50 There are two channels through which globalisation may widen
income inequality.
•
34
PART 1
When jobs are offshored from developed to developing countries, they tend to be
the low-skill-intensive jobs from the developed country’s point of view but high-skillintensive from the perspective of the developing country. Consequently, offshoring
GLOBALISATION
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 34
08/06/19 07:40 PM
•
increases the demand for the relatively high-skilled labour in both developed and
developing countries, thus increasing income inequality within both groups of
countries.
If low-income workers disproportionately work for low-productivity, low-profit
companies, and these companies suffer most from import competition, trade will
increase income inequality by reducing the employment opportunities and/or lowering
the relative wages of the low-income workers.51
Technological advances can also affect income inequality if they benefit higher-skilled
workers more than others. Technological advances have destroyed many low-skilled jobs
within economies through automation thus reducing the demand for low-skilled, lowincome workers. Technological advances have also made many medium and high-skilled
service jobs tradeable or ‘offshoreable’. (With current technologies at the moment, the tasks
of skilled medical specialists reading X-rays, for example, are offshoreable but not yet the
tasks of low-skilled gardeners and garbage collectors.) By the same token, as noted above,
developed countries may well have a comparative advantage in many medium and highskilled tradeable services that are ‘onshoreable’. The evidence suggests that the increasing
tradeability of services due to technological advances has not disproportionately impacted
the demand for skilled workers. Offshoring has in fact increased the wages of skilled
workers relative to those of unskilled workers. Technological advances, therefore, are more
likely to impact negatively the wages and employment opportunities of medium-skilled
workers (in services) and low-skilled, low-income workers (in manufacturing) than impact
high-skilled workers, thus increasing income inequality.52 In addition, globalisation and
technological change reinforce each other, further raising income inequality. Technology is
a driving force for globalisation, but globalisation increases the competition on companies
forcing them to introduce skill-based technological change.
So while the critics argue that the decline in unskilled wage rates, job losses and
growing inequality corresponds to the rise of globalisation, academics and the supporters
of globalisation see a more complex picture. One complication is the entanglement of
relocation and scale effects. Another is to disentangle globalisation effects from the effects
of technological change.
Supporters point out that many advanced economies report a shortage of highly skilled
workers and an excess supply of unskilled workers. Thus, growing income inequality
is a result of the wages for skilled workers being bid up by the labour market and the
wages for unskilled workers being discounted. They point to evidence that suggests that
technological change has had a bigger impact than globalisation on the declining share
of the national income enjoyed by wage and salary earners and the increase in wage
dispersion.53 Supporters would also contend that despite any rise in income inequality,
the standards of living of the unskilled worker would continue to rise. They would share
a larger economic pie due to the productivity-enhancing effects on economic growth of
free trade, skill transfers, more intense international competition and specialisation. Yet
another complication is the difficulty of attributing job loss to any one cause when there
always exists a large churn in jobs, as to be expected in any dynamic economy. A study
in the United Kingdom found that 51 000 jobs are destroyed and 53 000 jobs are created
in the private sector in one week, representing nearly 16 per cent of the private sector
workforce.54 It is also difficult to disentangle the impact of economic cycles of expansion
and recession on employment and unemployment, which in turn increase income
differentials and income inequality.
Estimating the actual or potential number of jobs to be lost and gained by globalisation
or offshoring and onshoring and whether or not forces other than globalisation are the
source of rising income inequality are difficult tasks. The reality is that jobs are being
CHAPTER 1
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 35
GLOBALISATION
35
08/06/19 07:40 PM
lost, wage growth has been restrained and income inequality has coincided with rising
globalisation. The challenge facing international business into the future is that this
coincidence may create the perception that globalisation is at fault and may be sufficient to
undermine the public support for globalisation. The public might agree that globalisation
has caused the national economy to grow and that there are benefits of globalisation
but when they see the pay of senior executives rising while their incomes are stagnant,
company profits rising while wages are stagnant and taxpayers being asked to bailout huge
corporations and financial institutions who are ‘too big to fail’, the public understandably
might conclude that the benefits of globalisation are not being evenly divided. Moreover,
as offshoring extends to high-tech goods and higher skill services, the sense of economic
vulnerability will spread across a wider range of skill and education groups—rather than
falling entirely on low-skilled workers, as had been the case until recently. A growing
number of people from all socioeconomic groups can more readily identify themselves
as losers and have sympathy with movements such as Occupy Wall Street. They begin
to question the merits of liberal free trade and foreign investment policies. When the
public perceives that their incomes are stagnant and the benefits are unevenly divided,
they become more protectionist.55 Rising protectionism is contrary to the interest of
international business.
Perceived increasing economic insecurity and the backlash of rising protectionism
suggest an urgent need for policies that both liberalise trade and investment to foster
globalisation while redistributing the benefits of globalisation (i.e. compensating the losers).
Proponents of different ideological stances will have different views of the extent to
which governments should intervene and redistribute income. In response to the growing
protectionist sentiment supporters of globalisation, including international business, argue
that the solution to the problem of declining income shares of low-income earners is to
be found not in limiting free trade and globalisation but in increasing society’s investment
in education and training to reduce the supply of unskilled workers.56 (We look at the
different ideological stances and their implications for international business in Chapter 6.)
Education policies that increase graduation rates in higher education and promote equal
access have been shown to help reduce income inequality.57 The cautionary tale with
education and training, however, is that it would be futile to target training to specific
jobs. It is difficult to predict which tasks are likely to be ‘offshoreable’ or ‘onshoreable’. The
education and training to assist workers who may be displaced by technological changes
and globalisation would be more effective if it were more general and aimed at lifetime
employment and a variety of industries.58 Others would argue for more interventionist
policies to reduce income dispersion—for example, more progressive taxes, broader social
welfare safety nets, minimum wage legislation and strengthening the role of trade unions.
Interventionist redistribution policies may be necessary to build the political consensus
that makes it feasible to liberalise international trade and investment and resist the call for
more protection. International business would most likely prefer to see the longstanding
debate about globalisation and jobs focus more on how best to compensate the losers of an
open trading system and globalisation.
Finally, there is the question of the pace of change. If the speed of the transition
to offshoring and onshoring is slow, the impact of the disruption to labour markets in
developed countries is likely to be less disruptive. The speed of transition will be governed
by factors in the onshoring countries. Do the economies of China and India have the
capacities to take on evermore sophisticated and complex tasks? These capacities are born of
a complex of quality economic and social institutions—including the material infrastructure,
education systems, property rights, intellectual property law, the rule of law, and governance.
There is also the question of whether or how quickly other developing and emerging
economies can replicate the achievements of China and India. It is also worth noting that
36
PART 1
GLOBALISATION
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 36
08/06/19 07:40 PM
the wage gap between developing and developed nations is closing as developing countries
experience rapid economic growth. We saw this in the case of India’s IT software industry
(see Emerging Markets: ‘India’s IT software sector’). One estimate suggests that wages in
China will approach Western economy levels in about 30 years.59 To the extent that this is
the case, rising wages in China and India could well erode their cost advantages and limit
the number of jobs that can be offshored. The migration of unskilled and medium-skilled
jobs to low-wage countries may well be a temporary phenomenon, representing a structural
adjustment on the way to a more tightly integrated global economy.
Globalisation, labour policies and the environment
A second source of concern is that free trade encourages companies from advanced nations
to move manufacturing facilities to less developed countries or source products from
countries that lack adequate regulations to protect labour and the environment from abuse
by unscrupulous businesses.60 Globalisation critics often argue that adhering to labour and
environmental regulations significantly increases the costs of manufacturing enterprises
and puts them at a competitive disadvantage in the global marketplace vis-à-vis companies
based in developing nations that do not have to comply with such regulations. Companies
deal with this cost disadvantage, the argument goes, by moving their production facilities
to nations that do not have such burdensome regulations or that fail to enforce the
regulations they have.
Multinationals are accused of putting downward pressure on wages, employment
conditions and environmental controls, fostering a regulatory ‘race to the bottom’. This
argument is used repeatedly by those who oppose any form of trade and investment
liberalisation, particularly by those who face the consequences of more intense international
competition. This was the situation in the case of the Ecuadorean rose industry. The
industry came under fire from environmentalists and human rights activists in the United
States and Europe. Growers were accused of misusing a toxic mixture of pesticides,
fungicides and fumigants to grow and export unblemished pest-free flowers, in the process
damaging the environment and endangering the health of workers. Those who have a
vested interest in restricting the flow of Ecuadorean exports, namely the established
growers in the Northern Hemisphere, are quick to lend voice to such criticisms. There also
continues to be a stream of reports of worker exploitation emanating from China that does
not help the cause of globalisation.
The Taiwanese company Foxconn, manufactures in China more than 40 per cent of
the world’s electronics for companies such as Apple, Dell, Amazon and others. In a recent
report, Foxconn was accused of violating Chinese law and industry codes of conduct on
numerous occasions, by having employees work more than 60 hours a week, and sometimes
for 11 or more days in a row. The report prompted protests and petitions over conditions
at overseas factories and several labour rights organisations called for greater scrutiny of
suppliers like Foxconn. Foxconn has also been accused of employing child labour.61 (The
issues in relation to ethics and corporate social responsibility are discussed in more detail
in Chapter 8.) On the other hand, where FDI creates a foreign affiliate, these affiliates pay
higher wages relative to domestic companies in both developed and developing countries.
The wage differential between domestic and foreign-owned companies ranges from about
10 to 70 per cent depending on the country. Jobs created by FDI are good jobs because
they are likely to pay higher wages and offer more training than local companies.62
Globalisation is also blamed for environmental degradation and global warming.63 Critics
argue that the expansion of world trade and multinational activity results in increased
carbon emissions as more goods are transported over greater distances all over the globe.
They argue that many of the goods in question can be produced much closer to the point
CHAPTER 1
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 37
GLOBALISATION
37
08/06/19 07:40 PM
of consumption. Another criticism of globalisation is that trade and globalisation have
contributed to enormous global economic growth, which with current technologies is very
carbon-intensive—global economic growth driven by the likes of China and India. A related
problem is the changing composition of economic growth. Globalisation has changed
consumption patterns throughout the world. The aspirational norms of consumption
have become more akin to the materialistic, ostentatious consumption patterns of the
Western world.64 Consequently, the impacts on environmental resources and systems of
the economic growth attained throughout the world are magnified. For example, while
global population doubled between 1950 and 2004, global wood use more than doubled,
global water use trebled, and the consumption of coal, oil and natural gas increased nearly
five times.65 It is estimated that car ownership in China will exceed 200 million in 2020,
causing serious energy security and environmental issues.66 The critics conclude that
globalisation is a force for rapid, carbon-fuelled development.
If the critics are correct, one might expect trade to lead to an increase in pollution
and result in companies from advanced nations exploiting the labour of less developed
nations.67 Supporters of free trade and greater globalisation express doubts about
this scenario. They argue that there is little evidence that globalisation fosters an
environmental ‘race to the bottom’. Any costs associated with meeting the standards
set by environmental regulations are not considered to be so burdensome as to sway a
decision on location choice. Access to markets and labour costs are more important to
location decisions. Supporters make the point that newly built foreign plants maintain
higher standards than domestic plants even when not required to do so. Companies find it
more efficient to have a single set of management practices, pollution control technologies
and training programs geared to a common set of standards, rather than seeking out any
cost advantage that might be obtained by scaling back on environmental standards in
any particular foreign facility.68 Furthermore, the relationship between pollution, labour
exploitation and production costs may not be that suggested by critics. In general, a
well-treated labour force is productive, and it is productivity rather than base-wage rates
that often has the greatest influence on costs. The vision of greedy managers who shift
production to low-wage countries to exploit their labour force or the local environment
may be misplaced.
Supporters of globalisation argue more generally that tougher environmental regulations
and stricter labour standards go hand in hand with economic progress.69 As countries
get richer, they enact tougher environmental and labour regulations.70 Because free trade
enables developing countries to increase their economic growth rates and become richer,
this should lead to tougher environmental and labour laws. In this view, the critics of
free trade have got it backwards—free trade does not lead to more pollution and labour
exploitation; it leads to less. By creating wealth and incentives for enterprises to produce
technological innovations, the free market system and free trade could make it easier for
the world to cope with pollution and population growth. Indeed, while pollution levels
(which includes the many forms of air, land and water pollution but excludes carbon
dioxide emissions) are rising in the world’s poorer countries, they have been falling in
developed nations.
A number of econometric studies have found consistent evidence of a hump-shaped
relationship between income levels and pollution levels (see Figure 1.4).71 As an economy
grows and income levels rise, initially pollution levels also rise. However, past some point,
rising income levels lead to demands for greater environmental protection, and pollution
levels then fall. A seminal study by Grossman and Krueger found that the turning point
generally occurred before per capita income levels reached US$8000.72
While the hump-shaped relationship depicted in Figure 1.4 seems to hold across a wide
range of pollutants—from sulphur dioxide to lead concentrations and water quality—carbon
38
PART 1
GLOBALISATION
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 38
08/06/19 07:40 PM
Carbon dioxide emissions
Pollution levels
dioxide emissions are an important exception, rising
steadily with higher income levels. Given that increased
atmospheric carbon dioxide concentrations are implicated
in global warming, action to reduce carbon emissions is
required. The solution to the problem, however, is probably
not to roll back the trade liberalisation efforts that have
fostered economic growth and globalisation, but to get
the nations of the world to agree to tougher standards
on limiting carbon emissions as agreed to under the Paris
Agreement in 2015. The limitation of this agreement is
that limits on carbon are nationally determined. As seen
in Australia, reaching agreement can be very challenging,
especially in an environment where the United States has
decided to walk away from the agreement.
Essentially, national governments are not prepared to
commit to mandated emission targets on three grounds.
Other pollutants
US$8000
Income per capita
FIGURE 1.4
Income levels and environmental
pollution
•
They claim pursuit of such targets will undermine the international competitiveness of
domestic industry and unreasonably retard national economic growth—that is, they need
a level ‘carbon playing field’.
•
They are concerned about ‘carbon leakage’—that is, carbon emissions will simply shift
from the parts of the planet that will undertake carbon reduction to other parts that
will not.73
•
They are concerned that to be subjected to the monitoring of their progress towards
attaining such targets by an external body would impinge on their national sovereignty.
Environmental issues are inherently global. Life-sustaining ecosystems and air pollution
cross national boundaries. Climate change will eventually affect everyone but impacts
such as rising sea levels and the degradation of agricultural land are likely to impact first
and hardest on the poor.74 Climate change, therefore, is likely to increase the incidence of
global poverty. It will cause population displacement and an increase in the domestic and
international migration of economic refugees, and result in conflict over access to natural
resources—all of which will pose new threats to the security of an already insecure world.
These outcomes are not conducive to international business. The resulting political and
economic instability raises the risks of doing business internationally.
The lack of an international agreement on climate change may spell difficulties for
international business in a second way. Without internationally agreed commitments,
countries that do decide to act unilaterally to achieve environmental objectives will most
likely resort to trade restrictions. Recourse to trade restrictions is typically sought on
two grounds: (1) as a means of attaining a ‘level carbon playing field’; and (2) as a means
of countering ‘carbon leakage’—that is, using the threat of trade sanctions as a means of
forcing other countries to fall into line on carbon reduction. A type of ‘green’ tariff or
countervailing duty, as will be discussed in Chapter 3, would likely be the instrument of
choice. Unilateral action tends to provoke retaliatory trade restrictions and a spiral into
a trade or investment war. Rapidly developing countries such as China and India that
are emerging as the major polluters see themselves as the target of such trade sanctions.
In their minds, however, it is the Western industrialised countries that are primarily
responsible for the climate change problem. The threat of ‘green’ trade restrictions,
therefore, is not conducive to international cooperation. In today’s global economy, no
meaningful global regulatory regime to do with climate change, trade or finance can exist
without the cooperation of China and India. International business would prefer to see
CHAPTER 1
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 39
GLOBALISATION
39
08/06/19 07:40 PM
© Overflightstock Ltd/Alamy Stock Photo
multilateral negotiation and cooperation on the governance of environmental issues, as
this is less likely to provoke rising trade and investment protectionism. The WTO with
its system of trade rules and sanctions may need to play a greater role in building global
cooperation on the control of carbon emissions. (The role of the WTO is discussed in more
detail in Chapter 3.)
Sea-level rise due to global warming will make many small Pacific Island nations
uninhabitable.
Notwithstanding the difficulty of getting nations to agree on tougher standards to
cut carbon emissions, supporters of free trade and globalisation argue that the solution to
the problem is not to roll back the trade liberalisation that has fostered global economic
growth and globalisation. They contend that free trade can benefit the environment in the
following ways, contrary to the views of the critics:75
40
PART 1
•
a more open trading system increases global access to products and services that can
help improve energy efficiency, natural resource conservation, and the quality of air and
other environmental systems
•
freer trade will lower the cost of environmentally friendly goods, services and advanced
technologies as a result of the efficiency gains accruing from comparative advantage
and specialisation. This will be important for countries that do not have the domestic
industries to produce such products
•
additional exports opportunities will give businesses the incentives to develop new
products to mitigate environmental problems
•
the increase in income that flows from trade and investment results in society
demanding better environmental quality (as depicted in Figure 1.4)
•
trade’s role in generating greenhouse gas emissions through its link with transport may
be exaggerated. Ninety per cent of world merchandise trade is transported by ship.
Marine transport generates only about 9 per cent of the emissions of the transport
sector. Road transport contributes nearly 74 per cent. International trade’s contribution
to transport emissions is minor.
GLOBALISATION
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 40
08/06/19 07:40 PM
Globalisation and national sovereignty
Another concern voiced by critics of globalisation is that today’s increasingly
interdependent global economy shifts economic power away from national governments
and towards supranational organisations such as the World Trade Organization, the
European Union and the United Nations. As perceived by critics, unelected bureaucrats
now impose policies on the democratically elected governments of nation-states, thereby
undermining the sovereignty of those states and limiting their ability to control their own
destiny.76 As noted above, sovereignty concerns have been a stumbling block to achieving
international agreement on how to manage climate change.
The World Trade Organization is a favourite target of those who attack the headlong
rush towards a global economy. As noted earlier, the WTO was founded in 1994 to police
the world trading system established by the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade. The
WTO arbitrates trade disputes between the 157 states that are signatories to GATT. The
arbitration panel can issue a ruling instructing a member state to change trade policies
that violate GATT regulations. If the violator refuses to comply with the ruling, the WTO
allows other states to impose appropriate trade sanctions on the transgressor. As a result,
according to one prominent critic, US environmentalist, consumer rights advocate and
former presidential candidate Ralph Nader:
Under the new system, many decisions that affect billions of people are no longer made
by local or national governments but instead, if challenged by any WTO member nation,
would be deferred to a group of unelected bureaucrats sitting behind closed doors in
Geneva (which is where the headquarters of the WTO are located). The bureaucrats can
decide whether or not people in California can prevent the destruction of the last virgin
forests or determine if carcinogenic pesticides can be banned from their foods; or whether
European countries have the right to ban dangerous biotech hormones in meat . . . At
risk is the very basis of democracy and accountable decision making.77
This lack of democratic accountability and control of borders (loss of national
sovereignty) was instrumental in the Brexit vote, whereby the United Kingdom chose to
withdraw from the European Union. One UK national newspaper, the Daily Express, took
up the cause as follows:
After far too many years as the victims of Brussels’ larceny, bullying, over-regulation
and all-round interference, the time has come for the British people to win back their
country and restore legitimacy and accountability to their political process.78
In contrast to these views, many economists and politicians maintain that the power of
supranational organisations such as the WTO is limited to what nation-states collectively
agree to grant them. They argue that bodies such as the UN and the WTO exist to serve
the collective interests of member states, not to subvert those interests. Supporters of
supranational organisations point out that the power of these bodies rests largely on their
ability to persuade member states to follow a certain action. If these bodies fail to serve
the collective interests of member states, those states will withdraw their support and the
supranational organisation will quickly collapse. In this view, real power still resides with
individual nation-states, not supranational organisations.
There are two other concerns in relation to the increasing liberalisation of foreign trade
and investment, the rise of globalisation and the possible erosion of national sovereignty.
They are the issues of the relatively small but growing role of SWFs in FDI; and the
economic size and power of multinational corporations relative to the size of national
CHAPTER 1
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 41
GLOBALISATION
41
08/06/19 07:40 PM
economies, particularly developing economies. Both of these issues are addressed elsewhere
in this book. The concerns over SWFs and responses were raised earlier in this chapter,
and they are also discussed in Chapter 3. The power of multinationals is discussed in
Chapter 6 in the context of shifting ideologies and the control of FDI. The reality is that no
government permits the free flow of trade and investment. They tend to take a pragmatic
stance of attempting to maximise the benefits and minimise the costs of these flows
in order to advance what they consider is the ‘national interest’. Concerns such as these
frequently arise in Australia when iconic enterprises are taken over by foreign investors,
for example, the foreign takeover of Cubbie Station, Australia’s largest cotton grower. The
national sovereignty debate can become emotional, spurred by considerable economic
xenophobia. Supporters of globalisation would concur with the view opined by one
commentator on the Cubbie Station affair, ‘[A]s long as foreign investors obey Australian
law, there’s no reason their dollars will pose a problem. Foreign money is as good as local
money’.79 Where democratic institutions and the rule of law preside, real power resides
with the state and its eminent domain powers.
Globalisation and the world’s poor
Critics of globalisation argue that despite the supposed benefits associated with free trade
and investment, over the past 100 years or so the gap between the rich and poor nations
of the world has widened. In 1870, the average income per capita in the world’s 17 richest
nations was 2.4 times that of all other countries. In 1990, the same group was 4.5 times
as rich as the rest. In 2019, the 34 member states of the Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), which includes most of the world’s rich economies, had
an average gross national income (GNI) of more than $40 000 per capita, whereas the world’s
40 least developed countries had a GNI of under $1000 per capita—implying that income per
capita in the world’s 34 richest nations was 40 times that in the world’s 40 poorest.80
While recent history has shown that some of the world’s poorer nations are capable of
rapid periods of economic growth—witness the transformation that has occurred in some
South-East Asian nations such as South Korea, Thailand and Malaysia—there appear to be
strong forces for stagnation among the world’s poorest nations. A quarter of the countries
with a GDP per capita of less than $1000 in 1960 had growth rates of less than zero, and a
third had growth rates of less than 0.05 per cent.81 Critics argue that if globalisation is such
a positive development, this divergence between rich and poor should not have occurred.
Although the reasons for economic stagnation vary, several factors stand out, none of
which has anything to do with free trade or globalisation.82 Many of the world’s poorest
countries have suffered from totalitarian governments, economic policies that destroyed wealth
rather than facilitated its creation, endemic corruption, scant protection for property rights
and prolonged civil war. A combination of such factors helps explain why countries such as
Afghanistan, Cuba, Haiti, Iraq, Libya, Nigeria, Sudan, Syria, North Korea and Zimbabwe have
failed to improve the economic lot of their citizens during recent decades. A complicating
factor is the rapidly expanding population in many of these countries. Without a major change
in government, population growth may exacerbate their problems. Promoters of free trade
argue that the best way for these countries to improve their lot is to lower their barriers to free
trade and investment and to implement economic policies based on free market economics.83
Many of the world’s poorer nations are being held back by large debt burdens. Of
particular concern are the 40 or so ‘highly indebted poorer countries’ (HIPCs), which are
home to some 700 million people. Among these countries, the average government debt
burden has been as high as 85 per cent of the value of the economy, as measured by
GDP, and the annual costs of serving government debt have consumed 15 per cent of the
42
PART 1
GLOBALISATION
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 42
08/06/19 07:40 PM
CHAPTER 1
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 43
GLOBALISATION
© John Wang/Getty Images
country’s export earnings.84 Servicing such a heavy debt load leaves the governments of
these countries with little left to invest in important public infrastructure projects such
as education, health care, roads and power. The result is that HIPCs are trapped in a cycle
of poverty and debt that inhibits economic development. Free trade alone, some argue, is
a necessary but not sufficient prerequisite to help these countries to bootstrap themselves
out of poverty. Instead, large-scale debt relief is needed for the world’s poorest nations to
give them the opportunity to restructure their economies and start the long climb towards
prosperity. Supporters of debt relief also argue that new democratic governments in poor
nations should not be forced to honour debts that were incurred and mismanaged long ago
by their corrupt and dictatorial predecessors.
In the late 1990s, a debt relief movement began to gain ground among the political
establishment in the world’s richer nations.85 Fuelled by high-profile endorsements from Irish
rock star Bono (who has been a tireless and increasingly effective advocate for debt relief), the
Dalai Lama and influential Harvard economist Jeffrey Sachs, the debt relief movement was
instrumental in persuading the United States to enact legislation in 2000 that provided
$435 million in debt relief for HIPCs. More importantly perhaps, the United States also backed
an IMF plan to sell some of its gold reserves and use the proceeds to help with debt relief.
The IMF and the World Bank have now picked up the banner and have embarked on a
systematic debt relief program. For such a program to have a lasting effect, however, debt
relief must be matched by wise investment in public projects that boost economic growth
(such as education) and by the adoption of economic policies that facilitate investment and
trade. Consistent with this, in June 2005 the finance ministers from several of the world’s
richest economies (including the United States) agreed to provide enough funds to the
World Bank and the IMF to allow them to cancel a further $55 billion in debt owed by
HIPCs. The goal was to enable HIPCs to redirect resources from debt payments to health
and education programs, and to alleviate poverty.
The richest nations of the world can also help by reducing barriers to the importation
of products from the world’s poorest nations, particularly tariffs on imports of agricultural
products and textiles. High-tariff barriers and other impediments to trade make it difficult
for poor countries to export more of their agricultural production. The WTO has estimated
that if the developed nations of the world eradicated subsidies to their agricultural producers
and removed tariff barriers to trade in agriculture, this would raise global economic welfare
by $128 billion, with $30 billion of that going to poor nations, many of which are highly
indebted. The faster growth associated with expanded trade
in agriculture could significantly reduce the number of
people living in poverty, according to the WTO.86
Despite the large gap between the rich and poor nations,
there is some evidence that progress is being made. In
2015, the United Nations adopted what were known as the
Sustainable Development Goals, 17 economic and human
development goals for the world. We address these goals in
Chapter 5. Overall, it is hard to escape the conclusion that
globalisation and lower barriers to cross-border trade and
investment are major factors in this remarkable prospect.
While internal conditions in developing countries play
a significant role, it does not excuse the developed nations
from contributing to the reduction in inequality. Critics
Many factors explain the plight of poor countries, ranging
of the free trade strategy for development—such as the
from domestic factors such as corrupt governments
Cambridge University economist Ha-Joon Chang—argue that
and economic mismanagement to external factors such
the free trade rules of the world economy are designed not
as the imbalance of economic power between rich and
poor nations.
to help poor nations develop but to lock in the advantages
43
08/06/19 07:40 PM
of the present industrial developed countries. In other words, some of the main reasons for
lack of economic development are not domestic or internal factors but factors external to
the economy, factors over which developing countries have little control.87
LO 1.5
INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS
Any firm that engages in
international trade or investment
44
PART 1
MANAGING IN THE GLOBAL MARKETPLACE:
WHAT’S THE DIFFERENCE?
Much of this book is concerned with the challenges of managing an international business.
An international business is any company that engages in international trade or investment.
A company does not have to become a multinational enterprise, investing directly in
operations in other countries, to engage in international business, although multinational
enterprises are international businesses. All a company has to do is export or import products
from other countries. As the world shifts towards a truly integrated global economy, more
companies, both large and small, are becoming international businesses. What does this shift
towards a global economy mean for managers within an international business?
As their organisations increasingly engage in cross-border trade and investment,
managers need to recognise that the task of managing an international business differs from
that of managing a purely domestic business in many ways. At the most fundamental level,
the differences arise from the simple fact that countries are different. Countries differ in
their cultures, political systems, economic systems, legal systems and levels of economic
development. Despite all the talk about the emerging global village, and despite the trend
towards globalisation of markets and production, as we shall see in this book, many of these
differences are profound and enduring.
Differences between countries require that an international business vary its practices
country by country. Marketing a product in Brazil may require a different approach from
marketing the product in Germany; managing Australian workers might require different skills
than managing Thai workers; maintaining close relations with a particular level of government
may be very important in Indonesia but less relevant in New Zealand; the business strategy
pursued in India might not work in South Korea; and so on. Managers in an international
business must not only be sensitive to these differences, but they must also adopt the
appropriate policies and strategies for coping with them. Much of this book is devoted to
explaining the sources of these differences and the methods for successfully coping with them.
A further way in which international business differs from domestic business is the
greater complexity of managing an international business. In addition to the problems
that arise from the differences between countries, a manager in an international business
is confronted with a range of other issues that the manager in a domestic business never
confronts. In global markets, the business will confront more intense competition from
rivals—often the benchmark firms in the business—and often that competition will not be
on a ‘level playing field’. To continue the sporting parlance, they will not have the home
advantage. The manager needs to be informed across a greater number of variables in order
to arrive at the best strategy to compete successfully. The managers of an international
business must decide where in the world to site production activities to minimise costs and
to maximise value added. They must decide whether it is ethical to adhere to the lower
labour and environmental standards found in many less developed nations. Then they must
decide how best to coordinate and control globally dispersed production activities (which,
as we shall see later in the book, is not a trivial problem). The managers in an international
business must also decide which foreign markets to enter and which to avoid. They must
choose the appropriate mode for entering a particular foreign country. Is it best to export its
product to the foreign country? Should the company allow a local company to produce its
product under licence in that country? Should the company enter into a joint venture with a
local firm to produce its product in that country? Or should the firm set up a wholly owned
subsidiary to serve the market in that country? As we shall see, the choice of entry mode is
GLOBALISATION
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 44
08/06/19 07:40 PM
•
countries are different—they have different political, legal, economic and cultural systems
•
the range of problems confronted by a manager in an international business is wider
•
the problems themselves are more complex and the knowledge demands much higher
•
the competition will be more intense
•
an international business must find ways to work within the limits imposed by
government intervention in the international trade and investment system
•
international transactions involve converting money into different currencies.
In this book, we examine all these issues in depth, paying close attention to the different
strategies and policies that managers pursue to deal with the various challenges created when
a company becomes an international business. Chapter 2 provides theoretical explanations
for companies going international. Chapter 3 examines why and how national governments
intervene in international trade and investment, and the role played by global and regional
agreements in promoting international trade and investment. Chapter 4 focuses on the nature of
the foreign exchange market and the international monetary system, and the risks of conducting
business across different currencies and with foreign parties. Chapters 5, 6 and 7 explore how
countries differ from each other with regard to their cultural, political, legal and economic
systems and institutions. Chapter 8 takes a detailed look at the ethical issues and issues of social
responsibility that arise in international business. Chapter 9 draws from the previous chapters
and describes analytical tools and resources that managers use to decide on the best location
for their business operations. Chapters 10 and 11 explore the strategies of international business
to enter and compete in foreign markets. Chapters 12, 13 and 14 look at the management of
various functional operations within an international business, including marketing, production
and human relations. By the time you complete this book, you should have a good grasp of
the issues that managers working within international business have to grapple with on a daily
basis, and you should be familiar with the range of strategies and operating policies available to
compete more effectively in today’s rapidly emerging global economy.
CHAPTER 1
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 45
GLOBALISATION
45
08/06/19 07:40 PM
© Paul Springett/Alamy Stock Photo
critical because it has major implications for the long-term
health of the company.
Conducting business transactions across national borders
requires understanding the rules governing the international
trade and monetary systems. Managers in an international
business must deal with government restrictions on
international trade and investment. They must find ways to
work within the limits imposed by specific governmental
interventions. As this book explains, even though many
governments are nominally committed to free trade, they
often intervene to regulate cross-border trade and investment.
Managers within international businesses must develop
strategies and policies for dealing with such interventions.
Cross-border transactions also require that money be
Despite the trend towards modernisation and the
globalisation of markets and production, many differences
converted from the company’s home currency into a foreign
between countries are profound and enduring.
currency, and vice versa. Because currency exchange rates
vary in response to changing economic conditions, managers
in an international business must develop policies for dealing
with exchange rate movements. A company that adopts a wrong policy can lose large
amounts of money, whereas one that adopts the right policy can increase the profitability of
its international transactions.
In sum, managing an international business is different from managing a purely
domestic business, for at least six reasons:
KEY TERMS
PAGE
18Asian Infrastructure
Investment Bank (AIIB)
17
BRIC
13
factors of production
19
foreign direct investment (FDI)
16General Agreement on Tariffs
and Trade (GATT)
10
globalisation
12
13
24
18
44
17
19
20
27
globalisation of markets
globalisation of production
Group of Eight (G8)
Group of Twenty (G20)
international business
International Monetary Fund (IMF)
international trade
Moore’s Law
multinational enterprise (MNE)
10
offshoring
10
outsourcing
25
sovereign wealth fund (SWF)
17
United Nations (UN)
18United Nations Conference on
Trade and Development (UNCTAD)
17
World Bank
16
World Trade Organization (WTO)
SUMMARY
This chapter sets the scene for the rest of the book. It shows how the world economy is becoming more global and it
reviews the main drivers of globalisation, arguing that they seem to be thrusting nation-states towards a more tightly
integrated global economy. We looked at how the nature of international business is changing in response to the
changing global economy; we discussed some concerns raised by rapid globalisation; and we reviewed implications of
rapid globalisation for individual managers.
The chapter made the following points:
1. Over the past three decades, we have witnessed the
globalisation of markets and production. There is greater
integration and interdependence of economies.
2. The globalisation of markets implies that national
markets are merging into one huge marketplace.
However, it is important not to push this view too far, as
significant differences in culture, politics and economies
exist between countries and the adaptation of products
and strategies to local conditions is often necessary for
international business to succeed.
3. The globalisation of production implies that companies
are basing individual productive activities at the optimal
world locations for the particular activities, often resulting
in the offshoring of activities that were once conducted
at home. As a consequence, it is increasingly irrelevant
to talk about ‘Australian products’, ‘Japanese products’
or ‘German products’, since these are being replaced by
‘global products’.
4. Two factors seem to underlie the trend towards
globalisation: (a) declining trade barriers; and (b)
changes in communication, information and transport
technologies. These factors have facilitated the trend
towards the globalisation of production and have
enabled companies to view the world as a single market.
5. As a consequence of the globalisation of production and
markets, world trade has grown faster than world output,
foreign direct investment has surged, imports have
penetrated more deeply into the world’s industrial nations,
and competitive pressures on industry have increased.
6. It is noted throughout the chapter that events such as
the GFC, the rise of sovereign wealth funds and climate
46
PART 1
change can provoke trade and investment protectionist
sentiment and have the potential to stall trade and
investment liberalisation and globalisation.
7. With the technological advances in transport and ICT, it
is no longer necessary to produce goods close to where
they are consumed resulting in a rapid increase in trade
and FDI. These technological advances have facilitated
an increasing level of offshoring both of manufactured
goods and services.
8. The technological advances, especially those embodied
in the internet, have helped companies to link their
worldwide operations into sophisticated information
networks. Companies are able to achieve tight
coordination of their worldwide operations and to view
the world as a single market.
9. The shape of the global economy has changed. Where
once the economies of the United States, Japan and
the European Union were dominant in global trade and
production and the drivers of global economic growth,
the poles of growth are now more dispersed among a
number of countries, including the emerging economies
such as the BRICs.
10. Evidence of a more multi-polar global economy is the
changing source and destination of trade and FDI, the
growth of non-US multinationals and the increasing
representation and political power of the emerging
economies in organisations as the IMF, AIIB and G20.
11. Among the most dramatic developments of the past 30
years have been the collapse of communism in Eastern
Europe and the rise of China as an economic power.
These developments have created enormous long-run
GLOBALISATION
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 46
08/06/19 07:40 PM
opportunities for international businesses. In addition,
the free market reforms in Eastern Europe, East and
South Asia, and Latin America have created opportunities
(and competitive threats) for the once dominant Western
international businesses.
12. The benefits and costs of globalisation are hotly
debated. The debates focus on the impact of
globalisation on jobs, wages and working conditions,
poverty, income inequality both within and across
nations, the environment and national sovereignty.
Some critics have called for de-globalisation while
supporters call for more openness and the liberalisation
of trade and investment.
13. Managing an international business is different from
managing a domestic business and is more challenging
due to a variety of reasons including country differences;
a wider range of more complex problems; the greater
intensity of competition; increased likelihood of intervention
by governments, home and host; and added complexity of
conducting transactions in different currencies.
CHAPTER 1
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 47
GLOBALISATION
47
08/06/19 07:40 PM
INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS
GRADUATE ATTRIBUTES (IBGAs):
LEARNING AND ASSESSMENT TASKS
IBGA1: DISCIPLINE KNOWLEDGE AND SKILLS
1. Describe the shifts in the world economy over the past
30 years. Compare the implications of these shifts for
international businesses based in a country of your choice.
2. ‘The study of international business is fine if you are
going to work in a large multinational enterprise, but it
has no relevance for individuals who are going to work in
small domestic firms.’ Evaluate this statement.
IBGA5: COMMUNICATION
3. As a group, develop a two-sentence maximum definition
of ‘globalisation’. As a starting point to your discussion,
consider the following notions. Does globalisation
simply mean internationalisation—that is, the increase
in cross-border trade, investment and migration? Does
it mean liberalisation—that is, the gradual removal
of government-imposed restrictions on cross-border
exchange? Or universalisation—that is, as ideas spread
around the world, people’s aspirations and experiences
become harmonised? Or Westernisation—that is, the
destruction of local identity and self-determination as
capitalism, consumerism and industrialism spread over
the world? Or de-territorialisation—that is, distance and
territorial borders grow less significant and the world
is conceived as a single place as exemplified in such
aspects as communications over the world wide web,
multinational organisations, global products, foreign
currency exchanges, climate change and religious
affiliations? These different concepts are drawn from J.
Scholte, ‘Defining globalisation’, World Economy, 31(11)
(November 2008). After the discussion and the task are
completed, reflect on the behaviours in the group that
facilitated the discussion and task completion.
4. Write a brief report, including suitable graphs and tables,
that examines the rise of China and India in the global
economy since 1970. Accessing data from organisations
such as the OECD and the World Bank, particularly World
Development Indicators, may prove a useful starting point.
IBGA7: GLOBAL PERSPECTIVE
5. Identify a number of civil society groups or associations
that are essentially global—for example, Oxfam. Many are
concerned with issues of global justice and sustainable
48
PART 1
development. Outline their missions and goals. Assess
the extent to which the issues they address and the
actions they take transcend borders. Discuss the risks,
if any, that these groups present to globalisation and
international business.
6. Successful international business managers are often
described as possessing a ‘global mindset’. Outline
what you think characterises an individual with a
global mindset.
IBGA9: CITIZENSHIP
7. The internet is reaching further into all parts of the world,
including developing countries. Outline how globalisation
and international business have been affected by this
increased connectivity, and speculate on the additional
challenges and responsibilities confronting international
business that are likely to arise from being an active
participant in the one ‘global village’.
8. Read ‘Who makes the Apple iPhone?’. What are the
potential ethical problems associated with outsourcing
assembly jobs to Foxconn in China? How might Apple
deal with these?
IBGA1: DISCIPLINE KNOWLEDGE AND SKILLS
IBGA2: CRITICAL ANALYSIS
9. CASE ANALYSIS Read again the Opening Case: ‘Kaihara:
Globalisation of a shinise, a long-lived company’ and then
answer the following questions.
a. From its inception Kaihara has focused on the high-end
market segment. Discuss the merits of this strategy.
b. Kaihara is a Japanese long-lived company. What
factors have contributed to its longevity?
c. Kaihara originally produced kasuri, a product
focused on the Japanese market. However, the
company has been able to achieve international
success. Discuss the strategies behind this
international success.
d. What were the reasons for the company establishing
a Thai subsidiary?
10. CASE ANALYSIS Read the following Closing Case and
answer the questions that follow.
GLOBALISATION
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 48
08/06/19 07:40 PM
CLOSING CASE
GLOBAL INNOVATION THROUGH THE
MOBILITY OF IDEAS AND TALENT
Zinemath cPlc is a born global technology startup. It has investors from Italy and talent acquired
from Australia and targets the US market. Its
revolutionary approach to developing virtual reality
(VR) and augmented reality (AR) technology for
use in cinematography, real-time broadcasting and
medical visualisation is opening up new business
opportunities and potentially revolutionising
operations across multiple industries from
broadcasting to health care and education.
Global innovation
Global movement of ideas is as old as global trade
itself, and the two are definitely related. A good
example of this is the technology transfer facilitated
by the Silk Road. In ancient times, Chinese silk was
transported to Egypt. During the Middle Ages, this
intercontinental trade route was responsible for the
transfer of technologies and ideas between Asia
and Europe. In the absence of long-haul flights, and
with limited tools of navigation and propulsion for
seafaring, the American side of the Pacific was not
accessible. (Although Maori reached all the way to the
islands of Aotearoa, and Chinese explorers may have
arrived at the shores of Australia much earlier, these
great efforts did not yield permanent trade routes.)
By means of this trade route, people travelled, learned
and transferred knowledge across different parts
of the world. An envoy of the Byzantine emperor,
Justinian, smuggled silk worm eggs out of China,
hidden in bamboo sticks, to start silk production in
the Middle East in the 6th century. Marco Polo, the
Italian merchant born in Venice, travelled to China
and brought back many things like noodles in the
13th/14th centuries. The Ottoman Empire acquired
the secrets of gunpowder around the 14th century,
and a Hungarian military engineer designed and built
the first cannon for the emperor of Byzantium in the
15th century, revolutionising warfare. This later
enabled the Ottoman Empire to conquer large parts
of Europe (including Hungary). Porcelain (originally
called ‘china’) production sprung up in Meissen,
Germany, in the 18th century after engineers were
able to re-create the production process and find
local resources. These are examples of how ideas
travel around the world by means of trade and the
movement of people. Nowadays, in the modern
global innovation system, international education,
collaboration, recruitment and entrepreneurship drive
the exchange and sharing of ideas and other resources
necessary to devise new technologies and products,
and access markets.
Systems of innovation are described by the
concept of the ripple helix, which identifies the
source of complex technological innovation as an
outcome of collaboration between universities
(research institutes), governments and industry
(businesses). These ‘interactions’ manifest by
transferring intangible and tangible resources, such
as knowledge, ideas, people, time on task and money.
For example, governments provide grant funding to
universities, on the condition of working together to
help them innovate. Businesses may directly contract
universities to conduct research for them, or help
them to collect ideas and recruit talent through
collaboration with students (class projects, internships,
events). And finally, governments provide funding
for the higher education sector and for research
institutes to provide research and development
services supporting public good, and to train the next
generation of experts and professionals to enable them
to contribute to the economic and social development
of the country.
CHAPTER 1
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 49
GLOBALISATION
49
08/06/19 07:40 PM
Global talent and mobility
In the 21st century, innovation has become a global
phenomenon, and with the global mobility of people,
the global mobility of ideas has also emerged. Dr
Ferenc Birloni, born in Hungary, completed a Masters
in electrical engineering in Budapest, studied as an
exchange student at UTS in Sydney and earned his
PhD in mathematical engineering and information
physics at the University of Tokyo. Ferenc moved
to Australia in 2008 to work as a consultant for a
rail, engineering and consultancy company, to grow
the business unit for ICT and electrical engineering
solutions. Throughout his career, beyond his technical
skills in electrical engineering and IT, Ferenc
developed his skills as a technology and business
development manager, and has become a serial
entrepreneur, participating in multiple start-ups.
Zinemath cPlc
In 2015, Ferenc was chief technology officer (CTO) of
Zinemath cPlc, an already existing technology startup located in Budapest. Zinemath was established as
a specialist provider of virtual production platforms
to the film, production and broadcast industries.
The company has developed zLense, a world-first
depth-mapping camera that captures 3D data and
scenery in real time and adds a depth layer to the
footage. The zLense technology processes spatial
information in real time, making new and real
3D compositing methods possible, enabling film
production teams to create stunning 3D effects and
use state-of-the-art computer-generated imagery (CGI)
in live television or pre-recorded formats. The zLense
technology enables live broadcast of unique simulated
and AR environments, generating and combining
dynamic VR and AR effects in live broadcast of
studio production.
The company was founded in 2012 by three Hungarian
film and media entrepreneurs: Norbert Komenczi,
a producer, and Botond Csizi and Gergo" Soós,
developers. The founders actively sought collaboration
opportunities with other businesses in the industry,
attracting funding from CenTech Hungarian
50
PART 1
Venture Capital Fund, as well as some minor capital
investments (Colabs Plc, Seed Co-Investment Ltd,
StreamNovation Ltd and Solid Ltd), and a major enabler
of capital injection by specialist investor, Docler
Holding. European venture capital investments are
growing (though only half the average size of those in
the United States) and Brussels is preparing legislation
that will further increase small to medium-sized
enterprise (SME) access to venture capital, cutting
red tape and fees and expanding assets in which
venture capital funds can invest to include even
smaller companies. In 2016, €2.5 billion was invested
in seed and early-stage investments across Europe, a
major increase since 2012 according to Invest Europe,
the association representing Europe’s private equity,
venture capital and infrastructure sectors and investors.
Zinemath grew quickly between 2012 and 2015,
doubling its research staff. After the arrival of Ferenc
in mid-2015, the product portfolio of zLense was
diversified into zStudio (3D AR visual plug-in for
integration with studio systems, providing real-time
AR composite), zTrack (a state-of-the-art cameratracking solution vital to create VR content rendering)
and zKey (a depth-based image segmentation
solution). Collaboration with SZTAKI (the Hungarian
Academy of Sciences Institute for Computer Science
and Control), Budapest University of Technology and
international partners was also developed.
Ferenc’s appointment brought clarity to the
company’s strategic direction. The diversification
and collaboration efforts of 2015–17 were aimed at
developing marketable products through prototyping
and linking with potential high-profile end users
to generate new revenue streams. This expectation
was driven by the new investor, Docler Holding,
and its owner György Gattyán. András Somkuti, the
chairman of Gattyán Group, had his eyes on the global
film and television industries, with a total annual
market of €1600 billion, and actively encouraged
Zinemath’s participation in international events and
trade shows, in Europe and beyond.
The additional research capacity and efforts to find
new collaborations led management to venture
GLOBALISATION
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 50
08/06/19 07:40 PM
into the health and medical industries. This was a
milestone, and enabled Zinemath to win one of the
largest technology development grants provided
by the EU, with a total value of HUF1799 million
(approximately €6 million), in July 2017. The
project was granted EU funding (in the Hungarian
Economic Development and Innovation Operational
Programme) from the Structural and Cohesion
Funds (European Regional Development Funding
and European Social Fund) in order to contribute
to support the Research, Technology Development
and Innovation (RTDI) projects of Hungarian SMEs.
The grant is funding the development of the zMed
product line, aiming to use AR technologies in
medical imaging and rehabilitation, and improving
doctor–patient relationships and medical practitioner
education, in collaboration with the Medical School
of the University of Pécs and SZTAKI. As a result,
Zinemath’s research and development capacity has
significantly increased.
April 2018: Dr Ferenc Birloni left company
September 2018: technology development operations
for the grant program in full swing
The role of international exhibitions and global
networking in the social media age
Trade shows and exhibitions have historically been an
opportunity for organisations to showcase their new
products and technologies, to meet representatives
from other organisations, and for the formal and
informal exchange of ideas and talent. Of course,
in the age of the internet, email, VoIP, chat and
social media, this may seem like an expensive and
redundant way of networking. And yet, trade shows
and exhibitions are as popular as ever, demonstrating
the importance of creating personal connections and
networks.
April 2017: received Best of Show innovation award at
National Association of Broadcasters (NAB), Las Vegas
The NAB show is an annual event, started in 2008 in
Las Vegas, bringing together businesses and people from
a wide range of related industries including broadcast
television, radio, production, post production, news
gathering, streaming, cable television, satellite television,
film restoration, data storage, data management, weather
forecasting, computer-generated imagery, connected
media and cybersecurity. Zinemath’s research
and development team received the Best of Show
innovation award for its ground-breaking development
of the zLense at the 2017 NAB show. The award gave
Ferenc an opportunity to showcase the progress his
team had made in terms of technology development,
producing a working prototype for the exhibition
and providing assurance to investors that their money
was being put to good use. This was a strong basis
for continuing the work, and facilitated investors’
commitment to apply for grant funding, which the
organisation received in the same year.
April 2017: showcased at the NAB exhibition in Las
Vegas
Technology development: initial stage and
opportunities created for new ideas
July 2017: received major EU-funded National
Development Plan grant with a total value of
HUF1799 million (€6 million) to develop collaborative
interdisciplinary research solutions with the health
and medical industries
Zinemath’s original scope was to develop VR and AR
applications for real-time live studio broadcasting. In
a commercial entertainment context, this enabled a
streamlining of requirements for shooting live media
broadcasts without excessive studio equipment.
Zinemath milestones/timeline
February 2012: founded by three Hungarian
entrepreneurs, with registered capital of
HUF5 million (€17 000)
2012–13: registered capital increased to HUF16 million
(€55 000), investors: CenTech Hungarian Venture
Capital Fund, Colabs Plc, Seed Co-Investment Ltd,
StreamNovation Ltd and Solid Ltd
February 2014: major capital investment provided
by Docler Holding, acquiring majority control of
Zinemath
June 2015: appointment of new CTO, Dr Ferenc Birloni
CHAPTER 1
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 51
GLOBALISATION
51
08/06/19 07:40 PM
The technology development grant funding
received in 2017 opened several new opportunities
for the technology development team in the
area of application of AR for medical technology.
Applications can be used in medical education, by
means of simulations, and further opportunities may
also emerge.
Dr Áron Perényi
Swinburne University of Technology
SOURCES: Docler Holding history, accessed via www.doclerholding.com/en/about/companies/43/; Docler Holding history, accessed via www.
doclerholding.hu/en/about/companies/41/; LinkedIn, www.linkedin.com/company/zinemath/; ‘Company overview of Zinemath Zrt’, accessed via www.
bloomberg.com/research/stocks/private/snapshot.asp?privcapid=228274724; ‘You can’t just take our business away’, Forbes, accessed via www.
doclerholding.com/static/press/Forbes-Hungary-2017-Gattyan-Gyorgy.pdf; YouTube, www.youtube.com/user/zinemath; H. Winbladh, ‘Time to think big
in European VC’, 11 September 2017, accessed via www.investeurope.eu/news-opinion/opinion/blog/2017/time-to-think-big-in-european-vc/; LinkedIn,
www.linkedin.com/in/ferenc-birloni-dr-b85b396/?originalSubdomain=au; ‘Access to finance’, accessed via https://europa.eu/youreurope/business/
funding-grants/access-to-finance/; Zinemath, http://zinemath.com/; zLense, http://zlense.com/; NABSHOW, http://www.nabshow.com/; S. Varga,
‘It’s going to sound as big as a color film back then’, accessed via http://hvg.hu/gazdasag/20140306_Ez_akkorat_fog_szolni_mint_annak_idejen;
‘Hungarian Zinemath Zrt. can simplify film production in the world’, Business online, 13 February 2017, accessed via http://businessonline.prim.hu/
cikk/123615/; http://nkfih.gov.hu/palyazatok/europai-unios-forrasbol/versenykepessegi-kivalosagi-egyuttmukodesek; ‘Docler has invested in Zinemath
Zrt’, Computer world, 10 February 2014, accessed via https://computerworld.hu/uzlet/a-zinemath-zrt-be-fektetett-a-docler-144539.html.
CLOSING CASE DISCUSSION QUESTIONS
a. Dr Ferenc Birloni, CTO of Zinemath, successfully drove the company’s diversification and technology
development efforts. It is now time to generate revenue. How would you recommend expanding into the global
market to the new management of Zinemath? How would you suggest they identify and realise the potential
revenue streams globally?
b. The owner and chairman of the largest investor in Zinemath have a portfolio of online content provider
businesses. How would you recommend linking the newly developed medical product line, zMed, with their
strategic investment portfolio in online content provision, globally? What opportunities do you think the
Asia–Pacific region holds for them?
c. Zinemath has grown substantially since its foundation in 2012, and with EU funding might have a shot at
conquering global markets. How would you recommend the founders seek further investment to build their
capabilities using their global networks?
d. How would you recommend the new CTO goes about technology development, with the opportunities
opening up in the Asia–Pacific region, in terms of talent, markets and collaboration opportunities?
52
PART 1
GLOBALISATION
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 52
08/06/19 07:40 PM
ENDNOTES
1. www.csl.com.au/businesses accessed on 8 September 2015.
2. For trade statistics, see the databases of the World Trade Organization at
www.wto.org, accessed on 2 April 2019.
3. M. Naim, ‘Globalization’, Foreign Policy, 171 (March/April 2009).
4. T. Friedman, The World Is Flat, New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux, 2005.
5. Ibid.
6. T. Levitt, ‘The globalization of markets’, Harvard Business Review,
May–June, 1983.
7. Interbrand, ‘Rankings, 2018’, accessed via www.interbrand.com/bestbrands/best-global-brands/2018/ranking on 24 May 2018.
8. A. Inkpen and K. Ramaswamy, ‘End of the multinational: the emerging
markets redraw the picture’, The Journal of Business Strategy, 28(5) (2007);
ZPMC, Company Information, accessed via www.zpmc.com/about.php on
15 January 2013.
9. See F.T. Knickerbocker, Oligopolistic Reaction and Multinational Enterprise,
Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1973; and R.E. Caves, ‘Japanese
investment in the US: Lessons for the economic analysis of foreign
investment’, The World Economy 16 (1993), pp. 279–300.
10. Australian Bureau of Statistics, Characteristics of Australian Exporters,
2013-14, Cat. No. 5368.0, accessed via www.abs.gov.au/ausstats/abs@.nsf/
PrimaryMainFeatures/5368.0.55.006 on 10 September 2015.
11. AusIndustry, ‘Success Stories—Gekko Systems’, Australian Government,
accessed via www.ausindustry.gov.au on 31 March 2007; ‘Gekko Footprint’,
Gekko Systems, News Releases, accessed via www.gekkos.com/pages.
php?page=2 on 15 January 2013.
12. US Department of Commerce, A Profile of U.S. Exporting and Importing
Companies, 2009–2010, 12 April 2012, accessed via www.census.gov/
foreign-trade/Press-Release/edb/2010/edbrel.pdf on 15 January 2013.
13. B. Benoit and R. Milne, ‘Germany’s best kept secret, how its exporters are
beating the world’, Financial Times, 19 May 2006, p. 11.
14. All Nippon Airlines, Press Release, 1 November 2012, accessed via www
.ana.co.jp/wws/us/e/local/about_ana/corp_info/pr2012/120619.html on 16
October 2012.
15. Imaging Partners Online, About Us, accessed via www.imagingpartners.
com.au/about on 15 January 2013.
16. R. Reich, The Work of Nations, New York: A. A. Knopf, 1991.
17. The World Bank, Projects and Operations, January 2012,
accessed via http://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/
EXTABOUTUS/0,,contentMDK:20103853~menuPK:8336850~pagePK:
51123644~piPK:329829~theSitePK:29708,00.html on 16 January 2013 and
www.worldbank.org/projects on 13 September 2015.
18. See ‘The UN in Brief’, www.un.org/Overview.
19. ‘Why China is creating a new “World Bank” for Asia’, accessed via www
.economist.com/blogs/economist-explains/2014/11/economist-explains-6
on 12 September 2015 and www.aiibank.org/html/aboutus/AIIB accessed
on 12 September 2015.
20. J. Frankel, ‘Globalization of the economy’, National Bureau of Economic
Research, Working Paper No. 7858, 2000.
21. J. Bhagwati, Protectionism, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1989.
22. F. Williams, ‘Trade round like this may never be seen again’, Financial Times,
15 April 1994, p. 8.
23. World Trade Organization, World Tariff Profiles, 2014, accessed via https://
www.wto.org/english/res_e/booksp_e/tariff_profiles17_e.pdf accessed on
02/04/2018.
24. Moore’s Law is named after Intel founder Gordon Moore.
25. www.internetworldstats.com/stats.htm accessed on 2 April 2019.
26. For a counterpoint, see ‘Geography and the Net: putting it in its place’, The
Economist, 11 August 2001, pp. 18–20.
27. World Bank, Connecting to Compete, Trade Logistics in the Global
Economy, 2012, accessed via http://siteresources.worldbank.org/TRADE/
Resources/239070-1336654966193/LPI_2012_final.pdf#page=11 on 18
January 2013.
28. ‘Dell in social media’, accessed via http://content.dell.com/au/en/corp/aboutdell-social-media on 18 January 2013.
29. ‘Al Jazeera, Times topics’, The New York Times, 8 February 2010.
30. N. McDonald, ‘Al Jazeera America, a test case for an open society’,
CBC News, 11 January 2013, accessed via www.cbc.ca/m/touch/news/
story/2013/01/10/f-rfa-macdonald-al-jazeera.html on 18 January 2013.
31. J. Sachs, ‘America has passed on the baton. Collective action needs to
succeed’, Financial Times, 30 September 2009; G. Rachman, ‘America is
losing the free world’, Financial Times, 5 January 2010.
32. P. Pielichata, ‘Norway’s sovereign wealth fund returns –6.1% in 2018’,
Pensions & Investments, 27 February 2019, accessed via www.pionline.
com/article/20190227/ONLINE/190229866/norways-sovereign-wealthfund-returns-61-in-2018.
33. UNCTAD World Investment Report 2009; World Investment Report 2008.
34. S. Chetty, ‘Explosive international growth and problems of success among
small- and medium-sized firms’, International Small Business Journal,
February 2003, pp. 5–28.
35. Comvita, Annual Reports 2006, 2008, 2012, 2015; New Zealand Trade and
Enterprise, ‘Comvita’, New Zealand Export Awards accessed via www.nzte.
govt.nz/section/14606/16255.aspx on 18 March 2007; Comvita Investor
Centre, accessed via www.comvita.co.nz/_assets/Investors/FinancialNews/31%20March%202015%20CVT%20Annual%20Report%206MB.pdf
on 16 September 2015.
36. N. Buckley and A. Ostrovsky, ‘Back to business—How Putin’s allies are
turning Russia into a corporate state’, Financial Times, 19 June 2006;
Freedom House, accessed via https://freedomhouse.org/report/freedomworld/freedom-world-2015#.VfjfkJMep_U on 16 September 2015.
37. For examples of this way of thinking, see ‘People first economics’,
New Internationalist, 19 November 2008; W. Bello, ‘The virtues of
deglobalization’, Foreign Policy in Focus, Institute of Policy Studies, 3
September 2009, accessed via www.fpif.org/articles on 20 February 2010;
‘Turning their backs on the world’, The Economist, 19 February 2009.
38. G. Thornton, Emerging Markets Opportunity Index, International Business
Report 2012, accessed via www.internationalbusinessreport.com/
Reports/2012 on 21 January 2013.
39. The Economist, ‘To have and have not. It may no longer be wise to group these
disparate countries together’, 21 April 2012, accessed via www.economist
.com/node/21552995?zid=295&ah=0bca374e65f2354d553956ea65f756e0
on 21 January 2013.
40. J. Stiglitz, Globalization and Its Discontents, New York: W.W. Norton, 2003;
J. Bhagwati, In Defense of Globalization, New York: Oxford University Press,
2004; and Friedman, The World Is Flat, op. cit.
41. Ravi Batra, The Myth of Free Trade, New York: Touchstone Books, 1993;
William Greider, One World, Ready or Not: The Manic Logic of Global
Capitalism, New York: Simon & Schuster, 1997; D. Radrik, Has Globalization
Gone Too Far?, Washington, DC: Institution for International Economics,
1997; J. Stiglitz, Making Globalization Work, New York: W.W. Norton, 2006;
N. Kleins, The Shock Doctrine: The Rise of Disaster Capitalism, New York:
Metropolitan Books, 2007; see also ‘Clean start—creating a fair economy’,
New Internationalist, 19 November 2008.
42. James Goldsmith, ‘The winners and the losers’, in J. Mander and E.
Goldsmith (eds.), The Case Against the Global Economy, San Francisco:
Sierra Club, 1996; and Lou Dobbs, Exporting America, New York: Time
Warner Books, 2004; see also the concerns expressed by interest groups
such as trade unions—for example, The Australian Workers Union (www
.awu.net.au) and NGOs such as Oxfam (www.oxfam.org).
43. For an excellent summary, see ‘The globalization of labor’, IMF World
Economic Outlook 2007 (April 2007), Ch. 5; and R. Freeman, ‘Labor Market
Imbalances’, Harvard University Working Paper, accessed via www.bos.frb
.org/economic/conf/conf51 on 14 June 2007.
44. D. Coe, ‘Globalisation and labour markets: policy issues arising from the
emergence of China and India’, OECD Social, Employment and Migration
Working Papers, No. 63, 12 November 2007; W. Milberg and D. Winkler,
‘Globalization, Offshoring and Economic Insecurity in Industrialized
Countries’, DESA Working Paper No. 87, ST/ESA/2009/DWP/87, November
2009, accessed via www.un.org/esa/desa/papers/2009/wp87_2009.pdf on
29 January 2013.
45. For example, see P. Krugman, Pop Internationalism, Cambridge, MA: MIT
Press, 1996; T. Harcourt, Beyond Our Shores: Essays on Australia and the
World Economy, Second Edition, Australian Trade Commission, Austrade:
Australian Government, 2005.
46. J. Bradford Jensen and Lori G. Kletzer, ‘Fear’ and Offshoring: The Scope
and Potential Impact of Imports and Exports of Services, No. PB08-1,
Washington, DC: Peterson Institute for International Economics, 2008.
47. Described in H. Görg, Globalization, offshoring and jobs, International
Labour Organization and World Trade Organization 2011, accessed via
www.wto.org/english/res_e/booksp_e/glob_soc_sus_e_chap1_e.pdf on
30 January 2013.
48. Ibid.
49. Quoted in D. Coe, ‘Globalisation and labour markets: policy issues arising
from the emergence of China and India’, 2007, op. cit.
CHAPTER 1
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 53
GLOBALISATION
53
08/06/19 07:40 PM
50. P. Gottschalk and T. Smeeding, ‘Cross-national comparisons of earnings
and income inequality’, Journal of Economic Literature, 35 (June 1997),
pp. 633–87; and S. Collins, Exports, Imports, and the American Worker,
Washington, DC: Brookings Institution, 1998.
51. OECD, ‘Reducing income inequality while boosting economic growth: Can it
be done?’ Economic Policy Reforms, 2012, Going for Growth, OECD, 2012,
Ch.5, accessed via www.oecd.org/dataoecd/44/26/49421421.pdf on 21
February 2012.
52. D. Coe, ‘Globalisation and labour markets: policy issues arising from the
emergence of China and India’, op. cit.
53. IMF, ‘The globalization of labor’, 2007, op. cit.; D. Coe, ‘Globalisation and
labour markets: policy issues arising from the emergence of China and
India’, 2007, op. cit.
54. Quoted in H. Görg, Globalization, offshoring and jobs, 2011, op. cit.
55. D. Coe, ‘Globalisation and labour markets: policy issues arising from
the emergence of China and India’, op. cit.; W. Milberg and D. Winkler,
‘Globalization, offshoring and economic insecurity in industrialized
countries’, 2009, op. cit.
56. See Krugman, Pop Internationalism, op. cit.; and D. Belman and T.M. Lee,
‘International trade and the performance of US labor markets’, in R.A.
Blecker (ed.), U.S. Trade Policy and Global Growth, New York: Economic
Policy Institute, 1996.
57. OECD, ‘Reducing income inequality while boosting economic growth: Can it
be done?’, op. cit.
58. A. Blinder, ‘Offshoring: big deal or business as usual?’ CEPS Working
Paper No.149, June 2007, accessed via www.princeton.edu/~ceps/
workingpapers/149blinder.pdf on 25 January 2013.
59. Freeman, ‘Labor Market Imbalances’, op. cit.
60. E. Goldsmith, ‘Global trade and the environment’, in J. Mander and E.
Goldsmith (eds.), The Case Against the Global Economy, San Francisco:
Sierra Club, 1996.
61. China Labor Watch, ‘Foxconn employs interns between 14 to 16’, 15
October 2012, accessed via www.chinalaborwatch.org/news/new-438.html
on 30 January 2013.
62. B. Javorcik, Does FDI Bring Good Jobs to Host Countries?, Background
Paper for the World Development Report 2013.
63. L. Leopold, ‘Globalization is fueling global warming’, AlterNet, 28 December
2007, accessed via www.alternet.org on 16 February 2010; A. Najam, D.
Runnalls and M. Halle, ‘Environment and globalization: five propositions’,
International Institute for Sustainable Development, Environment and
Governance Project, 2007.
64. Ibid., p. 21.
65. Ibid.
66. Bao Chang, ‘Automobile ownership to exceed 100m by year’s end:
CMIF’, China Daily, 23 July 2011, accessed via www.chinadaily.com.cn/
business/2011-07/23/content_12967089.htm on 30 January 2013.
67. C. Mooney and B. Dennis, ‘WHO: Global air pollution is worsening, and
poor countries are being hit the hardest’, The Washington Post, 12 May
2016, accessed via www.washingtonpost.com/news/energy-environment/
wp/2016/05/12/who-global-air-pollution-is-worsening-and-poor-countriesare-being-hit-the-hardest/?noredirect=on&utm_term=.83a2351d0335 on
3 July 2019. O. Omoju, ‘Environmental Pollution is Inevitable in Developing
Countries’, Breaking Energy, 23 September 2014, accessed via https://
breakingenergy.com/2014/09/23/environmental-pollution-is-inevitable-indeveloping-countries/ on 3 July 2019.
54
PART 1
68. F. Mann, ‘The environmental benefits of globalization’, Global Envision, July
2004, accessed via www.globalenvision.org on 18 February 2010.
69. B. Lomborg, The Skeptical Environmentalist, Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 2001.
70. H. Nordstrom and S. Vaughan, Trade and the Environment, World Trade
Organization Special Studies No. 4, Geneva: WTO, 1999.
71. For an exhaustive review of the empirical literature, see B.R. Copeland and
M. Scott Taylor, ‘Trade, growth and the environment’, Journal of Economic
Literature, March 2004, pp. 7–77.
72. G. Grossman and A. Krueger, ‘Economic growth and the environment’,
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110 (1995), pp. 353–78.
73. P. Lamy, ‘Lamy underscores the urgency of responding to the climate crisis’,
WTO News: Speeches, 2 November 2009, accessed via www.wto.org/
english/news on 17 February 2010.
74. See, for example, E. Gertz, ‘Pacific Island youth comes to Copenhagen,
seeking climate change justice’, Oxfam America, 7 December 2009; http://
blogs.oxfamamerica.org, accessed on 17 February 2010; and E. Gertz,
‘Indigenous peoples affected by climate change, climate talks’, Oxfam
America, 9 December 2009.
75. See World Trade Organization, ‘The impact of trade opening on climate
change’, Trade Topics, WTO, 2013, accessed via www.wto.org/english/
tratop_e/envir_e/climate_impact_e.htm on 31 January 2013.
76. R. Kuttner, ‘Managed trade and economic sovereignty’, in R. Blecker
(ed.), U.S. Trade Policy and Global Growth, New York: Economic Policy
Institute, 1996.
77. R. Nader and L. Wallach, ‘GATT, NAFTA, and the subversion of the
democratic process’, in R. Blecker (ed.), U.S. Trade Policy and Global
Growth, New York: Economic Policy Institute, 1996, pp. 93–4.
78. ‘Get Britain out of Europe’, Daily Express, 31 January 2013, accessed via
www.express.co.uk/web/europecrusade on 31 January 2013.
79. C. Berg, ‘Australia’s unfounded foreign investment fear’, The Drum, ABC,
accessed via www.abc.net.au/unleashed/4242062.html on 31 January 2013.
80. L. Pritchett, ‘Divergence, big time’, Journal of Economic Perspectives
11(3) (Summer 1997), pp. 3–18. The data are from the World Bank’s World
Development Indicators, 2015.
81. Ibid.
82. W. Easterly, ‘How did heavily indebted poor countries become heavily
indebted?’ World Development, October 2002, pp. 1677–96; J. Sachs, The
End of Poverty New York: Penguin Books, 2006.
83. D. Ben-David, H. Nordstrom and L. A. Winters, Trade, Income Disparity
and Poverty, World Trade Organization Special Studies No. 5, Geneva:
WTO, 1999.
84. W. Easterly, ‘Debt relief’, Foreign Policy, November–December 2001,
pp. 20–6.
85. J. Sachs, ‘Sachs on development: helping the world’s poorest’, The
Economist, 14 August 1999, pp. 17–20.
86. World Trade Organization, Annual Report 2003, Geneva: WTO, 2004.
87. See also M. Lind, ‘Do as we say, not as we did’, The Weekend Australian
Financial Review, 24–25 January 2004, p. 10, for a review of Chang’s
arguments; M. Hart-Landsberg, ‘Neoliberalism: Myths and reality’, Monthly
Review, 27(11) (1 April 2006); and Oxfam, ‘Signing away the future: how
trade and investment agreements between rich and poor countries
undermine development’, Briefing Paper 101, Oxfam, March 2007,
accessed via www.oxfam.org.uk/what_we_do/issues/trade/downloads/
bp101_ftas.pdf on 3 April 2007.
GLOBALISATION
hiL23674_ch01_001-054.indd 54
08/06/19 07:40 PM
2
© Songquan Deng/Shutterstock
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES:
TRADE, INVESTMENT AND
EXCHANGE
CHAPTER 2
THEORIES OF TRADE, INVESTMENT
AND INTERNATIONALISATION
CHAPTER 3
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE
AND INVESTMENT
CHAPTER 4
FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND THE
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 55
08/06/19 07:41 PM
© Miki Studio/Shutterstock
CHAPTER 2
THEORIES OF TRADE,
INVESTMENT AND
INTERNATIONALISATION
56
PART 2
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 56
08/06/19 07:41 PM
INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS GRADUATE
ATTRIBUTES (IBGAs)
This chapter’s content, learning resources and case studies provide you with the
opportunity to develop a number of International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs),
including the following:
IBGA1
IBGA2
IBGA3
IBGA4
IBGA5
IBGA6
Discipline Knowledge and Skills
Critical Analysis
Problem Solving
Ethical Decision Making
Communication
Social Interaction
LEARNING OBJECTIVES (LOs)
2.1
2.2
2.3
2.4
2.5
2.6
Understand why countries trade with each other—the
benefits of trade.
Understand the theories explaining trade between countries.
Understand why companies invest in other countries.
Understand explanations of the internationalisation of the company.
Understand the arguments for why governments might play a role
in promoting national competitive advantage in particular industries.
Examine implications that international trade, investment and
internationalisation hold for international business practice.
CHAPTER 2
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 57
THEORIES OF TRADE, INVESTMENT AND INTERNATIONALISATION
57
08/06/19 07:41 PM
OPENING CASE
BANGLADESH’S TEXTILE TRADE
© NurPhoto/Sony Ramany/Getty Images
Bangladesh has a comparative advantage in the production of
textiles: it is one of the world’s low-cost producers—and this
is allowing the country to grow its share of world markets.
Obviously, this benefits producers in Bangladesh, but it also
benefits consumers in developed nations who can use money
saved on garment purchases to buy other goods and services.
Garment workers working inside a factory in Gazipur,
Bangladesh, on 14 May 2017. Bangladesh is the secondlargest apparel exporter in the world after China.
Bangladesh, one of the world’s poorest countries, has long
depended heavily upon exports of textile products to
generate income, employment and economic growth. Most of
these exports are low-cost, finished garments sold to Western
mass-market retailers, such as Walmart in the United States,
and Rivers, Coles and Kmart in Australia. For decades,
Bangladesh was able to take advantage of a quota system
for textile exports that gave it, and other poor countries,
preferential access to rich markets such as the United States
and the European Union. However, on 1 January 2005 that
system was scrapped in favour of one that was based on free
trade principles. From that point on, exporters in Bangladesh
would have to compete for business against producers from
other nations such as China and Indonesia. Many analysts
predicted the quick collapse of Bangladesh’s textile industry.
They predicted a sharp jump in unemployment, a decline in
the country’s balance of payments accounts and a negative
impact upon economic growth.
The collapse didn’t happen. On the contrary, Bangladesh’s
exports of textiles continued to grow. For example,
Bangladesh’s exports of apparel amounted to US$8.9 billion
in 2006 but in December 2015, apparel exports amounted
to roughly $2.6 billion for that month alone. Apparently,
Bangladesh’s advantage is based on a number of factors.
First, labour costs are low, in part due to low hourly wage
rates, and in part due to textile manufacturers’ investments
in productivity-boosting technology during the previous
decade. Today, minimum wage rates in Bangladesh’s textile
industry are about US$95 a month, a 51 per cent increase,
mandated by government in September 2018, over the
prior minimum. This new pay rate seems dismally low by
Western standards (and some ethical issues have arisen
within the sector—see Chapter 8), but in a country where
the gross national income per capita is only $1470 a year, the
textile industry provided a source of employment for some
4.5 million people in 2018—more than 60 per cent of whom
are women with few alternative employment opportunities.
Another source of advantage for Bangladesh is that it
has a vibrant network of supporting industries that
supply inputs to its garment manufacturers. Some threequarters of all inputs are made locally. This saves garment
manufacturers transport and storage costs, import duties
and the long lead times that come with the imported
woven fabrics used to make shirts and trousers. In other
words, the local supporting industries help boost the
productivity of Bangladesh’s garment manufacturers, giving
them a cost advantage that goes beyond low wage rates.
A third advantage for Bangladesh is that it has benefited
from the trend by Western importers to diversify their
supply sources. Many importers in the West have grown
cautious about becoming too dependent upon China
for imports of specific goods, for fear that an economic
or other disruption would decimate their supply chains
unless they had an alternative source.
SOURCES: E. Matsangou, ‘Bangladesh textile industry sets export record’, World Finance, 26 January 2016; R. Paul, ‘Bangladesh raises wages for garment
workers’, Reuters, 14 September 2018; ‘Australian retailers Rivers, Coles, Target, Kmart linked to Bangladesh factory worker abuse’, ABC Four Corners,
24 June 2013; A. Akhar, ‘Employment trends in 2018 in Bangladesh textile and apparel industry’, Textile Today, 2 January 2019; ‘Knitting pretty’, The Economist,
18 July 2008, p. 54; World Bank data on Bangladesh accessed via http://data.worldbank.org/country/bangladesh on 19 February 2019.
58
PART 2
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 58
08/06/19 07:41 PM
INTRODUCTION
LO 2.1
The benefits of free trade and globalisation are well illustrated by the growth of the
garment industry in Bangladesh. Low barriers to trade have enabled Bangladesh, one of
the world’s poorest nations, to exploit its comparative advantage in the production of
garments and enabled growth of its exports, even during a global economic downturn.
Strong garment exports help support over 4.5 million jobs in Bangladesh, and may help the
country to sustain economic growth. Bangladesh’s garment exports also benefit consumers
in developed nations who can save on garment purchases and, consequently, have more
money available for other goods and services, thereby improving their living standards.
The losers in this process are higher-cost garment producers in more developed nations,
who have lost business to enterprises from Bangladesh, and the employees in these highercost enterprises.
Local workers (in this case, those in Bangladesh) do gain employment that they
otherwise would not have. But the process that generated offshoring in the first place,
namely global competition and international pressure for cost containment, will tend to
contain wage growth and potentially keep the local employment base insecure and with
low employment standards. After all, if Bangladesh becomes too expensive, in either wages
or production-cost terms (e.g. better occupational health and safety), the tendency will be
to seek out a new cheaper country to relocate production to. This process, when it occurs,
is often referred to as a ‘race to the bottom’.
In the world of international trade and investment, there are always winners and losers,
but as economists have long argued, the benefits to the winners generally outweigh
the costs borne by the losers. Economists argue that in the long run, free trade leads
to optimal resource allocation, which stimulates economic growth and raises living
standards—although there are, as noted above, distributional impacts in more immediate
periods as some sectors and individuals lose while others gain. The economic arguments
on the benefits and costs of free trade in goods and services are not solely abstract and
the results are there for all to see. The formation of the World Trade Organization (WTO)
(and its predecessor, the GATT, the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade) and regional
trade blocs have changed the international trade landscape in recent times. Free trade has
enabled the economic rise of the large emerging markets—Brazil, Russia, India and China—
and it is enabling continued growth and rising living standards across the globe. But it has
arguably also led to growing social and political conflict.
We open this chapter with a discussion on mercantilism. Mercantilism was advocated
in the 16th to 18th centuries by the Englishmen Gerard de Malynes and Thomas Mun, and
developed further by Josiah Child and Frenchman Jean-Baptiste Colbert. Mercantilist theory
holds that countries should encourage and promote exports while discouraging imports, as
the goal is to amass trade surpluses—accumulation of wealth as an end in itself. Although
mercantilism is an old and largely discredited doctrine, its echoes remain in modern
political debate and in the trade policies of many countries. We often hear pronouncements
on neo-mercantilism in our modern economies.
Mercantilism cannot work in our modern economies, particularly those with floating
exchange rates, which is most countries. When trade surpluses persist, as advocated by
mercantilists, the value of the currency in the exporting country will rise as a result
because countries importing from the surplus country will have to buy more of the
exporter’s currency to pay for those imports. With an increasing exchange rate (relative to
the importing country), exports from the exporting country will become more expensive
to the importing country. As exports become more expensive, the importing country will
demand fewer exports, and hence the exporting country will export less, ultimately having
its surplus eliminated.
CHAPTER 2
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 59
FREE TRADE
The absence of barriers to the
free flow of goods and services
between countries
MERCANTILISM
An economic philosophy advocating
that countries should simultaneously
encourage exports and dissuade
imports to accumulate surpluses
THEORIES OF TRADE, INVESTMENT AND INTERNATIONALISATION
59
08/06/19 07:41 PM
COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE
The theory that countries should
specialise in the production of goods
and services they can produce
relatively more efficiently
60
PART 2
Mercantilism treats trade as an exercise in wealth accumulation—at the extreme one
country would accumulate all wealth—and as a zero-sum game. However, trade is not a
zero-sum game, as Adam Smith maintained in his 1776 book, An Inquiry into the Nature
and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Smith argued that there are mutual gains from trade
when country differences (naturally occurring) render some countries more able to produce
particular products, and thus have an ‘absolute advantage’ in the production of a product
when it is more efficient than any other country in producing that good. A country with
an absolute advantage should specialise and trade with other countries for goods in which
they have an absolute advantage, and as such, trade is a positive-sum game in that both
countries gain and increase their standard of living.
It would seem that when one country might have an absolute advantage in producing
all goods, mutual gains from trade exhaust themselves. However, David Ricardo (1772–1823)
postulated that there are still gains to be had in a country specialising in the production
of goods for which it has a ‘comparative advantage’, even if it has an absolute advantage
in its ability to produce all goods more efficiently than some other country. Comparative
advantage is the ability of a country to produce a particular good or service at a lower
marginal and opportunity cost relative to another country. Ricardian comparative advantage
theory has become the major argument for free trade, with productivity differentials
between countries driving trade gains. Much later, Heckscher and Ohlin (1933) emphasised
the association between comparative advantage and factor endowments (i.e. inputs such
as labour and capital)—the more abundant the factor, the lower its cost. Hence, a country
will export those goods that make intensive use of its relatively abundant factors, and it
will import those goods that make intensive use of its relatively scarce factors (known as
Heckscher–Ohlin theory).
In the 1950s, the economist Wassily Leontief empirically tested the Heckscher–Ohlin
theory in a study of the goods imported and exported by the United States. The results
were surprising in that they didn’t support the Heckscher–Ohlin theory. This became
known as the Leontief paradox. Leontief (1953) demonstrated that US exports were less
capital-intensive than were its imports. Why is a capital-rich economy exporting products
that are less capital-intensive than are its imports? Various explanations have been
advanced, but one possible explanation is that US exports may be skilled labour-intensive
(including large shares of innovation and entrepreneurship), while its imports are physicalcapital-intensive (being more mass produced).
An early response to the failure of the Heckscher–Ohlin theory to explain the observed
pattern of international trade in the United States was the product life-cycle (PLC) theory
proposed by Raymond Vernon in the early 1960s. Then, during the 1980s, the economist
Paul Krugman of the Massachusetts Institute of Technology developed the new trade
theory. New trade theory stresses that, in some cases, countries specialise in the production
and export of particular products not because of underlying differences in factor
endowments, but because in certain industries the world market can support only a limited
number of companies. Michael Porter of the Harvard Business School carried this idea
further in his theory of national competitive advantage, which attempts to explain why
particular nations achieve international success in particular industries. In addition to factor
endowments, Porter points out the importance of country factors such as domestic demand
and vigorous domestic competition in explaining a nation’s dominance in the production
and export of particular products.
While international trade theories explain the patterns of trade between countries,
and why particular countries specialise in particular goods and services, they do not
explain why particular companies engage in business exchange in foreign markets. In
recent decades, a new stream of research has emerged to explain individual company
behaviours in foreign markets. In the later sections of this chapter, we will discuss foreign
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 60
08/06/19 07:41 PM
direct investment theories, company internationalisation models, and a particular cadre of
companies that have recently become prominent in international markets, the so-called
international new ventures and born globals.
MERCANTILISM
LO 2.2
We now take for granted the notion that there are ‘mutual gains from trade’ (to use
economics phraseology). In other words, if two parties each have something the other
wants, and they can negotiate the terms and price each finds satisfactory, then both
parties will be better off conducting such an exchange. However, the history of trade
theory shows that this idea was not always so obvious.
The first theory of international trade emerged in the era of the large European empires
of the 15th and 16th centuries. Referred to as mercantilism, its principal assertion was that
gold and silver were the portents of national wealth and were essential to commerce. At
that time, gold and silver were the currencies of trade between countries. The main tenet
of mercantilism was that it is in a country’s best interest to maintain a trade surplus—to
export more than it imports. By doing so, a country would accumulate gold and silver and,
consequently, increase its national wealth, prestige and power. As the English mercantilist
writer Thomas Mun put it in 1630: ‘The ordinary means therefore to increase our wealth
and treasure is by foreign trade, wherein we must ever observe this rule: to sell more
to strangers yearly than we consume of theirs in value’.1 Consistent with this belief, the
mercantilist doctrine advocated government intervention to achieve a trade surplus. They
recommended policies to maximise exports, through subsidies, and to minimise imports,
through tariffs and quotas.
Then, in 1752, the economist David Hume pointed out an inconsistency in mercantilist
doctrine. According to Hume, if England had a trade surplus with France (it exported
more than it imported), the resulting inflow of gold and silver would expand the domestic
money supply and generate inflation in England. In France, however, the outflow of gold
and silver would have the opposite effect: France’s money supply would contract and
its prices would fall. This change in relative prices between France and England would
encourage the French to buy fewer English goods (because they were becoming more
expensive) and the English to buy more French goods (because they were becoming
cheaper). The result would be a deterioration in the English balance of trade and an
improvement in France’s trade balance, until the English surplus was eliminated. The flaw
with mercantilism was that it viewed trade as a zero-sum game, one in which a gain by one
country results in a loss by the other. Adam Smith and David Ricardo showed the shortsightedness of this approach and demonstrated that trade is a positive-sum game as both
countries will benefit.
ABSOLUTE ADVANTAGE
POSITIVE-SUM GAME
A situation in which all countries can
benefit even if some benefit more
than others from trade
LO 2.2
In The Wealth of Nations, Adam Smith refuted the mercantilist assumption that trade is
a zero-sum game. Smith argued that countries differ in their ability to produce goods
efficiently. In Smith’s time, the English, by virtue of their superior manufacturing
processes, were the world’s most efficient textile manufacturers. Due to the combination
of favourable climate, good soils and accumulated expertise, the French had the world’s
most efficient wine industry. The English had an absolute advantage in the production
of textiles, while the French had an absolute advantage in the production of wine. Thus,
Smith postulated that a country has an absolute advantage in the production of a product
when it is more efficient than any other country in producing it.
CHAPTER 2
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 61
ZERO-SUM GAME
A situation in which an economic
gain by one country results in an
economic loss by another
ABSOLUTE ADVANTAGE
A country has an absolute advantage
in the production of a product when
it is more efficient than any other
country at producing it
THEORIES OF TRADE, INVESTMENT AND INTERNATIONALISATION
61
08/06/19 07:41 PM
According to Smith, countries should specialise in the production of goods for which
they have an absolute advantage and then trade these goods for goods produced by other
countries. At the time, England should specialise in textiles, while France should specialise
in wine. England could get all the wine it needed by selling its textiles to France, and
France could get all the textiles it needed by selling wine to England. Smith’s basic
argument, therefore, is that a country should not produce goods at home that it can buy at
a lower cost from other countries. By specialising in the production of goods in which each
has an absolute advantage, both countries gain by engaging in trade.
LO 2.2
COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE
Ricardo’s theory
PRODUCTION POSSIBILITY
FRONTIER (PPF)
The boundary between those
combinations of goods and services
that can be produced and those
that cannot
David Ricardo developed Smith’s absolute comparative advantage theory further by asking
what would happen when one country has an absolute advantage in the production of
all goods.2 According to Ricardo’s theory of comparative advantage, a country should
specialise in the production of those goods that it produces relatively most efficiently and
buy the goods that it produces relatively less efficiently from other countries, even if this
means buying goods from other countries that it could produce more efficiently itself.3
This may seem counterintuitive, so let’s take a traditional illustration.
Assume that Ghana is more efficient than South Korea in producing both cocoa and
rice; that is, Ghana has an absolute advantage over South Korea in the production of both
products. Each country has a resources base of 200 units. In Ghana it takes 10 units of
resource to produce 1 tonne of cocoa and 13⅓ units to produce 1 tonne of rice. Thus,
given its 200 units of resources, Ghana can produce 20 tonnes of cocoa and no rice, 15
tonnes of rice and no cocoa, or any combination in between on its production possibility
frontier (PPF) (the line GG′ in Figure 2.1). (The production possibility frontier is the
boundary between those combinations of goods and services that can be produced and
those that cannot.) In South Korea, it takes 40 units of resources to produce 1 tonne of
cocoa and 20 units of resources to produce 1 tonne of rice. Thus, South Korea can produce
5 tonnes of cocoa and no rice, 10 tonnes of rice and no cocoa, or any combination on its
PPF (the line KK′ in Figure 2.1). Assume that without trade, each country uses half of
FIGURE 2.1
Theory of comparative advantage
20
G
C
Cocoa
15
A
10
5
K
B
2.5
0
3.75
5
7.5
K'
G'
10
15
20
Rice
PART 2
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 62
08/06/19 07:41 PM
its resources to produce rice and half to produce cocoa. Thus, without trade, Ghana will
produce 10 tonnes of cocoa and 7.5 tonnes of rice (point A in Figure 2.1), while South Korea
will produce 2.5 tonnes of cocoa and 5 tonnes of rice (point B in Figure 2.1).
In the light of Ghana’s absolute advantage in the production of both goods, why should
it trade with South Korea? Although Ghana has an absolute advantage in the production of
both cocoa and rice, it has a comparative advantage only in the production of cocoa: Ghana
can produce four times as much cocoa as South Korea, but only 1.5 times as much rice.
Ghana is comparatively more efficient at producing cocoa than it is at producing rice.
Without trade, the combined production of cocoa will be 12.5 tonnes (10 tonnes
in Ghana and 2.5 tonnes in South Korea) and the combined production of rice will also
be 12.5 tonnes (7.5 tonnes in Ghana and 5 tonnes in South Korea). Without trade, each
country must consume what it produces. By engaging in trade, the two countries can
increase their combined production of rice and cocoa, and consumers in both nations can
consume more of both goods.
The gains from trade
Imagine that Ghana exploits its comparative advantage in the production of cocoa to
increase its output from 10 tonnes to 15 tonnes. This uses up 150 units of resources, leaving
the remaining 50 units of resources to be used in producing 3.75 tonnes of rice (point C
in Figure 2.1). Meanwhile, South Korea specialises in the production of rice, producing
10 tonnes. The combined output of both cocoa and rice has now increased. Before
specialisation, the combined output was 12.5 tonnes of cocoa and 12.5 tonnes of rice. Now
it is 15 tonnes of cocoa and 13.75 tonnes of rice (3.75 tonnes in Ghana and 10 tonnes in
South Korea). The source of the increase in production is summarised in Table 2.1.
Not only is output higher, but both countries also can benefit from trade. If Ghana and
South Korea exchange cocoa and rice on a one-to-one basis, with both countries choosing
RESOURCES REQUIRED TO PRODUCE
1 TONNE OF COCOA AND RICE
Cocoa
Ghana
10.0
South Korea
40.0
PRODUCTION AND CONSUMPTION WITHOUT TRADE
Cocoa
Ghana
10.0
South Korea
2.5
Total production
12.5
PRODUCTION WITH SPECIALISATION
Cocoa
Ghana
15.0
South Korea
0.0
Total production
15.0
CONSUMPTION AFTER GHANA TRADES 4 TONNES
OF COCOA FOR 4 TONNES OF SOUTH KOREAN RICE
Cocoa
Ghana
11.0
South Korea
4.0
INCREASE IN CONSUMPTION AS A RESULT
OF SPECIALISATION AND TRADE
Cocoa
Ghana
1.0
South Korea
1.5
CHAPTER 2
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 63
Rice
13.33
20.00
LO 2.1
TABLE 2.1
Comparative advantage and the
gains from trade
Rice
7.50
5.00
12.50
Rice
3.75
10.00
13.75
Rice
7.75
6.00
Rice
0.25
1.00
THEORIES OF TRADE, INVESTMENT AND INTERNATIONALISATION
63
08/06/19 07:41 PM
to exchange 4 tonnes of their export for 4 tonnes of the import, both countries are able to
consume more cocoa and rice than they could before specialisation and trade (see Table 2.1).
Thus, if Ghana exchanges 4 tonnes of cocoa with South Korea for 4 tonnes of rice, it is still
left with 11 tonnes of cocoa, which is 1 tonne more than it had before trade. The 4 tonnes
of rice it gets from South Korea in exchange for its 4 tonnes of cocoa, when added to
the 3.75 tonnes it now produces domestically, leaves it with a total of 7.75 tonnes of rice,
which is 0.25 of a tonne more than it had before specialisation. Similarly, after exchanging
4 tonnes of rice with Ghana, South Korea still ends up with 6 tonnes of rice, which is more
than it had before specialisation. In addition, the 4 tonnes of cocoa it receives in exchange
is 1.5 tonnes more than it produced before trade. Thus, consumption of cocoa and rice can
increase in both countries as a result of specialisation and trade.
Importantly, the message from comparative advantage theory is that potential total world
production is greater with unrestricted free trade than it is with restricting trade. Ricardo’s
comparative advantage theory predicts that consumers in all nations can consume more
if there are no restrictions on trade. This occurs even in countries that lack an absolute
advantage in the production of any good. In other words, to an even greater degree than the
theory of absolute advantage, the theory of comparative advantage suggests that trade is a
positive-sum game in which all countries that participate ultimately realise economic gains.
As such, this theory provides a powerful argument for encouraging free trade.
Qualifications and assumptions
The conclusion that free trade is universally beneficial is a rather bold one to draw from
such a simple model. Our simple model includes many assumptions:
1. A simple world in which there are only two countries and two goods. In the real world,
there are many countries and many goods.
2. No transport costs between countries. This is clearly an over-simplification.
3. No differences in the prices of resources in different countries. Exchange rates are
assumed away—cocoa and rice are bartered on a one-to-one basis.
4. Resources can move freely from the production of one good to another within a
country. This is not always the case.
5. Constant returns to scale. That is, specialisation by one country has no effect on the
amount of resources required to produce one tonne of cocoa or rice. In reality, both
diminishing and increasing returns to specialisation exist. The amount of resources
required to produce a good might decrease or increase as a nation specialises in
production of that good.
6. Each country has a fixed stock of resources and that free trade does not change
the efficiency with which a country uses its resources. This assumption makes no
allowances for the dynamic changes in a country’s stock of resources and in the
efficiency with which the country uses its resources that might result from free trade.
7. Trade has no effect on income distribution within a country.
Given these assumptions, can the conclusion that free trade is mutually beneficial be
extended to a world of many countries, many goods, positive transportation costs, volatile
exchange rates, immobile domestic resources, non-constant returns to specialisation and
dynamic changes? It has been shown that the basic result derived from our simple model can
be generalised to a world composed of many countries producing many different goods.4,5
However, once all the assumptions are relaxed, the case for unrestricted free trade has
been argued by some economists associated with the new trade theory to be less than
optimal.6 We return to this issue later in this chapter when we discuss new trade theory.
64
PART 2
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 64
08/06/19 07:41 PM
Also, the Nobel Prize-winning economist Paul Samuelson argued (contrary to the standard
interpretation) that in certain circumstances the theory of comparative advantage predicts
that a rich country might actually be worse off by switching to a free trade regime with a
poor nation.7 We will consider Samuelson’s critique in the next section.
Extensions of the Ricardian model
We’ll now explore the effect of relaxing three of the assumptions identified earlier in the
simple comparative advantage model. We relax the assumptions that resources move freely
from the production of one good to another within a country, that there are constant
returns to scale and that trade does not change a country’s stock of resources or the
efficiency with which those resources are used.
Immobile resources In our simple comparative model of Ghana and South Korea, we
assumed that producers could easily convert land from the production of cocoa to rice, and
vice versa. While this assumption may hold for some agricultural products, resources do not
always shift quite so easily from producing one good to another. For example, embracing
a free trade regime for an advanced economy such as Australia, New Zealand, Japan or the
United States often implies that the country will produce less of some labour-intensive
goods, such as textiles, and more of some knowledge-intensive goods, such as computer
software or biotechnology products. Although the country as a whole will gain from such a
shift, textile producers will lose. A textile worker in Sydney, Auckland or Tokyo is probably
not qualified to write software. Thus, the shift to free trade may mean that he or she
becomes unemployed, must be retrained or has to accept another less attractive job.
Resources do not always move easily from one economic activity into another. While
the theory predicts that the benefits of free trade outweigh the costs, this is of little
comfort to those who bear the costs. Additionally, it takes time, sometimes years, to
replace an outmoded industry and its employment with a new one. Accordingly, political
opposition to the adoption of a free trade regime typically comes from those whose jobs are
most at risk. In Australia, for example, workers and companies in the car industry generally
resisted the move towards free trade precisely because this group had much to lose from
free trade. Indeed, the last car plant in Australia closed in 2017 after remaining government
subsidies were removed.
Diminishing returns The simple comparative advantage model developed earlier assumes
constant returns to specialisation. Constant returns to specialisation means that the units
of resources required to produce a good (cocoa or rice) are assumed to remain constant
no matter where one sits on a country’s production possibility frontier. Thus, we assumed
that it always took Ghana 10 units of resources to produce 1 tonne of cocoa. However, it
is more realistic to assume diminishing returns to specialisation. Diminishing returns to
specialisation occurs when more units of resources are required to produce each additional
unit. While 10 units of resources may be sufficient to increase Ghana’s output of cocoa
from 12 tonnes to 13 tonnes, 11 units of resources may be needed to increase output
from 13 tonnes to 14 tonnes, 12 units of resources to increase output from 14 tonnes to
15 tonnes, and so on. Diminishing returns implies a convex PPF for Ghana (see Figure 2.2),
rather than the straight line depicted in Figure 2.1.
It is more realistic to assume diminishing returns for two reasons. First, not all resources
are of the same quality. As a country tries to increase its output of a certain good, it is
increasingly likely to draw on more marginal resources whose productivity is not as great
as those initially employed. The result is that it requires ever more resources to produce
an equal increase in output. For example, some land is more productive than other land.
As Ghana tries to expand its output of cocoa, it might have to use increasingly marginal
CHAPTER 2
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 65
THEORIES OF TRADE, INVESTMENT AND INTERNATIONALISATION
65
08/06/19 07:41 PM
FIGURE 2.2
Ghana’s PPF under
diminishing returns
Cocoa
G
0
Rice
LO 2.1
FIGURE 2.3
The influence of free trade
on the PPF
PPF2
Cocoa
PPF1
0
66
Rice
PART 2
land that is less fertile than the land it originally used. As yields per hectare decline,
Ghana must use more land to produce each additional tonne of cocoa. A second reason
for diminishing returns is that different goods use resources in different
proportions. For example, imagine that growing cocoa uses more land and
less labour than growing rice, and that Ghana tries to transfer resources
from rice production to cocoa production. The rice industry will release
proportionately too much labour and too little land for efficient cocoa
production. To absorb the additional resources of labour and land, the
cocoa industry will have to shift towards more labour-intensive methods of
production. The effect is that the efficiency with which the cocoa industry
uses labour will decline, and returns will diminish.
Diminishing returns shows that it is not feasible for a country to
specialise to the degree suggested by the simple Ricardian model outlined
earlier. Diminishing returns to specialisation suggests that the gains from
G'
specialisation are likely to be exhausted before specialisation is complete.
In reality, most countries do not specialise, but instead, produce a range of
goods. However, the theory predicts that it is worthwhile to specialise until
the point where the resulting gains from trade are outweighed by diminishing returns. Thus,
the basic conclusion that unrestricted free trade is beneficial still holds, although, because of
diminishing returns, the gains may not be as great as suggested in the constant returns case.
Dynamic effects and economic growth The simple comparative advantage model
assumes that trade does not change a country’s stock of resources or the efficiency with
which it utilises those resources. This assumption is static, referring to conditions at a
single point in time, and makes no allowances for the dynamic changes over time that
might result from trade. If we relax this assumption, it becomes apparent that opening
an economy to trade is likely to generate dynamic gains of two types.8 First, free trade
might increase a country’s stock of resources, as increased supplies of labour and capital
from abroad become available for use within the country. For example, this occurred when
foreign companies first invested in China as that economy opened up in the 1990s and
early 2000s and it is now occurring again as China is investing in nearby South-East Asia
as its own production costs have risen.
Second, free trade might also increase the efficiency with which a country uses its
resources. Gains in the efficiency of resource utilisation could arise from a number of
factors. For example, economies of large-scale production might become available as trade
expands the size of the total market available to domestic companies. Trade might make
better technology from abroad available to domestic companies. Better technology can
increase labour productivity or the productivity of land. The so-called green revolution
had this effect on agricultural outputs in developing countries such as
India. Also, opening an economy to foreign competition might stimulate
domestic producers to look for ways to increase their efficiency. Again, this
phenomenon has arguably been occurring in the once-protected markets
of Eastern Europe and China, where many former state monopolies
have had to increase the efficiency of their operations to survive in the
competitive world market.
Dynamic gains in both the stock of a country’s resources and the
efficiency with which resources are utilised will cause a country’s PPF to
shift outward. This is illustrated in Figure 2.3, where the shift from PPF1
to PPF2 results from the dynamic gains that arise from free trade. As a
consequence of this outward shift, the country in Figure 2.3 can produce
more of both goods than it did before the introduction of free trade. The
theory suggests that opening an economy to free trade results not only in
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 66
08/06/19 07:41 PM
static gains of the type discussed earlier, but also in dynamic gains that stimulate economic
growth. If this is so, the case for free trade becomes stronger still. However, these effects do
take time and there can be losses during the transition period. Moreover, as noted earlier,
one of the leading economic theorists of the 20th century, Paul Samuelson, argued that in
some circumstances, dynamic gains can lead to an outcome that is not so beneficial.
The Samuelson critique
Samuelson’s critique considers what happens when a rich country such as Singapore, New
Zealand or Australia enters into a free trade agreement with an emerging market—such as
China—that rapidly improves its productivity after the introduction of a free trade regime.
That is, there is a dynamic gain in the efficiency with which resources are used in the
poorer country. Samuelson’s model suggests that in such cases, the lower prices that
Australian consumers pay for goods imported from China following the introduction of a
free trade regime may not be enough to produce a net gain for the Australian economy if
the dynamic effect of free trade is to lower real wage rates in Australia.9
Samuelson goes on to note that his concern is also about the ability to move offshore
service jobs that traditionally were not internationally mobile, such as software debugging,
call centre jobs, accounting jobs and even medical diagnosis of CT scans. Recent advances
in communications technology have made this possible, effectively expanding the labour
market for these jobs to include educated people in places such as India, the Philippines
and China. When coupled with rapid advances in the productivity of foreign labour due
to better education, the effect on middle-class wages in developed countries such as
the United States, New Zealand and Australia may be similar to mass inward migration
into those countries. It will lower the market clearing wage rate, perhaps by enough to
outweigh the positive benefits of international trade.
However, Samuelson concedes that free trade has historically benefited rich countries
(as data discussed later confirm). Also, he notes that introducing protectionist measures
(e.g. trade barriers) to guard against the theoretical possibility that free trade may harm
developed countries in the future may produce a situation that is worse than the disease
they are trying to prevent. To quote Samuelson: ‘Free trade may turn out pragmatically
to be still best for each region in comparison to lobbyist-induced tariffs and quotas which
involve both a perversion of democracy and non subtle deadweight distortion losses’.10
Evidence for the link between trade and growth
LO 2.1
Many economic studies have looked at the relationship between trade and economic
growth.11 In general, these studies suggest that, as predicted by comparative advantage
theory, countries that adopt a more open stance towards international trade enjoy higher
growth rates than those that close their economies to trade. (The Opening Case provides
evidence of the link between trade and growth.) Jeffrey Sachs and Andrew Warner
created a measure of how ‘open’ to international trade an economy was, and then looked
at the relationship between openness and economic growth for a sample of more than
100 countries from 1970 to 1990.12 Among other findings, they reported:
We find a strong association between openness and growth, both within the group
of developing and the group of developed countries. Within the group of developing
countries, the open economies grew at 4.49 per cent per year, and the closed
economies grew at 0.69 per cent per year. Within the group of developed economies,
the open economies grew at 2.29 per cent per year, and the closed economies grew
at 0.74 per cent per year.13
CHAPTER 2
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 67
THEORIES OF TRADE, INVESTMENT AND INTERNATIONALISATION
67
08/06/19 07:41 PM
A study by Romain Wacziarg and Karen Horn Welch updated the Sachs and Warner
data through the late 1990s. They found that from 1950 to 1998, countries that liberalised
their trade regimes experienced, on average, increases in their annual growth rates of
1.5 per cent compared to pre-liberalisation times.14
However, there is also evidence that further trade liberalisation, at least in the
developed world, may be yielding diminishing returns. A survey of economic studies
of the gains to the US economy from concluding the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP)
trade agreement found estimated annual gains to US GDP of between 0.15 per cent and
0.5 per cent—not negligible but not as large as prior agreements, which may have already
picked most of the ‘low-hanging fruit’ so to speak. This is not an argument per se against
further liberalisation, but an indication that the substantial disruption that can occur
during transition periods is now often proportionately greater relative to the potential gains
than used to be the case.15 This may be one reason why new large trade agreements have
not been as easy to reach as they used to be.
© Purestock/Superstock
MANAGEMENT FOCUS
HOLLOWING OUT THE MANUFACTURINGBASED ECONOMY
Major banks in Australia and other countries have
outsourced or relocated skilled jobs overseas to lowcost countries such as India and the Philippines.
Classical economists have long argued that free
trade produces gains for all countries that participate
in a free trading system; however, as the Global
Financial Crisis (GFC) of 2007–09 swept through
the Australian and New Zealand economies, many
people—particularly those who lost their jobs as a
result—wondered if this were true. In the past quarter
68
PART 2
of a century, free trade has been associated with the
movement of low-skill, blue-collar manufacturing jobs
out of rich developed countries (such as Australia
and New Zealand) towards low-wage countries—for
example, textiles and shoes to China, and information
technology to India. Developments such as the
shifting of manufacturing to Asia by Pacific Brands
(the owner of brands such as Bonds, KingGee and
Holeproof) at the height of the financial downturn with
a loss of over 1800 jobs were indicative of this trend.
Earlier, the iconic Australian boot-maker Blundstone
shifted its manufacturing overseas, with the loss of
350 jobs in Tasmania and New Zealand, when it was
unable to compete with cheaper imports because
of the relatively high wages in Australia and New
Zealand. Blundstone decided not to seek government
assistance or protection against cheaper imports;
instead, it addressed the low-cost competition issue
on a permanent basis by choosing to manufacture
overseas while retaining Australian ownership. For
the workers being made redundant as a result of such
developments, the future is often bleak—they may find
it difficult to gain employment locally with a similar
company where their skills will be useful.
While many observers bemoan the ‘hollowing out’
of Australian and New Zealand manufacturing,
economists have traditionally argued that high-skilled
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 68
08/06/19 07:41 PM
and high-wage white-collar jobs associated with the
service and knowledge-based economy will stay in
these countries. For example, garments might be
made in China or Indonesia, but they will continue
to be designed in Australia and New Zealand, they
say. However, automation and artificial intelligence
(AI) are making many skilled jobs either redundant or
more ‘tradeable’ in the sense that they can be done
remotely anywhere. These recent developments
have some people questioning the assumption
about continued growth in the knowledge-based
sector. Even during the long economic boom in the
1990s, Bank of America had to compete with other
organisations for the scarce talents of information
technology (IT) specialists, driving annual salaries
to more than US$100 000. But with business under
pressure, the bank cut nearly 5000 jobs from its
25 000-strong, US-based IT workforce. Some of these
jobs were transferred to India, where work that costs
$100 an hour in the United States could be done for
$20 an hour.
In Australia, a number of banks such as ANZ have
outsourced jobs to India and the Philippines. Filipino
employees earn around $6000 per year, while their
Australian counterparts may earn 10 times that amount.
Shifting work to the Philippines gives the banks a costbased competitive advantage in the very competitive
global banking sector.
The companies that outsource or relocate skilled
jobs clearly benefit from lower costs, enhanced
competitiveness in the global economy and greater
profits. Developing nations such as India and the
Philippines, which have a good supply of welleducated, skilled and (by global standards) low-cost
labour, also benefit. However, some observers wonder
whether developed countries such as Australia and
New Zealand will suffer from the loss of highly skilled
and high-paying jobs in addition to low-skilled jobs.
Standard trade theory would argue that while
there will be short-term losses to some workers,
the overall economy will benefit, although with a
changing structure. They point out that while some
of the more routine skilled jobs are going overseas,
most managerial, marketing and cutting-edge research
and development jobs are staying in developed
countries such as Australia or New Zealand, precisely
because these countries have a comparative
advantage in those areas. Second, economists argue
that the lower price of services that results from such
outsourcing means that the average Australian or
New Zealand consumer can afford to consume more
of these services, or can use any savings to consume
more of other goods and services, thereby boosting
economic growth and associated employment. Third,
economists believe that any economic growth that
occurs in China, India, the Philippines and so on, as a
result of this trend will ultimately benefit Australia and
New Zealand, since consumers in those countries will
be able to purchase more Australian and New Zealand
goods and services.
In the end it comes down to the data, past and future.
Research by the Boston Federal Reserve Bank in the
United States indicates that past experience shows that
offshoring of jobs has caused disruption but overall
jobs eliminated onshore have been more than replaced
with new jobs in new industries and activities. On the
other hand, a working paper by the US International
Trade Office notes: ‘Offshoring is a contentious
political issue. Unfortunately, it is also a complex
economic issue, with many subtle aspects in which
a simple model may over-simplify and thus miss key
mechanisms or outcomes.’ Time will tell.
SOURCES: K. Barlow, ‘AM–Blundstone’s move offshore leaves 350 jobless’, ABC Online, 17 January 2007 accessed via www.abc.net.au/am/content/
2007/s1828662.htm on 7 August 2009; ‘Bonds, King Gee owner slashes 1850 jobs’, ABC Online, accessed via www.abc.net.au/news/stories/2009/
02/25/2500712.htm on 7 August 2009; C. Waters, ‘ANZ recruiting in Philippines as local jobs axed’, The Age, 19 February 2012, accessed via www.
theage.com.au/national/anz-recruiting-in-philippines-as-local-jobs-axed-20120218-1tg3l.html#ixzz2Ak3EA13K on 30 October 2012; A. Barbe and D.
Riker, ‘The Effects of Offshoring on Domestic Workers: A Review of the Literature’, Working Paper 2017-10-A, US International Trade Commission, October
2017; J. Little, ‘Perspective: outsourcing jobs overseas, a cause for concern?’, US Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Regional Review, Q2/Q3 2004, pp. 2–6.
Heckscher–Ohlin theory
LO 2.2
Ricardo argued that comparative advantage arises from differences in productivity. Thus,
whether Ghana is more efficient than South Korea in the production of cocoa depends
on how productively it uses its resources. Swedish economists Eli Heckscher (1919) and
Bertil Ohlin (1933) (independently) put forward an explanation of comparative advantage
CHAPTER 2
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 69
THEORIES OF TRADE, INVESTMENT AND INTERNATIONALISATION
69
08/06/19 07:41 PM
based on differences in national factor endowments,16 the extent to which a country is
endowed with resources such as land, labour and capital. Nations have different factor
endowments, and different factor endowments explain differences in factor costs. The
more abundant a factor, the lower its cost will be. The Heckscher–Ohlin theory predicts
that countries will export those goods that make intensive use of their relatively abundant
factors and they will import goods that make intensive use of their relatively scarce
factors. Like Ricardian theory, the Heckscher–Ohlin theory argues that free trade is
beneficial, but unlike Ricardo’s theory, the Heckscher–Ohlin theory argues that the pattern
of international trade is determined by differences in factor endowments, rather than gross
differences in productivity.
The theory has commonsense appeal. For example, Australia, New Zealand and the
United States have long been exporters of agricultural goods, reflecting in part their
abundance of arable land. In contrast, China exports goods produced in labour-intensive
light manufacturing industries. This reflects China’s relative abundance of low-cost labour.
Australia, New Zealand and the United States, which are high labour-cost economies, have
been importers of these goods. Note that it is relative, not absolute, endowments that are
important. A country may have larger absolute amounts of land and labour than another
country, but be relatively abundant in one of them.
© yousang/Shutterstock
The Leontief paradox
Heckscher–Ohlin theory has been influential in international economics. It is generally
preferred to Ricardo’s theory because it makes fewer simplifying assumptions. Because
of its influence, Heckscher–Ohlin theory has been subjected to many empirical tests.
Beginning with a famous study published in 1953 by Wassily Leontief (winner of the Nobel
Prize in economics in 1973), many of these tests have raised questions about the validity of
Heckscher–Ohlin theory.17 Applying Heckscher–Ohlin theory, Leontief postulated that the
United States would be an exporter of c­ apital-intensive goods and an importer of labourintensive goods because it was relatively abundant in capital. He found that US exports
were less capital intensive than were US imports; hence, this result became known as the
Leontief paradox. Tests of the theory using data for a large number of countries tend to
confirm the existence of the Leontief paradox.18
One possible explanation for this paradox in the
United States context is that the United States has a
special advantage in producing new products or goods
made with innovative technologies. These products
may be less physical capital intensive than are products
whose technology has had time to mature and become
suitable for mass production. Thus, the United States may
be exporting goods that heavily use skilled labour and
innovative entrepreneurship, such as computer software,
while importing heavy manufacturing products that use
large amounts of physical capital. Empirical studies tend to
confirm this explanation.19
This presents a dilemma though. Heckscher–Ohlin theory
is preferred on theoretical grounds, but it is a relatively
poor predictor of real-world international trade patterns. On
American car manufacturing company Tesla Motors prides
the other hand, Ricardo’s theory of comparative advantage
itself on energy innovation. Its first plug-in electric car, the
actually predicts trade patterns with greater accuracy. A
Model S, is shown here being charged at a supercharger
station in Beijing.
solution to this dilemma may be to return to the Ricardian
70
PART 2
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 70
08/06/19 07:41 PM
idea that trade patterns are largely driven by international differences in productivity. Thus,
one might argue that the United States exports commercial aircraft and imports textiles
not because its factor endowments are especially suited to aircraft manufacture and not
suited to textile manufacture, but because the United States is relatively more efficient at
producing aircrafts than textiles.
A key assumption in Heckscher–Ohlin theory is that technologies are the same across
countries. This may not be the case. Differences in technology may lead to differences in
productivity. These differences, in turn, drive international trade patterns.20 Thus, Japan’s
success in exporting vehicles in the 1970s and 1980s was based not just on the relative
abundance of capital, but also on its development of innovative manufacturing technology,
coupled with a high standard of quality, which enabled it to achieve higher productivity
levels in vehicle production than other countries that also had abundant capital. Recent
empirical investigations strongly suggest that this explanation may be correct.21 The
new research shows that once differences in technology across countries are controlled
for, countries do export those goods that make intensive use of factors that are locally
abundant, while importing goods that make intensive use of factors that are locally scarce.
In other words, once the impact of differences of technology on productivity is controlled
for, Heckscher–Ohlin theory seems to gain predictive power.
THE PRODUCT LIFE-CYCLE THEORY
LO 2.2
The theories considered thus far demonstrate that unfettered trade is generally beneficial
to those who undertake it. They are also more based in pure economic theory than the
business realities of the market in action. We will now turn to theories that focus more on
explaining the patterns of trade that are actually observed in practice.
Raymond Vernon initially proposed his product life-cycle theory in the mid-1960s.22
This theory was based on the observation that for most of the 20th century a large
proportion of the world’s new products had been developed by US companies and sold
first in the US market (e.g. mass-produced cars, televisions, instant cameras, photocopiers,
personal computers and semiconductor chips). To explain this, Vernon argued that the
disposable income and size of the US market gave US companies a strong incentive
to develop new consumer products. In addition, the high cost of US labour gave US
companies an incentive to develop cost-saving process innovations. One could say that
while traditional trade theories focus on the nature of the supply side, Vernon’s theory
incorporates elements of product demand into why countries specialise in particular ways
and how that specialisation can change over time.
Just because a new product (such as a microwave oven) is developed by a US company
and first sold in the US market, it does not follow that all new products must be produced
in the United States. It could be produced abroad at some low-cost location and then
exported back into the United States. Nonetheless, Vernon argued that most new products
were initially produced in America, which was an accurate observation in his time.
Pioneering companies believed it was better to keep production facilities close to the
market and to the company’s centre of decision making, given the uncertainty and risks
inherent in introducing new products. Also, the demand for most new products tends to be
based on non-price factors, such as quality. Consequently, companies can charge relatively
high prices for new products, which obviates the need to look for low-cost production sites
in other countries.
Vernon went on to argue that early in the life-cycle of a typical new product, while
demand was growing rapidly in the United States, demand in other advanced countries
CHAPTER 2
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 71
THEORIES OF TRADE, INVESTMENT AND INTERNATIONALISATION
71
08/06/19 07:41 PM
160
140
120
100
Production
80
60
40
20
0
160
140
120
100
80
60
40
Consumption
20
0
160
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
New
product
FIGURE 2.4
The product life-cycle theory
72
PART 2
was limited to high-income groups. This limited demand elsewhere does not make
it worthwhile for companies in those countries to start producing the new product,
but it does necessitate some exports from the United States to those countries. Over
time, demand for the new product continues to grow in the other advanced countries,
ultimately making it worthwhile for foreign
producers to begin producing for their home
A. United States
markets. In addition, US companies might set up
production facilities in those advanced countries
where demand is growing, limiting the potential
for exports from the United States.
As the market in the United States and other
Imports
advanced nations matures, the product becomes
Exports
standardised, price becomes the main competitive
weapon and cost considerations play a greater
role in the competitive process. Producers based
Consumption
in advanced countries where labour costs are
lower than in the United States might now
be able to export to the United States. If cost
pressures become intense, the process might not
stop there and the locus of global production
B. Other advanced countries
initially switches from the United States to
other advanced nations and then from those
nations to developing countries. Over time, the
s
t
r
United States switches from being the inventor
o
Exp
and exporter of the product to an importer as
production becomes concentrated in lower-cost
foreign locations.
Figure 2.4 shows the growth of production
and consumption over time in the United States,
rts
other advanced countries and developing countries.
o
Production
p
Im
What this graph is positing is that in the early
stages of a new product, the first units produced
are made in the originating country (in this
example, the United States). At first, domestic
C. Developing countries
production levels are small and domestically
consumed, but as production expands domestic
demand is satisfied and units are increasingly made
to export to markets with similar characteristics
(in this case, other advanced countries). These
importing countries then start to follow a similar
Exports
cycle, developing their own production of the
new product for their own consumption, and then
shifting towards exporting. After a time, as the
Consumption
product market saturates and matures, and the
s
t
r
o
product has become standardised and low cost to
Imp
Production
produce, both the originating country (the United
States) and the similarly situated export markets
Maturing
Standardised
product
product
(other advanced countries) begin to offshore
production of the product to ­low-cost developing
Stages of product development
economies, which now become the manufacturers
and exporters to the rest of the world.
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 72
08/06/19 07:41 PM
Evaluating the product life-cycle theory
The product life-cycle theory appears to be an accurate explanation of international
trade patterns for manufacturing-based economies. For example, photocopiers were first
developed in the early 1960s by Xerox in the United States and sold initially in the United
States. Xerox then exported photocopiers from the United States, primarily to Japan and
the advanced countries of Western Europe. As demand began to grow in those countries,
Xerox entered into joint ventures to produce in Japan (Fuji–Xerox) and the United Kingdom
(Rank–Xerox). In addition, once Xerox’s patents on the photocopier process expired, other
foreign competitors began to enter the market (e.g. Canon in Japan, Olivetti in Italy). As a
consequence, exports from the United States declined, and US users began to buy some
of their photocopiers from lower-cost foreign sources, particularly Japan. More recently,
Japanese companies have found that manufacturing costs are too high in their country,
so they have begun to switch production to developing countries such as Singapore and
Thailand. Thus, the United States and other advanced countries (e.g. Japan and the United
Kingdom) have switched from being exporters of photocopiers to importers. This evolution
in the pattern of international trade in photocopiers is consistent with the predictions of
the product life-cycle theory. Even China is, in many ways, following this pattern now.
However, the product life-cycle theory is not without shortcomings. Vernon’s argument
that most new products are developed and introduced in the United States is true during
the period of US global dominance (from 1945 to 1975), when most new products were
introduced in the United States, but even then there were important exceptions. These
exceptions have become more common in recent years. Many new products are now
introduced elsewhere (e.g. video-game consoles in Japan). In addition, with the increased
globalisation and integration of the world economy (discussed in Chapter 1), many new
products (e.g. laptop computers, compact discs, digital cameras, mobile devices) are
introduced simultaneously in the United States, Japan, Australia, New Zealand, Singapore,
the advanced European nations and elsewhere. This may be accompanied by globally
dispersed production, with particular components of a new product produced in those
locations around the globe where the mix of factor costs and skills is most favourable, as
predicted by the theory of comparative advantage. Finally, economies have become more
service-based and the notion of a product life-cycle may be more subtle.
NEW TRADE THEORY
LO 2.3
New trade theory emerged in the 1970s when a number of economists pointed out
that relaxing the assumptions that were necessary in earlier trade theories highlighted
outcomes and policy recommendations that were different from those earlier practised.
The assumption of constant returns to scale (CRS) is particularly unrealistic, and while all
theory requires simplifying assumptions, this one has been seen as too simplistic given that
the ability of companies to attain economies of scale often has important implications for
international trade. Economies of scale are unit cost reductions associated with a large scale
of output. Economies of scale have a number of sources, including the ability to spread
fixed costs over a large volume, and the ability of large-volume producers to use specialised
employees and equipment that are more productive than less specialised employees and
equipment. Economies of scale are a major source of cost reductions in many industries,
including computer software, vehicles, pharmaceuticals and aerospace. For example, Google
and Facebook realise economies of scale by spreading the fixed costs of developing new
versions, and maintaining existing versions, of their online tools and platforms. Similarly,
vehicle manufacturers realise economies of scale by producing high volumes from an
assembly line where each employee has a specialised task, repeatedly undertaken.
CHAPTER 2
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 73
ECONOMIES OF SCALE
Cost advantages associated with
large-scale production
THEORIES OF TRADE, INVESTMENT AND INTERNATIONALISATION
73
08/06/19 07:41 PM
New trade theory makes two important points based on this. First, international trade
can increase economies of scale by increasing the size of the market. Second, in those
industries where the output required to attain economies of scale represents a significant
proportion of total world demand, the global market will support only a small number
of companies. Thus, world trade in certain products may be dominated by countries
whose companies were first movers in their production.
LO 2.1
Increasing product variety and reducing costs
Imagine a world without trade. In industries where economies of scale are important, both
the variety of goods that a country can produce and the scale of production are limited
by the size of the home market. If the home market is small, there may not be demand
to enable producers to realise economies of scale for certain products. Accordingly, those
products may not be produced at all, thereby limiting consumer choice. Alternatively,
they may be produced, but at such low volumes that unit costs and thus prices are much
higher than they might be if economies of scale could be realised.
Now enable countries to trade with each other. Individual home markets aggregate into
a large world market. As the size of this market expands due to trade, individual companies
may be able to better attain economies of scale. The implication, according to new trade
theory, is that each nation may be able to specialise in producing a narrower range of
products than it would in the absence of trade, yet by importing goods that it does not make
from other countries, each nation can simultaneously increase the variety of goods available
to its consumers. The costs of these goods are lowered; thus, trade offers an opportunity for
mutual gain even when countries do not differ in their resource endowments or technology.
Suppose two countries each have an annual home market for one million cars. By
trading with each other, these countries can create a combined market for two million
cars. In this combined market, due to the ability to realise economies of scale better, more
varieties (models) of cars can be produced, and at a lower average cost, than in either
market alone. For example, demand for a sports car may be limited to 55 000 units in each
national market, while a total output of at least 100 000 per year may be required to realise
significant scale economies. Similarly, demand for a minivan may be 80 000 units in each
national market, and again a total output of at least 100 000 per year may be required to
realise significant scale economies.
Faced with limited domestic market demand, companies in each nation may decide
not to produce a sports car, since the costs of doing so at such low volume are too great.
Although they may produce minivans, the cost of doing so will be higher than if significant
economies of scale had been attained. However, if these two countries trade, a company
in one nation may specialise in producing sports cars, while a company in the other
nation may produce minivans. The combined demand for 110 000 sports cars and 160 000
minivans allows each company to realise scale economies. Consumers benefit from having
access to a product (sports cars) that was not available before international trade, and from
the lower price for a product (minivans) that could not be produced at the most efficient
scale before international trade. Trade is mutually beneficial because it allows for the
specialisation of production, the realisation of scale economies, the production of a greater
variety of products and at lower prices.
LO 2.4
FIRST-MOVER ADVANTAGES
Advantages accruing to firms that
enter markets early
74
PART 2
Economies of scale, first-mover advantages and the
pattern of trade
A second theme in new trade theory is that the pattern of trade we observe worldwide
may be the result of economies of scale and first-mover advantages. First-mover advantages
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 74
08/06/19 07:41 PM
are the economic and strategic advantages that accrue to early entrants into an industry.23
The ability to capture scale economies ahead of later entrants, and thus benefit from a
lower cost structure, is an important first-mover advantage. New trade theory argues that
for those products where economies of scale are significant and represent a substantial
proportion of world demand, the first movers in an industry can gain a scale-based cost
advantage that later entrants find almost impossible to match. Countries may dominate in
the export of certain goods because economies of scale are important in their production
and because firms located in those countries were the first to capture scale economies,
giving them a first-mover advantage.
For example, consider the commercial aerospace industry. Substantial scale economies
arise from the ability to spread the fixed costs of developing a new jet aircraft over a
large number of sales. It cost Airbus some US$14 billion to develop its super-jumbo jet,
the 550-seat A380. To recoup those costs and break even, Airbus had to sell at least 250
of the A380 planes. If it could sell more than 350 of the A380 planes, it would have been
a profitable venture. However, demand for this class of aircraft has turned out to be well
below this number and Airbus is closing production of the plane in 2021.24 Airbus was
calculating that the global market could profitably support only one producer of jet aircraft
in the super-jumbo category and was hoping to dominate in the export of very large jet
aircraft, by being the first to produce a 550-seat jet aircraft and realise scale economies.
Other potential producers, such as Boeing, might have been shut out of the market because
they lacked the scale economies that Airbus enjoys in this category. In this case, however,
the gamble failed, due to changes in the way airlines serve their customers, increasingly
moving away from flying to ultimate destinations through major hubs (where carrying
large numbers in a single plane makes sense) and returning to an older pattern of more
direct flights (where smaller capacity planes, cheaper to operate, are better). What this case
illustrates is that economies of scale, combined with first-mover advantage, can create a
powerful competitive advantage for a company and, by extension, the nation or region that
company is based in.
Implications of new trade theory
LO 2.1, 2.4
New trade theory has important implications. This theory suggests that nations may
benefit from trade even when they do not differ in resource endowments or technology.
Trade allows a nation to specialise in the production of certain products, attaining scale
economies and lowering the costs of producing those products, while importing products
that it does not produce from other nations that specialise in the production of those
products. By this mechanism, the variety of products available to consumers in each nation
is increased, while the average costs of those products should fall, as should their price,
thus freeing resources to produce other goods and services.
The theory also suggests that a country may predominate in the export of a good
simply because it was lucky enough to have one or more companies among the first to
produce that good. Because they are able to gain economies of scale, the first movers in
an industry may dominate in the world market and discourage entry by other companies.
In the commercial aircraft industry, that Boeing and Airbus are already in the industry
and have the benefits of economies of scale discourages entry by new companies and
reinforces the dominance of the United States and Europe in the trade of midsize and large
jet aircraft (although China could possibly now challenge this dominance with its extensive
state support for strategic industries). This dominance is further reinforced because global
demand may not be sufficient to profitably support another producer of midsize and large
jet aircraft in the industry. So, although Japanese companies might be able to compete
CHAPTER 2
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 75
THEORIES OF TRADE, INVESTMENT AND INTERNATIONALISATION
75
08/06/19 07:41 PM
in the market, they have decided not to enter the industry but to position themselves
as major subcontractors to primary producers (e.g. Mitsubishi Heavy Industries is a major
subcontractor for Boeing on the 777 and 787 programs).
New trade theory is at variance with Heckscher–Ohlin theory, which, as we have seen,
suggests that a country will predominate in the export of a product when it is particularly
well endowed with those factors used intensively in its manufacture. New trade theorists
argue that the United States is a major exporter of commercial jet aircraft not because it
is better endowed with the factors of production required to manufacture aircraft, but
because one of the first movers in the industry, Boeing, was a US company. However,
new trade theory is not at variance with the comparative advantage theory. Economies of
scale increase productivity. Thus, the new trade theory identifies an important source of
comparative advantage.
This theory is especially useful in explaining trade patterns. Empirical studies support
the predictions of the theory that trade increases the specialisation of production within
an industry, increases the variety of products available to consumers and results in lower
average prices.25 With regard to first-mover advantages and international trade, a study
by Harvard business historian Alfred Chandler suggests that the existence of first-mover
advantages is an important factor in explaining the dominance of companies from certain
nations in specific industries.26 The number of companies is very limited in many global
industries, including the chemical, heavy construction-equipment, heavy truck, tyre,
consumer electronics, jet engine and computer software industries.
EMERGING MARKETS
BRAZIL’S EMBRAER
If you have flown in a jet aircraft in regional Australia,
it is likely you would have travelled in a Brazilian-built
Embraer such as the E 190AR. The company (formerly
known as Embraer-Empresa Brasileira de Aeronáutica
S.A., changing its name to Embraer S.A. in November
2010) was launched by the Brazilian government
in 1969 to give Brazil an independent capacity to
produce aircraft—primarily military aircraft. In the
early years, the company relied on financial support
and orders from the Brazilian government to build
EMB 326 Xavante, an advanced trainer and ground
attack jet, under licence from an Italian company. This
government backing gave Embraer the solid start it
needed to compete with established players and to
carve out a niche market in corporate jets, commercial
regional jets, military trainers and agricultural aviation.
In 2000, as part of the Brazilian government’s
privatisation plans, the company was listed on the
New York Stock Exchange. Since then the company has
expanded globally with production, service or sales
facilities in the United States, China, Portugal, France
and Singapore. The head office and major design and
production facilities are based at São José dos Campos
in São Paulo, where a cluster of high-tech companies
and educational institutions has developed, further
enhancing Embraer’s ability to continue to innovate. As
of early 2019, the company had a market capitalisation
of US$3.8 billion and 18 434 full-time employees.
SOURCE: Yahoo!7 Finance, https://finance.yahoo.com/quote/ERJ/profile?p=ERJ accessed on 20 February 2019.
76
PART 2
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 76
08/06/19 07:41 PM
Certainly the most contentious implication of new trade theory is its support for
an argument for government intervention and strategic trade policy.27 New trade
theorists stress the role of luck, entrepreneurship and innovation in giving a firm firstmover advantage. According to this argument, the reason Boeing was the first mover
in commercial jet aircraft manufacture, rather than companies such as the United
Kingdom’s DeHavilland and Hawker Siddeley or the Netherlands’ Fokker (all of which
could have been), was that Boeing was both lucky and innovative. Boeing was lucky
in that DeHavilland jeopardised its prospects when its Comet jet airliner, introduced
two years earlier than Boeing’s first jet airliner, the 707, was found to be seriously
technologically flawed. Had DeHavilland not made technological mistakes, the United
Kingdom might have become the world’s leading exporter of commercial jet aircraft.
Boeing’s innovativeness was demonstrated by its independent development of the
technological know-how required to build a commercial jet airliner. Several new trade
theorists have pointed out, however, that Boeing’s research and development was
largely paid for by the US government; that is, the 707 was a spin-off from governmentfunded military programs. (The entry of Airbus into the industry was supported also by
significant government subsidies.) Herein is a rationale for government intervention: by
the sophisticated and judicious use of subsidies, could a government increase the chances
of its domestic companies becoming first movers in newly emerging industries, as the US
government did with Boeing, the European Union with Airbus and the Brazilians with
Embraer (see Emerging Markets: ‘Brazil’s Embraer’)? This being possible, new trade theory
suggests an economic rationale for a proactive trade policy exists that is at variance with
the free trade prescriptions of the earlier trade theories we have introduced. Having said
this, governments still need to tread with caution. The historical record suggests that the
public sector’s ability to ‘pick winners’ is uneven and subject to political considerations.
NATIONAL COMPETITIVE ADVANTAGE:
PORTER’S DIAMOND
LO 2.2
Economic theory uses a deductive method; that is, a theory is posited and its validity is
then checked against the facts. This is generally a sound approach but in the complex
world of international business a more inductive approach is also useful; that is, collecting
facts and then building a theory suggested by those facts that can then be tested against
additional data.
In 1990, Michael Porter of the Harvard Business School published the results of an
extensive research project that attempted to determine why some nations succeed and
others fail in international competition.28 Porter looked at 100 industries in 10 nations.
Like the new trade theorists, Porter’s work was driven by a belief that existing theories of
international trade were at best partial. For Porter, the task was to explain why a nation
achieves international success in a particular industry. Why, for example, does Japan do
so well in the car industry? Why does Switzerland excel in the production and export
of precision instruments and pharmaceuticals? Why do Germany and the United States
do so well in the chemical industry? These questions cannot be answered by Heckscher–
Ohlin theory (since all these countries have similar factor endowments), and the theory
of comparative advantage offers only a partial explanation. The theory of comparative
advantage would say that Switzerland excels in the production and export of precision
instruments because it uses its resources very productively in these industries. Although
this may be correct, this does not explain why Switzerland is more productive in this
industry than the United Kingdom, Germany or Spain. Porter tries to solve this puzzle
by positing that four broad attributes of a nation shape the environment in which local
CHAPTER 2
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 77
THEORIES OF TRADE, INVESTMENT AND INTERNATIONALISATION
77
08/06/19 07:41 PM
companies compete, and these attributes promote or
impede the creation of ‘competitive’ advantage (see
Figure 2.5). These attributes are:
Firm strategy,
structure and
rivalry
Factor
endowments
Demand
conditions
Relating and
supporting
industries
FIGURE 2.5
Determinants of national competitive
advantage: Porter’s diamond
SOURCE: Reprinted by permission of the
Harvard Business Review. ‘The competitive
advantage of nations’ by Michael E. Porter,
March–April 1990, p. 77. © 1990 by The
President and Fellows of Harvard College.
All rights reserved. https://hbr.org/1990/03/
the-competitive-advantage-of-nations.
• F
actor endowments—a nation’s factors of production such
as skilled labour or the infrastructure necessary to
compete in a given industry
• D
emand conditions—the nature of home demand for the
industry’s product or service
• R
elating and supporting industries—the presence or absence
of supplier industries and related industries that are
internationally competitive
• F
irm strategy, structure and rivalry—the conditions
governing how companies are created, organised and
managed, and the extent of domestic rivalry.
These four attributes constitute Porter’s diamond. He argues that companies are most
likely to succeed in industries or segments of an industry where the diamond is complete
and favourable. He also argues that the diamond is a mutually reinforcing system. The
effect of one attribute is contingent on the state of others. For example, Porter argues that
favourable demand conditions will not result in competitive advantage unless the state
of rivalry is sufficient to cause companies to respond to them. Porter maintains that two
additional variables can influence the national diamond in important ways: chance and
government. Chance events, such as major innovations, can reshape industry structure
and provide the opportunity for the companies from one nation to displace those from
another. Government, by its choice of policies, can impede or improve national competitive
advantage. For example, regulation can alter home demand conditions, antitrust policies
can influence the intensity of rivalry within an industry and government investments in
education can change factor endowments.
Factor endowments
Factor endowments are at the centre of Heckscher–Ohlin theory. Porter embellishes
on this theory by further analysing the characteristics of the factors of production. He
recognises hierarchies among factors, distinguishing between basic factors (e.g. natural
resources, climate, location and demographics) and advanced factors (communication
infrastructure, sophisticated and skilled labour, research facilities and technological knowhow). He argues that advanced factors are the most significant for competitive advantage.
Unlike the naturally endowed basic factors, advanced factors are a product of investment
by individuals, firms and governments. Thus, government investment in basic and higher
education, by improving the general skill and knowledge level of the population and by
stimulating advanced research at higher education institutions, can upgrade a nation’s
advanced factors.
The relationship between advanced and basic factors is complex. Basic factors can
provide an initial advantage that is subsequently reinforced and extended by investment
in advanced factors. For example, in Australia and New Zealand the success of the wine
industry has been attributed to the availability of natural resources—land, and appropriate
climate—as well as skilled labour, research facilities and innovative wine-making processes.
Disadvantages in basic factors can also create pressures to invest in advanced factors. An
obvious example of this phenomenon is Japan, a country that lacks arable land and mineral
78
PART 2
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 78
08/06/19 07:41 PM
deposits and yet, through investment, has built a substantial endowment of advanced
factors. Porter notes that Japan’s large pool of engineers (resulting from more engineering
graduates per capita than almost any other nation) has been vital to Japan’s success in many
manufacturing industries.
Demand conditions
Porter highlights the role home demand plays in upgrading competitive advantage.
Companies are typically most sensitive to the needs of their closest customers. Thus, the
characteristics of home demand are particularly important in shaping the attributes of
domestically made products and in creating pressures for innovation and quality. Porter
argues that a nation’s companies gain competitive advantage if their domestic consumers
are sophisticated and demanding, creating pressure on local companies to meet high
standards of product quality and to produce innovative products. Porter notes that Japan’s
sophisticated and knowledgeable buyers of cameras helped stimulate the Japanese camera
industry to improve product quality and to introduce innovative models. A similar
example can be found in the wireless telephone equipment industry, where sophisticated
and demanding local customers in Scandinavia helped push Nokia of Finland and Ericsson
of Sweden to invest in mobile phone technology long before demand for mobile phones
took off in other developed nations.
Related and supporting industries
The third attribute of national advantage in an industry is the presence of internationally
competitive suppliers or related industries. The benefits of investments by related and
supporting industries in advanced factors of production can spill over into an industry,
thereby helping it achieve a strong competitive position internationally. Swedish expertise
in fabricated steel products (e.g. ball bearings and cutting tools) has drawn on strengths
in its specialty steel industry. Technological leadership in the US semiconductor industry
provided the basis for US success in personal computers and several other technically
advanced electronic products. Similarly, Switzerland’s success in pharmaceuticals is closely
related to its previous international success in the technologically related dye industry.
One consequence of this process is that successful industries within a country tend to be
grouped into clusters of related industries—a pervasive finding of Porter’s study. One such
cluster Porter identified was in the German textile and apparel sector, which included highquality cotton, wool, synthetic fibres, sewing machine needles and a wide range of textile
machinery. Clusters are important because valuable knowledge can flow between companies
within a geographic cluster, benefiting all within that cluster—what economists would call
positive externalities. Knowledge spillovers (another economics term) occur when employees
move between companies within a region and when national industry associations bring
employees from different companies together for regular conferences or workshops.29
Firm strategy, structure and rivalry
The fourth attribute of national competitive advantage in Porter’s model is the strategy,
structure and rivalry of companies within a nation. Porter makes two important points
here. First, different nations are characterised by different management ideologies, which
are either helpful or unhelpful in building national competitive advantage. For example,
Porter noted the predominance of engineers in top management at German and Japanese
companies. He attributed this to these companies’ emphasis on improving manufacturing
CHAPTER 2
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 79
THEORIES OF TRADE, INVESTMENT AND INTERNATIONALISATION
79
08/06/19 07:41 PM
© Maridav/Shutterstock
processes and product design. In contrast, Porter noted a
predominance of people with finance backgrounds leading
many US companies. He linked this to US companies’ lack
of attention to improving manufacturing processes and
product design. He argued that the dominance of finance
led to an overemphasis on maximising short-term financial
returns. According to Porter, one consequence of these
different management ideologies was a relative loss of US
competitiveness in those engineering-based industries where
manufacturing processes and product design issues are allimportant (e.g. the motor vehicle industry).
Porter’s second point here is that there is a strong
association between vigorous domestic rivalry and the
creation and persistence of competitive advantage in an
industry. Vigorous domestic rivalry induces companies to
look for ways to improve efficiency, which makes them more internationally competitive.
Domestic rivalry creates pressures to innovate, to improve quality, to reduce costs and to
invest in upgrading advanced factors. This all helps to create world-class competitors. Porter
cites the case of Japan:
Nowhere is the role of domestic rivalry more evident than in Japan, where it is a­ llout warfare in which many companies fail to achieve profitability. With goals that
stress market share, Japanese companies engage in a continuing struggle to outdo
each other. Shares fluctuate markedly. The process is prominently covered in the
business press. Elaborate rankings measure which companies are most popular
with university graduates. The rate of new product and process development
is breathtaking.30
LO 2.4
Evaluating Porter’s model
Porter contends that the degree to which a nation is likely to achieve international
success in a certain industry is a function of the combined impact of factor endowments,
domestic demand conditions, related and supporting industries, and domestic rivalry—his
diamond. He argues that the presence of all four components is usually required for this
diamond to boost competitive performance. Porter also contends that government can
influence each of the four components of the diamond positively or negatively. Factor
endowments can be affected by subsidies, policies towards capital markets, policies
towards education and the like. Government can shape domestic demand through
local product standards or with regulations that mandate or influence buyer needs.
Government policy can influence supporting and related industries through regulation,
and can influence company rivalry through instruments such as capital market regulation,
tax policy and competition laws.
Porter’s model predicts that the pattern of international trade that we observe
throughout the world consists of countries exporting products from those industries
where all four components of the diamond are favourable, while importing in those
sectors where the components are not favourable. Is he correct? We simply cannot say
so definitively. Porter’s model has not been subjected to independent empirical testing.
Much about his model rings true, but the same can be said for new trade theory, the
theory of comparative advantage and Heckscher–Ohlin theory. It may be that each of these
explanations, which complement each other, explains something about the patterns of
international trade.
80
PART 2
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 80
08/06/19 07:41 PM
COUNTRY FOCUS
INDIA: LONG-TERM OPPORTUNITIES FOR
BILATERAL TRADE AND INVESTMENT
© Image Source, All rights reserved
Of course, India faces many challenges. A large
population is a double-edged sword, providing, on the
one hand, a large potential labour force and customer
base, but on the other hand meaning many mouths to
feed, so to speak. China limited its population growth with
a controversial one-child policy. Democratic India cannot
resort to such extreme measures and has tamed some of
its population growth, but more needs to be done to lower
the birth rate to sustainable levels. Poverty is still endemic
in much of the country. There is a growing middle class,
but many still live in urban slums or off subsistence village
agriculture, and 22 per cent of the population (270 million
people) are below the poverty line.
China has long been the market that Australian
businesses have focused on. The country is expected
to become the world’s largest economy within the next
10–20 years, and it is by far Australia’s largest export
and import trading partner. However, India may be
the ultimate longer term source of growth. Even now
India is Australia’s fifth largest export market valued at
approximately $19.2 billion as of 2016–17; bilateral trade
(including imports and exports) was valued at $25.7
billion over the same period. Australia also has significant
foreign direct investment in India (around $10.3 billion in
2016–17), a little less than Indian foreign investment into
Australia ($13.5 billion) over the same time.
India’s growth rate remains at around 7 per cent per
annum and is now greater than China’s growth rate
which, if such a gap remains, means that India will at
some point swap places with China in accession to
the number one GDP spot. Currently, by 2030, India
is projected to be the world’s third largest economy.
Unlike China, India is a democracy—the world’s
largest in fact—suggesting, potentially, greater longterm political stability. English is widely (though not
universally) spoken in the country, a legacy of the
British Empire heritage and an advantage as English
remains the lingua franca of world business. India also
has the second-largest population in the world, at
1.3 billion, still behind China, but only just.
There is also much to be done in terms of lessening
the bureaucratic obstacles to establishing and running
businesses in the country and dealing with relatively high
levels of public and private corruption. Since 1991 India
has embarked on a program of economic liberalisation
and deregulation that has made the nation more attractive
to Australian and other international trade and investment.
But such changes are not always easy to accomplish in a
democracy where every economic group has its say, and
where such changes can exacerbate social issues (such
as economic inequality) if not implemented in the right
way. Progress is being made, but it is not assured.
Still, the prospects for Australian business in India are
overall bullish. Demand for Australian minerals should
grow as the country makes investments to close its
significant infrastructure needs (perhaps just in time to
make up for lowered demand from China as it closes its
own gaps in that area). Education is currently Australia’s
second-largest export to India and rising incomes
should increase demand there as well, building on an
already established base. India is now a major tourist
destination for Australians (and vice versa) and should
grow with rising development and income levels. If
most Indians get lifted out of poverty, the demands of
1.3 billion consumers could be very attractive indeed.
The next 20 years are almost certainly China’s, but
India could well own the 20 years after that.
Cameron Gordon
Australian National University
SOURCES: ‘Market profile’, Australian Government: Australian Trade and Investment Commission accessed via www.austrade.gov.au/Australian/Export/
Export-markets/Countries/India/Market-profile; ‘India country brief’, Australian Government: Department of Foreign Affairs and Trade accessed via
https://dfat.gov.au/geo/india/Pages/india-country-brief.aspx; ‘India’, 2019 Index of Economic Freedom accessed via www.heritage.org/index/country/
india; ‘India’s poverty profile’, The World Bank, 25 May 2016 accessed via www.worldbank.org/en/news/infographic/2016/05/27/india-s-poverty-profile.
CHAPTER 2
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 81
THEORIES OF TRADE, INVESTMENT AND INTERNATIONALISATION
81
08/06/19 07:41 PM
Thus far, we have not differentiated among different types of international trade. Implicit
in our discussion is trade of one type—inter-industry trade—trade between industries across
national borders. Australia exports resources-based commodities and agricultural products,
while importing sophisticated manufactures. Japan exports sophisticated manufactures
and imports resources-based commodities and agricultural products. There are other types
of international trade, such as intra-industry trade, which is trade between countries in
the same industry categories—European countries import cars from Japan while Japan
imports cars from European countries. There is also intra-company trade—trade within the
same company—such as trade between subsidiaries of a multinational corporation. Most
manufacturing multinational corporations have subsidiaries in different countries that
produce different components for final assembly elsewhere into final products. This is to
say that there are several types of international trade, and when explaining patterns of
international trade we need to be mindful that a particular type of international trade is
better explained by one or another of the explanations introduced here.
The trade theories and some of the newer theories, such as Vernon’s PLC theory, do
contribute to some understanding of why individual companies engage in international
trade into markets across national borders. However, in general, trade theories have
limitations in explaining the motivations and behavioural patterns of individual companies
that, after all, are the entities actually doing most of the trading. Patterns of international
trade are attributed to countries.
Companies engage in international business through various means of exchange
across national borders. International trade is one such means, and if international trade is
the only involvement, the company remains ‘at home’ and exports and/or imports from
there. We will see later that this is a low-commitment mode of international business.
If the company chooses to invest abroad, possibly by establishing a physical presence in
another country, we label this foreign direct investment (FDI). This could be in the form
of establishing a manufacturing operation in another country or by acquiring a foreign
company. This is a high commitment mode of international business. We now introduce
foreign direct investment.
LO 2.3
FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT
IN THE WORLD ECONOMY
In this section we introduce FDI and some explanations of FDI. At the outset, there
are some fundamentals we need to understand. FDI must not be confused with foreign
portfolio investment (FPI). FPI occurs when a local company takes up an interest in
financial instruments abroad (e.g. foreign corporate shareholdings, government bonds). This
is not our interest here. Our interest is exclusively with FDI, a local company investing
in physical facilities abroad, either through establishing physical operations itself or by
acquiring an enterprise abroad. In addition, to explain why companies invest in physical
facilities abroad, it is important to establish some context to this activity.
It is useful to conceive of FDI as companies operating in markets, and the two
fundamental institutions in this system are the company and the market. Pure
theory posits a perfect market with no physical space or time, no institutions and no
imperfections, the result being that buyers and sellers only pay direct costs of making
and/or purchasing the product. In other words, there are no additional transaction costs.
Of course, real markets are not pure in the theoretical sense. Globalisation is all about
transacting across physical space and there are transport costs to be borne on top of the
costs of the product or service being traded. Trades between buyers and sellers often
require contracts and there are thus contract costs arising from legal institutions and
82
PART 2
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 82
08/06/19 07:41 PM
requirements. There are also market imperfections such as government intervention via
tariffs and subsidies, and asymmetries in information access (where all information relevant
to the exchange is not readily available to buyers and sellers). There are always some
transaction costs and market imperfections, even in markets that function well. The bottom
line is that real markets will never be perfectly efficient (i.e. devoid of transaction costs).
This is where FDI comes in. Companies can remain ‘at home’ and export into markets
overseas, importing components and the like from other countries to assemble final products
at home, which are then sold abroad. This is the international trade we discussed earlier.
When companies choose to engage in actual investment abroad—for example, building
an overseas plant to produce and sell to the local market there—different explanations
are needed, and these explanations relate to the nature of markets and the extent of
imperfections in these markets both at home and abroad. If markets were ‘perfect’, there
would be no incentive for a company engaging in international business to do otherwise
than to remain at home and export and/or import. This is the least costly and risky way
for a company to do international business. But international business is complex, costly
and risky, because of market imperfections and transaction costs. Hence, there must be
compelling reasons for companies to engage in FDI. We now consider some of these reasons.
We approach FDI from three complementary perspectives. One is to explain why a
company will favour FDI as a means of entering a foreign market when alternatives are
possible. Another is to explain why companies in the same industry often undertake FDI at
the same time, and why certain locations are favoured over others as targets for FDI. Here
the interest is to explain the observed pattern of FDI flows. A third perspective combines
these other two perspectives into one holistic explanation, and this addresses important
questions that all companies must consider when undertaking international business.
Having decided to do international business, the company must ask itself which countries
(markets) will it enter, and via what mode of operation will it enter these markets?
Why foreign direct investment?
As mentioned above, companies have various possibilities besides FDI available to them
for exploiting the profit opportunities in a foreign market. Two of these possibilities are
exporting and licensing. As we have seen, exporting involves producing goods at home
and then transporting them to the receiving country for sale. Licensing, on the other
hand, involves granting a foreign company (the licensee) the right to produce and sell
our company’s product in return for a royalty fee on every unit the licensee sells. Clearly,
FDI may be both expensive and risky when compared to exporting and licensing. FDI is
expensive because the company must bear the costs of establishing facilities in a foreign
country or of acquiring a foreign enterprise. FDI is risky because the company is putting
its own capital at risk in a country where the ‘rules of the game’ may be very different.
Relative to local companies, a foreign company undertaking FDI in another country incurs
a ‘liability of foreignness’. When a company exports, it need not bear the costs associated
with FDI, and the risks associated with selling abroad can be reduced by using a local sales
agent. Similarly, when a licensor allows a licensee to produce its products under licence, it
need not bear the costs or risks of FDI, since these are borne by the licensee. So, why do
companies choose FDI over either exporting or licensing?
There are a number of reasons for companies to invest abroad. These include direct
access to new markets and to directly acquire resources not available at home. In addition,
companies seek improved efficiency by relocating operations to countries that offer costrelated advantages, investment incentives, or science and industrial parks which encourage
knowledge transfer among like-minded companies. Companies also invest abroad in order
CHAPTER 2
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 83
EXPORTING
Sale of products produced in one
country into another country
LICENSING
Occurs when a firm (the licensor)
licenses the right to produce
its product, use its production
processes, or use its brand name
or trademark to another firm (the
licensee). In return for giving the
licensee these rights, the licensor
collects a royalty fee on every unit
the licensee sells
THEORIES OF TRADE, INVESTMENT AND INTERNATIONALISATION
83
08/06/19 07:41 PM
to seek strategic assets by investing in local companies to gain access to distribution
networks and local knowledge, and other ownership advantages.31 In all, companies
investing abroad are market-seeking, resources-seeking, efficiency-seeking or strategic ­
asset-seeking in the real world where there are various barriers that exporting alone may
not be able to overcome.
Limitations of exporting Exporting can be constrained by transport costs (a natural
market imperfection) and trade barriers (a human-made market imperfection). Clearly,
costs of transporting production inputs or outputs generally accumulate as distances
covered increase, and past a certain point the final cost to a buyer might make the sale
unviable. This is particularly so for products that have a low value-to-weight ratio and
can be produced in almost any location (e.g. cement, soft drinks and beer). For these
products, relative to either FDI or licensing, exporting is unattractive. For products with a
high value-to-weight ratio, however, transport costs might be a minor component of total
landed cost (e.g. electronic components, personal computers, medical equipment, computer
software and commercial aircraft) and have little impact on the relative attractiveness of
exporting, licensing and FDI.
Transport costs aside, some FDI is undertaken as a response to actual or threatened
trade barriers such as import tariffs or quotas. By placing tariffs on imported goods,
governments can increase the cost of exporting relative to FDI and licensing. Similarly,
by limiting imports through quotas, governments increase the attractiveness of FDI and
licensing. For example, the wave of FDI by Japanese car companies in the United States
during the 1980s and 1990s was partly driven by protectionist threats from the US
Congress and by quotas on the importation of Japanese cars. For Japanese car companies,
these factors decreased the profitability of exporting and increased that of FDI. Trade
barriers do not have to be physically in place for FDI to be favoured over exporting. Often,
the desire to reduce the ‘threat’ that trade barriers might be imposed is enough to justify
FDI as an alternative to exporting. The drama of Brexit is an example of how unforeseen
events can suddenly alter business environments. In this case some companies are
considering FDI within the EU to limit the business consequences of the United Kingdom
suddenly losing its preferential trading arrangements with Europe.
Limitations of licensing Licensing has three major drawbacks as a strategy for exploiting
foreign market opportunities and these have mainly to do with another real-world factor not
present in pure theory; namely, the fact that the knowledge and assets that a company owns
often are not easily transferable from one use or party to another and/or not easily controlled
if a transfer is made. Since such a transfer is what happens under licensing, it is useful to
outline the three main ways these complications can interfere with its effectiveness.
First, licensing may result in a company giving away valuable technological know-how
to a potential foreign competitor. For example, in the 1960s, US company RCA licensed its
leading-edge colour television technology to a number of Japanese companies, including
Matsushita and Sony. At the time, RCA saw licensing as a way to earn a return from its
technological know-how in the Japanese market without the costs and risks associated
with FDI. However, Matsushita and Sony quickly assimilated RCA’s technology and used
it to enter the US market to compete directly against RCA. In 1986, the company was
disbanded; the RCA brand was acquired by the French company Thompson. In addition,
many e­ x-RCA employees were hired by Sony.32
A second problem with licensing is loss of control over manufacturing, marketing
and strategy in a foreign country. For both strategic and operational reasons, a company
may want to retain control over these functions. The rationale for wanting control over
the strategy of a foreign entity is that a company might want its foreign subsidiary to
84
PART 2
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 84
08/06/19 07:41 PM
price and market very aggressively as a way of keeping a foreign competitor in check. US
company Kodak pursued this strategy in Japan a couple of decades ago. The competitive
attacks launched by Kodak’s Japanese subsidiary kept its major global competitor, Fuji, busy
defending its competitive position in Japan, causing it to pull back from its earlier strategy
of confronting Kodak aggressively in the United States. (Changes in the way pictures are
taken and distributed have since made Kodak a shell of its former self and have radically
altered the nature of Fuji’s business as well. But such is life in the dynamic world of
international business.)
The use of FDI in the form of a wholly owned subsidiary allows the pursuit of
aggressive and pre-emptive (if also high-risk) moves, if judged to be in the company’s best
interest. A licensee would be unlikely to accept such an imposition, as such a strategy
implies the licensee could be compelled to accept a lowered profit, or might even have
to take a loss. In addition, the international company might wish to take advantage of
differences in factor costs across countries, producing only part of its final product in a
given country, while importing other parts from elsewhere where they can be produced
at lower cost. The internationalisation of production is discussed later, but for the
present, licensing may not be the best option when the companies can leverage factor
cost differentials across countries. Again, a licensee would be unlikely to accept such an
arrangement, since it would limit the licensee’s autonomy. Hence, for these reasons, when
control over a foreign operation is desirable, FDI is preferable to licensing.
A third problem with licensing arises when the company’s competitive advantage is
based not so much on its products but on the management, marketing and manufacturing
capabilities that produce those products. These capabilities often are not amenable to
licensing; that is, they cannot be codified and contracts written to replicate them by
a licensee overseas. While a foreign licensee physically may be able to reproduce the
company’s product under licence, it often may not be able to do so as efficiently as the
company could itself. As a result, the licensee may not be able to fully exploit the profit
potential inherent in a foreign market. For example, consider Toyota, a company whose
competitive advantage in the global car industry is acknowledged to be its superior ability
to manage the overall value chain of designing, engineering, manufacturing and selling
vehicles; that is, its management and organisational capabilities. Indeed, Toyota is credited
with pioneering the development of a new production process, known as lean production,
which enables it to produce higher quality cars at a lower cost than its global rivals.33
Although Toyota has certain products that could be licensed, its real competitive advantage
comes from its management and process capabilities. These kinds of skills are difficult to
codify. They cannot be written into a licensing contract.
Within the particular company, these capabilities are organisation-wide and have been
developed over a long time. They are not embodied in any one individual, but instead
are widely dispersed throughout the organisation. Toyota’s skills are embedded in its
organisational culture, and culture cannot be licensed. If Toyota were to allow a foreign
entity to produce its cars under licence, the entity would be unlikely to do so as efficiently
as does Toyota. In turn, this would limit the ability of the foreign entity to fully develop the
market potential of that product. This reasoning underlies Toyota’s preference for FDI abroad
as opposed to permitting foreign car manufacturers to produce its cars under licence.
FDI is thus more profitable than licensing when one or more of the following
conditions holds: (1) when the company has valuable know-how that cannot be adequately
protected by a licensing contract; (2) when the company needs tight control over a
foreign entity to maximise its market share and earnings in that country; and (3) when a
company’s skills and know-how are not amenable to licensing. A company will favour FDI
over exporting and licensing when market imperfections and transaction costs are higher
rather than lower.
CHAPTER 2
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 85
THEORIES OF TRADE, INVESTMENT AND INTERNATIONALISATION
85
08/06/19 07:41 PM
The pattern of foreign direct investment
It is often observed in some sectors that companies in the same industry undertake FDI at
about the same time as do their rivals. Retail banking is one such sector. In Australian retail
banking, the four major banks seek to increase market share by entering foreign markets,
and they consistently mimic one another’s behaviour in this respect. The announcement by
one of the Australian banking majors that it is entering retail banking in a country overseas
is generally followed in due course by another’s similar announcement. This is a pattern
that goes back decades; for example, when Australian banks opened their first US branches
over the course of a few short years in the late 1960s and early 1970s (and following a
similar clustering of opening London branches in the late 1950s).34 There is also a clear
tendency for companies to direct their investment activities towards particular locations.
We offer two explanations now that explain these patterns observed in FDI flows.
Strategic behaviour
OLIGOPOLY
An industry composed of a
limited number of large firms all
of whom recognise their mutual
interdependence
MULTIPOINT COMPETITION
Arises when two or more firms
encounter each other in different
regional markets, national markets
or industries
LO 2.3
One explanation of this FDI pattern of imitative behaviour is based on the idea that
FDI flows are a manifestation of strategic rivalry between international companies in
the global marketplace. An early exponent was F.T. Knickerbocker, who studied the
relationship between FDI and rivalry in oligopolistic industries.35 An oligopoly is an
industry composed of a limited number of large companies all of which recognise their
interdependence: what one company does has an immediate impact on major competitors,
eliciting a retaliatory response. Thus, if one company in an oligopoly lowers prices, this can
cut into rivals’ market share, forcing them to respond with similar price cuts to retain their
market share. Such imitative behaviour can take many forms in an oligopoly. Building on
this, Knickerbocker argued that the same kind of imitative behaviour characterises FDI.
Studies of US companies during the 1950s and 1960s that investigated FDI show that
companies based in oligopolistic industries tended to imitate each other’s FDI.36 The same
phenomenon has been observed with regard to FDI undertaken by Japanese companies
during the 1980s.37 For example, Toyota and Nissan responded to investments by Honda
in the United States and Europe by undertaking their own FDI in the United States and
Europe. More recently, research has shown that models of strategic behaviour in a global
oligopoly can explain the pattern of FDI in the global tyre industry.38
Knickerbocker’s theory can be extended to embrace the concept of multipoint
competition. Multipoint competition arises when two or more companies encounter
each other in different regional markets, national markets or industries. Economic theory
suggests that like chess players jockeying for advantage, companies will try to match the
moves of each other in different markets to try to hold one another in check. The strategy
is to ensure that a rival does not gain a commanding position in one market and then use
the profits generated there to subsidise competitive attacks in other markets. The online
retail business is a good example of this. A few large international and major regional
players contest major markets one by one, hoping to establish a first-mover advantage and
an unbeatable competitive position. For example, Amazon, Alibaba and Walmart are now
competing for dominance in the Indian retail space, repeating earlier and ongoing battles in
other national markets.39
The eclectic paradigm
Internalisation theory
Internalisation theory explains why companies often prefer FDI over licensing as a
strategy for entering foreign markets.40 According to internalisation theory, when market
imperfections make market-based transactions less efficient, a company is likely to
undertake FDI. The company ‘internalises’ what otherwise would have been ‘externalised’
86
PART 2
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 86
08/06/19 07:41 PM
market-based transactions. The transaction costs incurred in using the market are too
costly and the company making the exchange will internalise these costly exchanges
into the organisational form of the company—it brings the costly exchange into the
company to minimise or avoid these costs. As such, and attributed to Ronald Coase in
1937, internalisation theory provides a cogent explanation of why companies exist, and in
international business, it provides the strongest explanation of the nature and form of the
multinational corporation. This theorising was pioneered in international business by Peter
Buckley and Mark Casson (1976), Jean-Francois Hennart (1982) and Alan Rugman (1986).
All of the explanations introduced above have made important but partial contributions
to understanding the determinants of FDI. John Dunning, appointed to the Order of
the British Empire (OBE) in 2008, championed his eclectic paradigm,41 arguing that in
addition to ownership advantages that are company-specific and render some companies
more competitive than others, there are internalisation and location-specific advantages.
Internalisation advantages, the advantages of particular modes of operation in particular
circumstances of market imperfections, and location-specific advantages, the attributes
of one location over another, are also critical in explaining both the rationale for and the
direction of FDI. By location-specific advantages, Dunning refers to advantages that arise
from using resource endowments or assets that are tied to a particular foreign location and
that a company finds valuable to combine with its own unique company-specific assets,
such as the company’s technological, marketing or management capabilities.
Dunning accepts the argument of internalisation theory that it can be difficult for
a company to license its own unique capabilities and know-how; that is, its ownership
advantages. Therefore, he argues that combining location-specific assets or resource
endowments and the company’s own unique capabilities often requires FDI. This requires
the company to establish production facilities where those foreign assets or resource
endowments are located as they are location-bounded. This paradigm has been labelled
Dunning’s O-L-I paradigm, and it addresses explicitly two core questions that all companies
doing international business must consider. Having decided to do international business, for
whatever reason, where will the company engage overseas, and by what mode of operation
will the company engage overseas? The company will leverage on its O, its ownership
advantage, in a particular L, location, which offers it advantage in deriving the highest
returns to its O. It will choose a mode of operation which best permits efficiency given
the nature and extent of market imperfections in this location. This latter, I, addresses the
internalisation-specific attributes of the different modes of operation, which we have earlier
briefly introduced.
An obvious example of Dunning’s location arguments is natural resources, such as oil
and other minerals, which are by their character specific to certain locations. However,
Dunning’s framework has implications that go beyond basic resources such as minerals and
labour. Incentive schemes to attract FDI including the establishment of free trade zones,
or the existence of clusters such as Silicon Valley in the United States and Bangalore in
India, provide locational advantages. Consider Silicon Valley, which is the world centre
for the computer and semiconductor industry. Many of the world’s major computer and
semiconductor companies, such as Apple Computer, Hewlett–Packard and Intel, are located
close to each other in the Silicon Valley region. As a result, much of the cutting-edge
research and product development in computers and semiconductors occurs here. (Note
that this dynamic also mirrors an aspect of Porter’s diamond theory.)
According to Dunning’s arguments, knowledge is being generated in Silicon Valley
with regard to the design and manufacture of computers and semiconductors that is
available nowhere else in the world. As it is commercialised, that knowledge diffuses
throughout the world, but the leading edge of knowledge generation in the computer
and semiconductor industries is to be found in Silicon Valley. In Dunning’s language, this
CHAPTER 2
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 87
INTERNALISATION THEORY
Market imperfection approach to
explaining foreign direct investment
ECLECTIC PARADIGM
A framework, also known as
ownership, location, internalisation
(OLI), developed by John Dunning
to determine conditions suitable
for a firm to pursue foreign direct
investment (FDI)
INTERNALISATION ADVANTAGES
Factors associated with
imperfections in the market,
and the firm deciding to keep
the production of a good or
service within the firm rather than
externalising it to other firms
LOCATION-SPECIFIC ADVANTAGES
Advantages that arise from using
resource endowments or assets
that are tied to a particular foreign
location and that the firm finds
valuable to combine with its own
unique ownership-specific attributes
OWNERSHIP ADVANTAGES
Advantages that arise from the
accumulation of intangible assets,
technological capacities or
innovations that are specific to the
particular firm
CLUSTERS
Geographic concentrations of
interconnected firms and institutions
in a particular industry
THEORIES OF TRADE, INVESTMENT AND INTERNATIONALISATION
87
08/06/19 07:41 PM
© Phillip Bond/Alamy Stock Photo
Silicon Valley, where Google is based (as well as other major
US tech firms such as Facebook), has long been known as
the epicentre of the computer and semiconductor industry.
LO 2.3
EXTERNALITIES
Spillovers which occur when a firm is
impacted by an event and does not
choose to incur that benefit or cost.
The firm’s interests are not taken
into account when the event occurs.
They can be positive or negative
88
PART 2
means that Silicon Valley has a location-specific advantage
in the generation of knowledge related to the computer and
semiconductor industries. In part, this advantage comes from
the sheer concentration of intellectual talent in this area,
and in part it arises from a network of informal contacts that
allows companies to benefit from each other’s knowledgegeneration activities. These knowledge spillovers generate
externalities which enable interested companies that
locate nearby to internalise where possible these positive
spillovers.42 Companies learn from one another. It makes
sense for foreign computer and semiconductor companies
to invest in research and (perhaps) production facilities so
they too can learn about and use valuable new knowledge
before those based elsewhere can, thereby giving them a
competitive advantage in the global marketplace.43
INTERNATIONALISATION OF THE COMPANY
In the previous section, explanations of FDI were introduced. In general, FDI is undertaken
by large multinational companies (MNCs), although this is not always the case as smaller
companies can also invest abroad. Technico Pty Ltd, an innovative Australian small seedpotato company, chose to establish a complete manufacturing facility in Yanglin, Yunnan
Province, China, early in the company’s life-cycle as part of its internationalisation strategy
to take its seed potatoes to the world. Nonetheless, smaller companies more often use
market-based modes of operating in international markets. That is, as we have seen, they
can externalise their exchanges into companies in international markets, rather than
internalising them within the organisational structure of their own company. They
contract with other companies for some activities rather than undertaking these activities
themselves. As such, they export or license, given the three possibilities we have thus
far introduced. These are less risky and costly than is FDI, and hence are more attractive
international possibilities. The majority of Australian and New Zealand companies are small
to medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) and much business activity in these and other countries
is conducted by small companies. While there is no universal definition of an SME, in
Australia a small business is defined as a company employing between five and 20 people,
and a medium business is one that employs more than 20 but fewer than 200 people.44
Over the last four decades, a number of models have emerged to explain how companies
develop from operating in domestic markets exclusively to operating in international markets
(referred to in the literature as the internationalisation process of the company). It has also
been found that exporting is the most common form of initial international market entry
mode,45 and these models have attempted to explain the process involved in beginning to
export and progressing beyond export. In addition, exporting is a mode of internationalisation
often favoured by governments, given the benefits that accrue to an economy from foreign
currency earnings through export, and the employment benefits of keeping operations at
home. SMEs are very significant employers and new SMEs particularly so.
Since the 1960s, the internationalisation process of companies has been an
attractive research domain. Scholars such as Jan Johanson and Finn Wiedersheim-Paul,46
S. Tamer Cavusgil47 and Michael Czinkota48 among others have conceptualised the
internationalisation process of the company as an incremental process, with companies at a
similar stage of development in their internationalisation exhibiting similar characteristics
in their export behaviour.49 Unfortunately, like the FDI theories, at present there is no
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 88
08/06/19 07:41 PM
single widely accepted internationalisation process model. However, two schools of thought
have emerged in the literature to explain internationalisation processes. Otto Andersen has
categorised these as the Uppsala internationalisation process models (U-models) and the
Innovation-related internationalisation models (I-models).50
The Uppsala models (U-models)
The U-models were pioneered by researchers in Sweden. Johanson and Wiedersheim-Paul,51
supported by evidence from a case study of just four Swedish manufacturing companies,
identified four different stages of entering an international market, where each successive
stage represents a greater degree of commitment to internationalisation:
•
Stage 1—no regular export activity
•
Stage 2—export via independent representatives (agents)
•
Stage 3—establishment of an overseas sales subsidiary
•
Stage 4—overseas production/manufacturing units.
The framework was further developed by Jan Johanson and Jan-Erik Vahlne.52 To explain
the incremental nature of internationalisation, they formulated a dynamic model in which
the outcome of one cycle is the input to the next cycle. The model structure is given
by the distinction between the state and change aspects of internationalisation. The basic
PSYCHIC DISTANCE
idea of this model is that internationalisation begins with increased knowledge of foreign
Factors impeding the flow of
markets which then triggers increased actual commitment of resources on the ground in
information between the firm and an
those markets, with a reinforcing feedback loop between knowledge and commitment
international market
ongoing after that (see Figure 2.6).
The Uppsala models are explicitly staged in that companies incrementally increase
progressive involvement in their international markets as they experientially learn by
carrying out operations in foreign markets. Reducing risk through experiential learning,
Uppsala-type companies expand their international operations by progressively increasing
their commitment and by extending gradually into markets that are dissimilar to the home
FIGURE 2.6
market. In the Uppsala models, their increasing commitment through higher involvement
The theoretical and operational level
modes is referred to as the ‘establishment chain postulate’ and the behaviour of gradually
of the knowledge and foreign market
extending in dissimilar markets is referred to as the
commitment development U-model
‘psychic distance postulate’. According to Daniel Sullivan
Operational level
and Alan Bauerschmidt, ‘the internationalization of the
firm is an incremental process owing to the progressive
Overseas market location
Operational steps for overseas
reduction of psychic distance through managers’ gradual
choices
commitment levels
accumulation of knowledge of foreign markets’.53
The Uppsala models are actually a conceptualisation
Initial entry into low-distance
that is represented by two underlying models, a theoretical
1. No/few exports
markets (close geographical,
model and an operational (empirical) model. Figure 2.6
cultural and/or ‘psychic’ distance
provides a comparison of the theoretical and operational
from home country)
levels of the model. As can be seen, the relationship
2. Indirect exports
(via third parties)
between the concepts of the theoretical model and
linkages between the theoretical and the operational level
are somewhat vague, making it difficult to test the model.
3. FDI—overseas sales
The tests that have been carried out have produced mixed
operations
results.54 Researchers such as Yung-Chul Kwon and Michael
Hu55 have found support for the evolutionary path, but
Expansion (if successful)
Andrew Millington and Brian Bayliss56 have not. There
4. FDI–production
into more distant markets
have been other criticisms of the model, such as its inability
CHAPTER 2
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 89
THEORIES OF TRADE, INVESTMENT AND INTERNATIONALISATION
89
08/06/19 07:41 PM
to explain the international behaviours of a cadre of companies that do not begin operations
in their home market before internationalising. These companies have become known as ‘born
globals’.57 (The ‘born global’ aspect of companies will be discussed in the next section.)
Overall, U-model researchers have made a significant contribution towards our
understanding of the internationalisation process and have influenced much of the subsequent
empirical research. They have highlighted the importance of knowledge in export market
development. In their revised model, Johanson and Vahlne58 also recognised the importance of
networks to small companies and also to larger ones, and opportunity seeking in international
markets. Even more recently, they have extended their internationalisation process model to
become a globalisation model, and in 2017 Vahlne and Johanson published another version as
an evolutionary model of their so-called modern multinational business enterprise.59
The Innovation-related models (I-models)
The body of research referred to as I-models60 encompasses a number of studies61 that
differ from the U-models in that they view exporting as an innovation in the company as
it changes the company in a fundamental way. Proponents of this approach have relied on
the application of Rogers’62 theory of innovation diffusion to explain the export behaviour
of companies. Rogers’ theory is widely accepted in other fields of study such as consumer
behaviour.63 The basic premise common to these models is that the internationalisation
process is a series of innovations for the company, particularly managerial innovations.64
The focus of these models is primarily on the export development process of SMEs.65
When management decides that own export is too demanding, they might appoint a
sales agent in a foreign market. As such, they implicitly give up some control of their
international expansion aspirations, relying on this agent to undertake all of the company’s
international marketing activities in this foreign market. This is viewed as a managerial
innovation and if continued might foreshadow progressive and gradual foreign market
expansion with deepening involvement of independent agents overseas.
There are several limitations identified in the literature that are common to both
the U-models and the I-models. Some researchers have criticised these models for being
too deterministic and of limited value in accounting for the idiosyncratic behaviours of
internationalising companies.66 This criticism has become centred on a number of studies
that have found that the conventional internationalisation theories do not adequately explain
the internationalisation of a cadre of companies, especially (but not exclusively) those small
companies in the high-tech fields that appear to be ‘born global’. These companies internationalise
very early in their life-cycles and they accelerate their subsequent international expansion.67 As
such, early development in home markets before the first internationalisation step, and gradual
expansion overseas as theorised by the Uppsala and Innovation-related models, is not observed.
LO 2.5
BORN GLOBAL
A firm that internationalises into
global markets soon after it is formed
90
PART 2
‘BORN GLOBAL’ COMPANIES
Various terms have been used to describe companies that internationalise early in their
life-cycles and accelerate subsequent international expansion activity. These include ‘early
internationalisers’, ‘global start-ups’, ‘international new ventures’ (INVs)68 and ‘born globals’.69
In this chapter we will adopt the last term, ‘born globals’, as this label is becoming
prevalent in the literature. Unfortunately, there is no consensus within the literature as to
what constitutes a born global company. However, it is generally taken that INVs emerge
from existing companies, whereas born globals are new companies that internationalise
soon after the company is formed. We will focus on the so-called born globals.
Researchers from around the world have reported that high-tech (mostly, but not
exclusively) companies that have internationalised rapidly are becoming more common
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 90
08/06/19 07:41 PM
and are emerging from many countries. This is now a worldwide phenomenon, and lowertech companies are also being born global. However, we need to be careful, as the term
‘born global’ is not an accurate descriptor, as few of these companies are actually born
global. They do not generally enter global markets from inception. More accurately, these
companies are born internationally. Nonetheless, there are many, many new companies from
many countries that are entering markets overseas soon after the company is formed and
they are continuing with entry in new markets more rapidly than predicted by the gradual
internationalisation of the Uppsala and Innovation-related models.
Gary Knight and S. Tamer Cavusgil70 conducted a number of case studies in Australia
to develop profiles of some emerging exporters. Even back when they did the study a
couple of decades ago, they found a breed of exporting companies that did not match
the profile of traditional exporters. An example they cited was ANCA, a manufacturer of
CNC tool grinders and controls, which exported 85 per cent of its products within five
years of its founding. This business attributed its success to its leading-edge technology,
unique product and international vision, backed up by resource commitment. Trends like
this have continued. An Austrade survey in 2017, defining ‘born global’ as ‘firms that have
earned international revenue within two years of starting operations’, found an increasing
proportion of companies meeting this criteria between 2000 and 2017, with the proportion
of companies considered to be born global between 2010 and 2017 a good deal larger
compared with the previous three decades.71
Similar trends have been found in other regions too. Jim Bell conducted a comparative
study into the export behaviour and internationalisation of small computer software
companies in Finland, Ireland and Norway. The findings of this study challenged many of
the underlying assumptions of conventional internationalisation ‘stage’ theories (namely,
the incremental sequential process), leading to the conclusion that such theories do not
adequately reflect the internationalisation process among small computer software companies.
AMC/McKinsey72 in Australia examined exports by manufacturers in the areas of
emerging high value-added and elaborately transformed manufactures. This study found
a trend that companies in this sector tend to be born global. The study also found that
these successful exporters are generally companies in which top management has a desire
and commitment to export, compete on value, and also have a strong market orientation.
Based on their own research and that of AMC/McKinsey,73 Knight and Cavusgil concluded
that small companies have inherent advantages in terms of response time, flexibility and
adaptability, all of which facilitate their internationalisation efforts. They also concluded
that ‘gradual internationalization is dead’, at least for value-added exporters, and that rapid
internationalisation is feasible and even desirable. However, we should not take this statement
as a definitive conclusion, as many companies will remain gradual internationalisers.
Nonetheless, in certain instances, some companies will ‘leapfrog’ into internationalisation
rather than moving cautiously through a series of incremental steps, as suggested by the
‘stage’ theories.74 Another reason for rapid internationalisation includes shorter product lifecycles in some industries, especially in high-tech industries, the reduction in trade barriers
and the ease of communicating and transacting across national borders.
Some interesting companies in this cadre are reported in the publication Born to be
Global: A Closer Look at the International Venturing of Australian Born Global Firms.75 The
companies studied present a cross-section of early internationalising Australian companies
from different industry sectors. Other more widely recognised companies include Logitech,
a Switzerland-based producer of aids for personal computers (see the Closing Case), and
Cochlear, an Australian company producing implants for people with deafness and deriving
more than 95 per cent of its income from exports. The Department of Foreign Affairs and
Trade identified a number of companies that have internationalised using the internet.
Yahoo is another company that was born global, relying on the internet.
CHAPTER 2
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 91
TEST PREP
Preparing for a test?
Use LearnSmart to
help you remember
what you’ve learned.
THEORIES OF TRADE, INVESTMENT AND INTERNATIONALISATION
91
08/06/19 07:41 PM
FOCUS ON
MANAGERIAL IMPLICATIONS
Why does all this matter for
international business? There
are several implications for international businesses.
These include: (1) international business as exchange
across borders; (2) FDI as an option; (3) location as core
to international business; (4) first-mover advantages;
(5) internationalisation of the company; and (6) policy
implications.
LO 2.6
INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS AS
EXCHANGE ACROSS BORDERS
Companies can choose to remain ‘at home’ and cater
to their domestic markets exclusively. This may be the
best strategy for some companies that do not have
something special to take to the world—Dunning’s
O—an ownership-specific advantage. For a company
to engage in international business, and to market
goods or services in markets overseas, it must have
something special as the competition in these markets
will be intense, and the company will confront a
liability of foreignness in overseas markets. Having
taken a decision to do international business, there
are choices to be made. First, where to go—which
overseas market to enter? Second, how to enter that
market—which mode of operation to choose? Here we
have introduced just three modes—exporting, licensing
and FDI. More will be said of these modes later in this
book. At this point, we recognise that all markets have
varying degrees of imperfections, human-made and
natural, and the choice of mode will depend on the
nature and extent of these market imperfections—the
more imperfect the market, the more internalised will
be the exchange. However, we also recognise that the
more internalised the mode, the more costly will be the
foreign operation, and the more risks the company will
have to accommodate.
FDI AS AN OPTION
The implications of FDI theory for international
business practice are several. First, it is worth noting
that the location-specific advantages argument
associated with John Dunning helps to explain the
92
PART 2
direction of FDI flows. However, the location-specific
advantages argument does not explain why companies
prefer FDI, an internalised mode of operation, to the
market-based modes of licensing or exporting. In
this regard, from both explanatory and international
business perspectives, a useful explanation is that
which focuses on the limitations of exporting and
licensing. This explanation is useful because it
identifies precisely how the relative attractiveness
of FDI, exporting and licensing varies with different
circumstances. Exporting is preferable to licensing
and FDI when transport costs and trade barriers are
few and low. As transport costs and trade barriers
increase, exporting becomes less attractive, and the
choice is between FDI and licensing. Because FDI is
more costly and more risky than licensing, all other
things being equal, licensing is preferable to FDI. Other
things are seldom equal, however, and licensing is
not an attractive option in the following conditions: (a)
the company has valuable know-how that cannot be
adequately protected by a licensing contract; (b) the
company needs tight control over a foreign entity in
order to maximise its market share and earnings in that
country; and (c) the company’s skills and capabilities
are not amenable to licensing.
LOCATION AS CORE TO
INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS
Underlying most of the explanations we have
discussed is the notion that different countries have
particular advantages in different productive activities.
That is, different countries have particular locationspecific advantages. It makes sense for a company
to disperse its need for productive capabilities to
those countries where particular activities can be
performed most efficiently. If design can be performed
most efficiently in Finland, then that is where design
facilities should be located; if the manufacture of basic
components can be performed most efficiently in
China, then that is where they should be manufactured;
and if final assembly can be performed most efficiently
in Singapore, then that is where final assembly should
be performed. The company might be headquartered
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 92
08/06/19 07:41 PM
in New Zealand or Australia. The result is a global
web of productive enterprise, with different activities
being performed in different locations around the
globe, depending on considerations of comparative
advantage, factor endowments and other aspects of
trade and investment. As such, international business
for the company is an evolving mix of international
trade, FDI, licensing and other modes of international
business operations, yet to be discussed. As Dunning’s
O-L-I paradigm outlines, location is fundamental to
international business.
FIRST-MOVER ADVANTAGES
According to new trade theory, companies that
establish a first-mover advantage in the production and
marketing of a new product may dominate global trade
in that product. This is particularly true in industries
where the global market can profitably support only a
limited number of companies, such as the aerospace
market. Early commitments also seem to be important
in less concentrated industries, such as the market
for mobile telephone equipment. For the individual
company, the message is that it pays to invest
substantial financial resources in building either a firstmover or early-mover advantage, even if that means
several years of losses before a new venture becomes
profitable. The intent is to pre-empt demand, gain cost
advantages related to volume, build an enduring brand
ahead of rivals and, consequently, establish a longterm sustainable competitive advantage. Although the
details of how to achieve this are beyond the scope
of this chapter, many publications offer strategies for
exploiting first-mover advantages, and for avoiding the
traps associated with pioneering a market (first-mover
disadvantages).76
INTERNATIONALISATION OF
THE COMPANY
There are several forms of international trade and no
one theory explains all forms of trade. Regardless of
the form of international trade, trade is initiated by
companies and much trade occurs between companies
or within companies across national borders. FDI is
also an option for companies in international markets.
While international trade is critical to a nation’s
standard of living and wellbeing, and is well explained
by longstanding existing theories, trade only occurs
CHAPTER 2
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 93
because companies choose to engage in international
business through internationalisation activities. With
modern technologies and forces interconnecting the
world more and more, companies large and small are
internationalising in ever-expanding numbers and
from all corners of the globe. While there are some
patterns to these internationalisation activities and
processes, and the search is for explanations of these
processes, there is much variation in companies’
internationalisation. Explanations of these processes
require that management within these companies be
understood, and as such, behavioural considerations
are vitally important. No one explanation of the
internationalisation process has achieved consensus.
This domain of international business is an attractive
research context.
POLICY IMPLICATIONS
International trade matters to international business
because companies are major players on the
international trade scene. International business
companies produce exports, and they import the
products of other countries either for final sale to
consumers or as components into their own production
processes. Because of their fundamental role in
international trade, companies can exert a strong
influence on government trade policy, lobbying to
promote free trade or trade restrictions. The theories
of international trade claim that promoting free trade is
generally in the best interests of a country, although it
may not always be in the best interests of an individual
company. Many companies recognise this and lobby
governments.
Porter’s theory of national competitive advantage also
contains policy implications. Porter suggests that it is
in the best interests of an economy that companies
invest in upgrading advanced factors of production; for
example, to invest in better training for its employees
and to increase its commitment to research and
development. It is also in the best interests of the
business community to lobby government to adopt
policies that have a favourable impact on each
component of the so-called national diamond. Thus,
according to Porter, companies should urge government
to increase investment in education, infrastructure
and basic research (since all these enhance advanced
factors), and to adopt policies that promote strong
competition within domestic markets (since this makes
companies stronger international competitors).
THEORIES OF TRADE, INVESTMENT AND INTERNATIONALISATION
93
08/06/19 07:41 PM
KEY TERMS
PAGE
61
absolute advantage
90
born global
87
clusters
60
comparative advantage
87
eclectic paradigm
73
economies of scale
83
exporting
88
74
59
87
87
83
87
59
externalities
first-mover advantages
free trade
internalisation advantages
internalisation theory
licensing
location-specific advantages
mercantilism
86
86
87
61
62
89
61
multipoint competition
oligopoly
ownership advantages
positive-sum game
production possibility frontier (PPF)
psychic distance
zero-sum game
SUMMARY
In this chapter, we recognise that international business involves international trade and foreign direct investment, and
other modes of operating overseas such as licensing. Large MNCs with operations in many countries will have a complex
mix of international trade and FDI strategically located so as to maximise their advantages to increase their revenue
and profits overall. Smaller companies that internationalise successfully are likely to begin by exporting and importing
but will likely deepen their internationalisation by moving to higher commitment modes of operation and extending into
more overseas markets. These patterns of internationalisation will differ depending on the companies’ strategies, country
differences and a host of other variables. We recognise that in our modern world economies today, increasing numbers of
companies, large and small, are internationalising as globalising forces are making the business world more interconnected.
While we understand that companies trade, a number of theories have been introduced that explain why it is beneficial
for a country to engage in international trade. These theories have explained the patterns of international trade observed
in the world economy. In addition, we have discussed some of the explanations of why companies undertake FDI, as
well as some recent theoretical developments in explaining the internationalisation process of SMEs. In this chapter, the
following points were made:
1. Mercantilists argued that it was in a country’s best
interests to persistently run trade surpluses, and to
persistently accumulate wealth acquired from other
countries. This theory holds that trade is a zero-sum
game, in which one country’s gains result in losses for
other countries. This philosophy has been proven to be
flawed, but neo-mercantilism remains a common view
held by some within our modern economies. Trade has
been proven to be a positive-sum game.
2. The theory of absolute advantage suggests that
countries differ in their ability to produce goods
efficiently. The theory suggests that a country should
specialise in producing goods for which it has an
absolute advantage in productivity over all other
countries and import goods from other countries which
have absolute advantages in their particular goods.
3. What happens if one country has an absolute advantage
in producing all goods? The theory of comparative
advantage suggests that it makes sense for a country to
specialise in producing those goods that it can produce
most efficiently relative to others it produces, while
importing goods that it produces relatively less efficiently
from other countries, even if that means importing goods
it could have produced more efficiently itself.
4. The Heckscher–Ohlin theory argues that the pattern
of international trade is determined by differences in
94
PART 2
factor endowments. It predicts that countries will export
those goods that make intensive use of their relatively
abundant factors and they will import goods that make
intensive use of their relatively scarce factors.
5. Vernon’s product life-cycle theory suggests that trade
patterns are influenced by where a new product is
invented and first produced. In an increasingly integrated
global economy, the product life-cycle theory seems to
be less predictive than it once was.
6. New trade theory states that trade allows a country
to specialise in the production of certain goods,
attaining scale economies and lowering the costs of
producing those goods, while buying goods that it
does not produce from other countries that are similarly
specialised. By this mechanism, the variety of goods
available in each nation is increased, while the average
costs of those goods should fall.
7. New trade theory also states that in those industries
where substantial economies of scale imply that the
world market will profitably support only a few firms (an
oligopolistic industry), countries may predominate in the
export of certain products simply because they had a
company that was a first mover in that industry.
8. Some new trade theorists have promoted the idea of
strategic trade policy. The argument is that government,
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 94
08/06/19 07:41 PM
by the sophisticated and judicious use of subsidies, might
be able to increase the chances of domestic companies
becoming first movers in newly emerging industries.
9. Porter’s model of national competitive advantage
suggests that patterns of trade are influenced by four
attributes of a country: (a) factor endowments; (b)
domestic demand conditions; (c) relating and supporting
industries; and (d) company strategy, structure and
rivalry. In addition, chance and government policy
are vitally important. Specialisation in this construct
should be in goods and services where the ‘diamond’ of
attributes is strongest and most complete.
10. International markets have varying types and degrees
of market imperfections and transactions costs. Some
are human-made and others are natural. When markets
are imperfect and transactions costs exist, there is an
incentive to internalise the market for exchanges rather
than to use market-based modes of exchange. Exporting
is a market-based mode of exchange while FDI is an
internalised mode.
11. High transport costs (a natural market imperfection)
and tariffs imposed on imports (a human-made market
imperfection) help to explain why many companies prefer
FDI (an internalised mode) to licensing or exporting
(market-based modes).
12. Companies often prefer FDI to licensing when: (a)
the company has valuable know-how that cannot be
protected by a licensing contract; (b) the company needs
tight control over a foreign entity to maximise its market
share and earnings in that country; or (c) the company’s
skills and capabilities are not amenable to licensing.
13. Knickerbocker’s theory suggests that much FDI is
explained by imitative behaviour by rival companies in an
oligopolistic industry.
14. Vernon’s product life-cycle theory suggests that
companies undertake FDI at particular stages in the lifecycle of products they have pioneered. However, Vernon’s
theory does not address the issue of whether FDI is more
efficient than exporting or licensing for expanding abroad.
CHAPTER 2
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 95
15. Dunning argued that location-specific advantages are
important in explaining the nature and direction of FDI.
According to Dunning, companies undertake FDI to
exploit markets, resource endowments or assets that are
location-specific.
16. Dunning’s O-L-I paradigm has become widely recognised
in international business. A company considering
international business must have something special to
take overseas, an ownership-specific advantage, an O.
After having taken a decision to internationalise, Dunning
asks into which market overseas will the company go
(different countries have different location-specific
advantages, L). Having chosen a location overseas,
which mode of entry and operation will the company
select? (All modes have varying degrees of market
internalisation and internalisation-specific advantages, I.)
17. The internationalisation pattern of SMEs has been
described as an incremental, sequential process in some
explanations, but in others, the first internationalisation
activity occurs soon after the company is founded and is
rapid, and its subsequent internationalisation activity can
be accelerated.
18. Some internationalisation models suggest that
companies initiating exports for the first time will target
countries that are psychically close. As such, a company
in Australia would start exporting to countries such as
New Zealand or the United Kingdom, and only after
accumulating experience in markets overseas would it
enter a market such as Japan, which is psychically distant
from Australia.
19. The so-called INVs and born globals internationalise
rapidly due to many factors which include reduced
trade barriers, shorter product life-cycles and
communication technologies which facilitate that rapid
internationalisation. In addition, often management in
these companies has experience accumulated from
previous work-lives and this can truncate the formative
phases in the new company. These companies do
not follow an incremental, sequential process to
internationalisation.
THEORIES OF TRADE, INVESTMENT AND INTERNATIONALISATION
95
08/06/19 07:41 PM
INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS
GRADUATE ATTRIBUTES (IBGAs):
LEARNING AND ASSESSMENT TASKS
IBGA1: DISCIPLINE KNOWLEDGE
AND SKILLS
1. ‘Japan is a neo-mercantilist nation. It protects industries
where it has no competitive advantage in the world
economy, such as domestic agriculture, while demanding
that other countries open those markets where Japanese
producers have a competitive advantage, such as cars.’
Discuss this statement.
2. Unions in developed nations often oppose imports
from low-wage countries such as Bangladesh and
advocate trade barriers to protect jobs from what they
often characterise as ‘unfair’ import competition. Is such
competition ‘unfair’? Do you think that this argument is
in the best interests of: (a) the unions; (b) the people they
represent; and/or (c) the country as a whole?
3. Drawing upon the new trade theory and Porter’s
model of national competitive advantage, outline the
case for government policies that would build national
competitive advantage in a particular industry. What
kinds of policies would you recommend that the
government adopt? Are these policies at variance with
the basic free trade philosophy?
IBGA3: PROBLEM SOLVING
4. One of the most significant factor endowments is
education, with important measures being the literacy
rate and the literacy rate gap between the genders.
Which of the following countries do you think has the
highest literacy rate and which country has the largest
literacy gap between males and females: (a) Iraq (b)
Rwanda (c) Chile (d) India?
IBGA4: ETHICAL DECISION MAKING
5. ‘The world’s poorest countries are at a competitive
disadvantage in every sector of their economies. They
have little to export. They have no capital, their land is
of poor quality, they often have too many people given
the available work opportunities and they are poorly
educated. Free trade cannot possibly be in the interests
of such nations!’ Discuss.
IBGA5: COMMUNICATION
6. You are the international manager of an Australian or
a New Zealand business that has just developed a
96
PART 2
revolutionary new personal computer that can perform
the same functions as PCs but costs only half as much
to manufacture. Your CEO has asked you to formulate a
recommendation for how to expand into the European
Union market. Your options are: (a) to export from your
home market; (b) to license a European company to
manufacture and market the computer in Europe; and (c)
to set up a wholly owned subsidiary in Europe. Evaluate
the pros and cons of each alternative and write a brief
report suggesting a course of action to your CEO.
7. The UNCTAD World Investment Report and its World
Investment Directory provide quick electronic access to
comprehensive statistics on foreign direct investment
and the operations of transnational corporations.
Compile a list of the largest transnational corporations
in terms of their FDI and identify their home country
(i.e. headquarters country). Then provide a 15-minute
commentary about the characteristics of countries that
have the greatest number of transnational companies.
IBGA6: SOCIAL INTERACTION
8. Your company is considering opening a new factory in
an Asian country, and management is evaluating the
specific country locations for this direct investment.
The pool of candidate countries has been narrowed to
China, India and Thailand. Form a small group of four
or five peers and prepare a short report comparing the
FDI environment and location advantage of these three
countries.
IBGA2: CRITICAL ANALYSIS
9. CASE ANALYSIS Read the Opening Case, ‘Bangladesh’s
textile trade’ again, and answer the following questions.
a. How has Bangladesh benefited from free trade and
globalisation?
b. What did the end of the quota system mean for that
country?
c. Using Porter’s diamond of competitive advantage,
explain Bangladesh’s competitive advantage in the
production of textiles.
d. How important are Bangladesh’s supporting
industries to its textile trade?
10. CASE ANALYSIS Read the following Closing Case and
answer the questions that follow.
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 96
08/06/19 07:41 PM
CLOSING CASE
LOGITECH’S GLOBAL APPROACH
Logitech, a computer technology company, was
co-founded in 1982 in Apples, Vaud, Switzerland,
by Daniel Borel, Pierluigi Zappacosta and Giacomo
Marini. The former are Stanford alumni and
classmates, while the latter was an engineer at
Olivetti and IBM. United in their vision of a global
operation, they rejected the ‘typical’ start-up strategy
of targeting niche markets and instead set their sights
on configuring a global organisation.
From its inception, Logitech faced the challenge of
entering a crowded and highly competitive market in
personal computer peripherals. This market includes
products such as keyboards, Bluetooth speakers,
webcams and (what would become Logitech’s
hallmark offering) computer mouses. To differentiate
itself from its competitors, Logitech’s strategy was
four-pronged: continued innovation, high-brand
recognition and robust retail presence, all supported
by an effective global supply chain and consequently
lower production costs.
Within just five years, Logitech had achieved its global
ambitions, with research and development (R&D) and
manufacturing operations in Switzerland, the United
States and Taiwan. It also laid the groundwork for
continuing success and innovation; it pioneered
infra-red tracking in computer mouses and was the
first company to make wireless mouses and keyboards.
Today, through products such as mouses, keyboards
and webcams that cost under US$100, Logitech
reports annual sales of more than US$1.5 billion.
programming R&D work. Ergonomic design work (the
look and feel of Logitech products) is based in Ireland,
where it is outsourced to a design company.
Manufacturing is now based in Asia, an outcome of
a course charted in the late 1980s when Logitech
opened a factory in Taiwan. At the time, most
Logitech products were produced in the United
States. The company was vying for the business of
the two biggest original equipment manufacturing
(OEM) customers: Apple Computer and IBM. These
companies were buying their computer mouses from
a Japanese company called Alps, which was also
supplying Microsoft. By shifting its manufacturing
to a new factory in Taiwan, Logitech was able to
produce a highly competitive product that was
better designed, manufactured at a higher volume
and offered for a lower cost. Taiwan boasted a
well-developed supply base of parts, a qualified
labour force and an overall robust and growing local
computer industry.
Importantly, Logitech also availed itself of an
excellent deal on rent. To encourage and nurture
early-stage innovators in the expanding technology
sector, Taiwan offered space in its science-based
industrial park in Hsinchu for the modest fee of
CHAPTER 2
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 97
© suphakit73/Shutterstock
Since its remarkable first years, Logitech has
persevered in its global approach and continues to
thrive. Loyal to its roots, Logitech remains a Swiss
company and retains R&D operations in Switzerland.
Its headquarters, however, are now based in
Fremont, California, neighbour to many of America’s
technology companies, such as Google. It employs
450 people in Fremont across areas including global
marketing, finance, logistics operations and software
THEORIES OF TRADE, INVESTMENT AND INTERNATIONALISATION
97
08/06/19 07:41 PM
US$200 000. Logitech signed the lease, and when it
shortly thereafter won Apple’s contract, production
in the Taiwan location soon outpaced the US facility.
Logitech concentrated its manufacturing in
Taiwan, and the plant’s capacity soon reached
10 million computer mouses annually. In the late
1990s, recognising a need for increased production
capacity, Logitech established plants in China, where a
wide variety of its retail products are currently created.
The Wanda, a wireless infrared mouse and one of
Logitech’s most successful products, provides an
effective case study for understanding the reality
of the company’s global operations. The Wanda is
assembled in a Logitech factory in Suzhou, China.
This factory employs 4000 people, such as 18-year-old
Wang Yen, who comes from the impoverished rural
province of Anhui. Each day, she sits at a conveyor
belt, plugging three tiny pieces of metal into circuit
boards. She performs this function 2000 times every
day, for compensation equivalent to US$75 a month,
to help create the Wanda—a product that will sell to
US consumers for about US$40.
Such economic exploitation is not Logitech’s alone.
Many other companies rely on exploitative practices
in China to support their manufacturing operations.
According to China’s ministry of commerce, foreign
companies account for three-quarters of China’s hightech exports. China’s top 10 exporters include US
companies with Chinese operations, such as Motorola
and Seagate Technology, a maker of computer disk
drives. Intel now produces some 50 million chips
a year in China, the majority of which end up in
computers, and other goods that are exported to other
parts of Asia or back to the United States.
SOURCES: V.K. Jolly, M. Alhuhta and J. Jeannet, ‘Challenging the incumbents: how high-technology start-ups compete globally’, Journal of Strategic
Change, 1 (1992), pp. 71–82; V.K. Jolly and K.A. Bechler, ‘Logitech: the mouse that roared’, Planning Review, 20(6) (1992), pp. 20–34; K. Guerrino, ‘Lord of
the mice’, Chief Executive, July 2003, pp. 42–4; A. Higgins, ‘As China surges, it also proves a buttress to American strength’, The Wall Street Journal, 30
January 2004, pp. A1, A8; J. Fox, ‘Where is your job going?’, Fortune, 24 November 2003, pp. 84–8, accessed via www.logitech.com on 15 February 2010.
CLOSING CASE DISCUSSION QUESTIONS
a. Is Logitech an INV/born global? Explain.
b. Explain how trade lowers the costs of making Logitech computer peripherals such as mouses and keyboards,
and increases the diversity of products available to consumers.
c. Using the theories discussed in this chapter, explain the way in which Logitech has configured its global
operations. Why does the company manufacture in China and Taiwan, undertake basic R&D in California and
Switzerland, design products in Ireland, and coordinate marketing and operations from California?
d. Why do you think the company decided to shift its corporate headquarters from Switzerland to Fremont,
California?
e. To what extent can Porter’s diamond help to explain the choice of Taiwan as a major manufacturing site for
Logitech?
f. Why do you think China is now a favoured location for so much high-tech manufacturing activity? How will
China’s increasing involvement in global trade help that country? How will it help the world’s developed
economies? What potential problems are associated with moving work to China?
98
PART 2
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 98
08/06/19 07:41 PM
ENDNOTES
1. H.W. Spiegel, The Growth of Economic Thought, Durham, NC: Duke
University Press, 1991.
2. S. Hollander, The Economics of David Ricardo, Buffalo: The University of
Toronto Press, 1979.
3. D. Ricardo, The Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, Homewood, IL:
Irwin, 1967 [1817].
4. For example, R. Dornbusch, S. Fischer and P. Samuelson, ‘Comparative
advantage: Trade and payments in a Ricardian model with a continuum of
goods’, American Economic Review, 61 (December 1977), pp. 823–39.
5. B. Balassa, ‘An empirical demonstration of classic comparative cost theory’,
Review of Economics and Statistics, 1963, pp. 231–8.
6. See P.R. Krugman, ‘Is free trade passé?’, Journal of Economic Perspectives,
1 (Fall 1987), pp. 131–44.
7. P. Samuelson, ‘Where Ricardo and Mill rebut and confirm arguments of
mainstream economists supporting globalization’, Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 18(3) (Summer 2004), pp. 135–46.
8. P. Samuelson, ‘The gains from international trade once again’, Economic
Journal, 72 (1962), pp. 820–9.
9. S. Lohr, ‘An elder challenges outsourcing’s orthodoxy’, The New York Times,
9 September 2004, p. C1.
10. P. Samuelson, ‘Where Ricardo and Mill rebut and confirm arguments of
mainstream economists supporting globalization’, op. cit., p. 143.
11. For example, J.D. Sachs and A. Warner, ‘Economic reform and the
process of global integration’, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity
(1995), pp. 1–96; J.A. Frankel and D. Romer, ‘Does trade cause growth?’,
American Economic Review, 89(3) (June 1999), pp. 379–99; and D. Dollar
and A. Kraay, ‘Trade, growth and poverty’, Working Paper, Development
Research Group, World Bank, June 2001. Also, for an accessible discussion
of the relationship between free trade and economic growth, see T. Taylor,
‘The truth about globalization’, Public Interest, Spring 2002, pp. 24–44.
12. Sachs and Warner, ‘Economic reform and the process of global integration’,
op. cit.
13. Ibid., pp. 35–6.
14. R. Wacziarg and K.H. Welch, ‘Trade liberalization and growth: New
evidence’, The World Bank Economic Review, 22(2) (2008), pp. 187–231.
15. J.K. Jackson, The Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP): Analysis of Economic
Studies, US Congressional Research Service, 30 June 30 2016.
16. B. Ohlin, Interregional and International Trade, Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press, 1993. For a summary, see R.W. Jones and J.P. Neary,
‘The positive theory of international trade’, in R.W. Jones and P.B. Kenen
(eds.), Handbook of International Economics, Amsterdam: North Holland,
1984.
17. W. Leontief, ‘Domestic production and foreign trade: The American capital
position re-examined’, Proceedings of the American Philosophical Society,
97 (1953), pp. 331–49.
18. See H.P. Bowen, E.E. Leamer and L. Sveikaysks, ‘Multicountry, multifactor
tests of factor abundance theory’, American Economic Review, 77 (1987),
pp. 791–809.
19. R.M. Stern and K. Maskus, ‘Determinants of the structure of US foreign
trade’, Journal of International Economics, 11 (1981), pp. 207–44.
20. D. Trefler, ‘The case of the missing trade and other mysteries’, American
Economic Review, 85 (December 1995), pp. 1029–46.
21. D.R. Davis and D.E. Weinstein, ‘An account of global factor trade’, American
Economic Review, December 2001, pp. 1423–52.
22. R. Vernon, ‘International investments and international trade in the product
life cycle’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, May 1966, pp. 190–207; and
R. Vernon and L.T. Wells, The Economic Environment of International
Business, 4th ed, Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall, 1986.
23. M.B. Lieberman and D.B. Montgomery, ‘First-mover advantages’, Strategic
Management Journal, 9 (Summer 1988), pp. 41–58; and W.T. Robinson and
Sungwook Min, ‘Is the first to market the first to fail?’, Journal of Marketing
Research, 29 (2002), pp. 120–8.
24. ‘Airbus to axe A380 superjumbo program in 2021 as Emirates
reduces order’, accessed via www.traveller.com.au/airbus-set-toaxe-a380-superjumbo-program-as-emirates-reviews-demandh1b8nx#ixzz5g3BKmT6Q on 20 February 2019.
25. J.R. Tybout, ‘Plant and firm level evidence on new trade theories’, National
Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper Series No. 8418, August
2001. Paper available at www.nber.org. S. Deraniyagala and B. Fine, ‘New
trade theory versus old trade policy: A continuing enigma’, Cambridge
Journal of Economics, November 2001, pp. 809–25.
CHAPTER 2
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 99
26. A.D. Chandler, Scale and Scope, New York: The Free Press, 1990.
27. P. Krugman, ‘Does the new trade theory require a new trade policy?’, World
economy, 15(4), 1992, pp. 423–442.
28. M.E. Porter, The Competitive Advantage of Nations, New York: Free Press,
1990. For a good review of this book, see R.M. Grant, ‘Porter’s Competitive
Advantage of Nations: An assessment’, Strategic Management Journal,
12 (1991), pp. 535–48.
29. B. Kogut (ed.), Country Competitiveness: Technology and the Organizing of
Work, New York: Oxford University Press, 1993.
30. Porter, The Competitive Advantage of Nations, op. cit., p. 121.
31. John H. Dunning, ‘Location and the multinational enterprise:
Neglected factor?’, Journal of International Business Studies, First
Quarter 1998, pp. 45–63.
32. Anthony R. Gargano, ‘An awakening’, Broadcast Engineering, 49(3)
(March 2007), p. 220.
33. J.P. Womack, D.T. Jones and D. Roos, The Machine that Changed the World,
New York: Rawson Associates, 1990.
34. D.T. Merrett, ‘The internationalization of Australian banks’, Journal of
International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money, 12(4–5), (2002),
pp. 377–97.
35. The argument is most often associated with F.T. Knickerbocker, Oligopolistic
Reaction and Multinational Enterprise, Boston: Harvard Business School
Press, 1973.
36. The studies are summarised in R.E. Caves, Multinational Enterprise
and Economic Analysis, 2nd ed, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University
Press, 1996.
37. See R.E. Caves, ‘Japanese investment in the US: Lessons for the
economic analysis of foreign investment’, The World Economy, 16 (1993),
pp. 279–300; B. Kogut and S.J. Chang, ‘Technological capabilities and
Japanese direct investment in the United States’, Review of Economics and
Statistics, 73 (1991), pp. 401–43; and J. Anand and B. Kogut, ‘Technological
capabilities of countries, foreign direct investment’, Journal of International
Business Studies, Third Quarter 1997, pp. 445–65.
38. K. Ito and E.L. Rose, ‘Foreign direct investment location strategies in the tire
industry’, Journal of International Business Studies, 33 (2002), pp. 593–602.
39. P. Jha, ‘Amazon, Walmart, now Alibaba — Indian retail headed towards an
oligopoly’, Newsclick, 22 August 2018, accessed via www.newsclick.in/
amazon-walmart-now-alibaba-indian-retail-headed-towards-oligopoly.
40. For example, see S.H. Hymer, The International Operations of National Firms:
A Study of Foreign Direct Investment, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1976;
A.M. Rugman, Inside the Multinationals: The Economics of Internal Markets, New
York: Columbia University Press, 1981; D.J. Teece, ‘Multinational enterprise,
internal governance, and industrial organization’, American Economic Review,
75 (May 1983), pp. 233–8; C.W.L. Hill and W.C. Kim, ‘Searching for a dynamic
theory of the multinational enterprise: A transaction cost model’, Strategic
Management Journal (special issue), 9 (1988), pp. 93–104.
41. J.H. Dunning, Explaining International Production, London: Unwin
Hyman, 1998.
42. P. Krugman, ‘Increasing returns and economic geography’, Journal of
Political Economy, 99(3) (1991), pp. 483–99.
43. J.M. Shaver and F. Flyer, ‘Agglomeration economies, firm heterogeneity,
and foreign direct investment in the United States’, Strategic Management
Journal, 21 (2000).
44. Australian Bureau of Statistics, ‘Small and Medium Enterprises’, Cat. No.
8141.0 (1998).
45. T. Clark, D. Pugh and G. Mallory, ‘The process of internationalization in the
operating firm’, International Business Review, 6 (1997), pp. 605–23.
46. J. Johanson and F. Wiedersheim-Paul, ‘The internationalization of the firm:
Four Swedish cases’, Journal of Management Studies, 1975, pp. 305–22.
47. S. Cavusgil, ‘On the internationalization process of firms’, European
Research, 8 (1980), pp. 273–81.
48. M. Czinkota, Export Development Strategies: US Promotion Policy, New
York: Praeger, 1982.
49. T. Rao and G. Naidu, ‘Are the stages of internationalization empirically
supportable?’, Journal of Global Marketing, 6(1/2) (1992), pp. 147–70.
50. O. Andersen, ‘On the internationalization process of firms: a critical analysis’,
Journal of International Business Studies, 24(2) (1993), pp. 209–31.
51. Johanson and Wiedersheim-Paul, ‘The internationalization of the firm: Four
Swedish cases’, op. cit.
52. J. Johanson and J. Vahlne, ‘The internationalization process of the
firm—a model of knowledge development and increasing foreign market
commitments’, Journal of International Business Studies, 8(1) (1977),
pp. 23–32.
THEORIES OF TRADE, INVESTMENT AND INTERNATIONALISATION
99
08/06/19 07:41 PM
53. D. Sullivan and A. Bauerschmidt, ‘Incremental internationalization: a test
of Johanson and Vahlne’s thesis’, Management International Review, 30(1)
(1990), pp. 19–30.
54. Andersen, ‘On the internationalization process of firms: A critical analysis’,
op. cit.
55. Y. Kwon and M. Hu, ‘Comparative analysis of export-oriented and foreign
production-oriented firms’ foreign market entry decisions’, Management
International Review, 35(4) (1995), pp. 325–36.
56. A. Millington and B. Bayliss, ‘The process of internationalization: UK companies
in the EC’, Management International Review, 30(2) (1990), pp. 151–61.
57. See J. Bell, ‘The internationalization of small computer software firms: A
further challenge to “stage” theories’, European Journal of Marketing,
29(8) (1995), pp. 60–75; and G. Knight and S. Cavusgil, ‘The born global
firm: A challenge to traditional internationalization theory’, Advances in
International Marketing, 8 (1996), pp. 11–26.
58. J. Johanson and J. Vahlne, ‘The mechanism of internationalization’,
International Marketing Review, 7(4) (1990), pp. 11–24.
59. J‐E. Vahlne and J. Johanson, ‘The Uppsala model on evolution of the
multinational business enterprise: from internalization to coordination of
networks’, International Marketing Review, 30(3) (2013), pp. 189–210.
60. Andersen, ‘On the internationalization process of firms: A critical analysis’,
op. cit.
61. Such as J. Lim, T. Sharkey and K. Kim, ‘An empirical test of an export
adoption model’, Management International Review, 31(1) (1991), pp. 51–62;
and S. Reid, ‘The decision-maker and export entry and expansion’, Journal
of International Business Studies, 12 (1981), pp. 101–12.
62. E.M. Rogers, Diffusion of Innovation, New York: The Free Press, 1962.
63. Lim, Sharkey and Kim, ‘An empirical test of an export adoption model’, op. cit.
64. T. Clark, D. Pugh and G. Mallory, ‘The process of internationalization in the
operating firm’, International Business Review, 6 (1997), pp. 605–23.
65. L. Leonidou and C. Katsikeas, ‘The export development process: An
integrative review of empirical models’, Journal of International Business
Studies, 27(3) (1996), pp. 517–51.
66. S. Reid, ‘Managerial and firm influences on export behavior’, Journal
of the Academy of Marketing Science, 11 (1983), pp. 323–32; and
100
PART 2
67.
68.
69.
70.
71.
72.
73.
74.
75.
76.
T. Madsen and P. Servais, ‘The internationalization of born globals: An
evolutionary process?’, International Business Review, 6 (1997),
pp. 561–83.
Bell, ‘The internationalization of small computer software firms: A
further challenge to “stage” theories’, op. cit.; and Knight and Cavusgil,
‘The born global firm: A challenge to traditional internationalization
theory’, op. cit.
B. Oviatt and P. McDougall, ‘Toward a theory of international new ventures’,
Journal of International Business Studies, 25(1) (1994), pp. 45–64.
AMC and McKinsey, Emerging Exporters: Australia’s High ValueAdded Manufacturing Exporters, Melbourne: Australian Manufacturing
Council, 1993; Knight and Cavusgil, ‘The born global firm: A challenge to
traditional internationalization theory’, op. cit.; and Madsen and Servais,
‘The internationalization of born globals: An evolutionary process?’, op. cit.
Knight and Cavusgil, ‘The born global firm: A challenge to traditional
internationalization theory’, op. cit.
D. Skene, ‘Born global firms: a growing feature of Australia’s internationally
active business community’, Australian Trade and Investment Commission
(Austrade), 19 December 2017, accessed via www.austrade.gov.au/News/
Economic-analysis/born-global-firms-a-growing-feature-of-australiasinternationally-active-business-community on 29 March 2019.
AMC and McKinsey, Emerging Exporters: Australia’s High Value-Added
Manufacturing Exporters, op. cit.
Ibid.
L. Welch and R. Luostarinen, ‘Internationalization: Evolution of a concept’,
Journal of General Management, 14(2) (1988), pp. 34–55.
P.W. Liesch, M. Steen, S. Middleton and J. Weerawardena, Born to be Global:
A Closer Look at the International Venturing of Australian Born Global Firms,
Sydney: Australian Business Foundation, 2007.
Lieberman and Montgomery, ‘First-mover advantages’, op. cit. See
also Robinson and Min, ‘Is the first to market the first to fail?’, op. cit;
W. Boulding and M. Christen, ‘First mover disadvantage’, Harvard
Business Review, October 2001, pp. 20–21; and R. Agarwal and M. Gort,
‘First mover advantage and the speed of competitive entry’, Journal of Law
and Economics, 44 (2001), pp. 131–59.
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch02_055-100.indd 100
08/06/19 07:41 PM
© HaJingjing/Shutterstock
CHAPTER 3
THE POLITICAL
ECONOMY OF
TRADE AND
INVESTMENT
CHAPTER 3
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd 101
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
101
08/06/19 07:44 PM
INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS GRADUATE
ATTRIBUTES (IBGAs)
This chapter’s content, learning resources and case studies provide you with the
opportunity to develop a number of International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs),
including the following:
IBGA1
IBGA2
IBGA3
IBGA4
IBGA5
Discipline Knowledge and Skills
Critical Analysis
Problem Solving
Ethical Decision Making
Communication
LEARNING OBJECTIVES (LOs)
3.1
3.2
3.3
3.4
3.5
102
PART 2
Identify and describe the policy instruments used by governments
to influence international trade and foreign direct investment.
Identify and evaluate the arguments for government intervention in
international trade and foreign direct investment.
Describe current international trade and foreign direct investment
issues, and discuss how the World Trade Organization is addressing
these issues.
Identify and compare the different levels of regional economic
integration.
Examine the implications for international business strategies of
international trade barriers and the increasing number of bilateral
and regional trade agreements.
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd
102
08/06/19 07:44 PM
OPENING CASE
UNEASE OVER CHINA’S RARE
EARTH TRADE POLICIES
Neither really rare nor particularly earthy (as the
Australian national science agency, CSIRO, puts its), rare
earth elements—with such exotic names as neodymium,
europium, ytterbium and lutetium—are a group of 15
speciality metals, along with an additional two closelyrelated elements. They have unique physical and chemical
properties that make them critical to an ever-increasing
variety of applications and demand in the electronics
and cutting-edge technology industries, as well as in the
search for energy efficiency and greenhouse gas reduction.
The metals have been used, for example, to develop
stronger magnets that have improved the performance of
electric motors, more effective rechargeable batteries and
catalysts that reduce toxins from exhaust emissions and
aid in the refining of oil. Global demand for rare earths is
estimated to have grown on average by 10 per cent per
annum over the past two decades. To many governments
and industries, the production of these metals is identified
as a ‘strategic priority’.
These elements are not rare in the literal sense. Cerium,
for example, is the 25th most abundant element in the
earth’s crust, as commonly occurring as copper. Rather,
these elements are rare in an economic feasibility sense,
since they are not often found in distinct deposits that
are easy to mine in quantity. Most natural deposits are
in China, and in 2015, China accounted for more than
90 per cent of global rare earth production and at one
stage accounted for 97 per cent of production. This
dominance put rare earths at the top of the ‘risk list’
compiled by the British Geological Survey.
China realised the strategic importance of rare earths in
the 1970s and embarked on rapidly growing exploitation
of its vast natural advantage in the metals, estimated to
be equivalent to nearly 40 per cent of the world’s total
supply. During the 1980s, Chinese production increased
rapidly at a rate of 40 per cent per annum. In 1992, the
Chinese leader, Deng Xiaoping, boasted: ‘There is oil in
the Middle East. There is rare earth in China.’ By the
1990s, China had overtaken the United States as the
CHAPTER 3
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd 103
major supplier of rare earths and now dominates the
world’s production.
Understandably, the United States and Japan, among
other nations, have felt vulnerable being so dependent on
China’s rare earth production. In 2010, China dramatically
reduced exports of rare earths to Japan as the Chinese
trade ministry stopped issuing licences for Chinese
companies to export to Japan. Such dramatic cuts,
however, did not apply to the United States and Europe
which, like Japan, were seen by China as major economic
and strategic competitors. Diplomatic relations between
China and Japan had been strained for some time.
However, China claimed that the decision was consistent
with one it had made a year earlier to begin to scale back
all exports of rare earths. True to its word, during the
second half of 2010, export quotas to all countries were
slashed further by nearly 70 per cent.
The cut in quotas, combined with increases in Chinese
domestic consumption and attempts by importers to
stockpile reserves, led to an almost eightfold increase in
the average global price of rare earths in the 12 months
after July 2010. The unease felt by importing nations over
China’s actions over export quotas came to a head in
2012. The United States, the European Union and Japan
were successful in having the World Trade Organization
(WTO) investigate whether China, a member of the
WTO, had violated the international rules of trade by
restricting the export of rare earths. China responded
to the accusations claiming that the export cuts were
justified and necessary to preserve an exhaustible natural
resource and to control serious environmental problems
caused by rare earth mining and refining. To these ends,
China claimed that it had to close down many smaller
and less-efficient mines.
These concerns about supply being subject to
the will and caprices of the Chinese government
have understandably caused importing nations to
try to expand their own supplies of rare earths.
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
103
08/08/19 11:28 AM
© Bjoern Wylezich/Shutterstock
production, planned for 2020–21. Meanwhile, a Canadian
company and another Australian company are developing
a mining project in Canada’s Northwest Territories.
Yttrium, a rare earth element often used to produce LEDs.
Australian mining companies Alkane Resources and
Arafura Resources are, as of 2019, developing large
projects to extract rare earths. Alkane’s investment
is the most advanced poly-metallic project of its
kind outside of China, while Arafura’s project could
supply up to 10 per cent of the world’s demand
for neodymium and praseodymium when in full
China, however, is not standing still. Not only is it
continuing to exploit its own natural endowments, but
it is also seeking to take control over deposits elsewhere
in the world. For example, China’s Shenghe Resources
Holding Co has announced a joint venture on rare earths
with Greenland Minerals to develop resources in that
country, and the company is participating in a number
of other undertakings, including the Mountain Pass rare
earth mine in California, the Kvanefjeld poly-metallic
deposit in Greenland and a rare earth metallurgical and
separating plant in Vietnam.
Demand for rare earths is continuing to outstrip supply
and for now China continues to have the advantage. But
the market is not standing still and ultimately a more
diversified supply will develop, which will be good for
the many companies that rely on a stable supply of this
critical resource.
SOURCES: S. Mertzman, ‘What are rare earths, crucial elements in modern technology? 4 questions answered’, The Conversation, 16 August 2018, accessed via
http://theconversation.com/what-are-rare-earths-crucial-elements-in-modern-technology-4-questions-answered-101364 on 21 February 2019; CSIRO, ‘The rare
earth challenge’, Resourceful, 7 (June 2015), accessed via www.csiro.au/en/Research/MRF/Areas/Resourceful-magazine/Issue-07/Rare-earth-challenge on 21
February 2019; M. Bohlsen, ‘Australia preparing to meet the world’s demand for rare earths’, Investor Intel, 29 January 2019, accessed via https://investorintel.
com/sectors/technology-metals/technology-metals-intel/australia-preparing-meet-worlds-demand-rare-earths on 21 February 2019; F. Egbaria, ‘Rare earths MMI:
Canadian, Australian firms join forces for Canadian rare earths project’, Metal Miner, 6 February 2019, accessed via https://agmetalminer.com/2019/02/06/rareearths-mmi-canadian-australian-firms-join-forces-for-canadian-rare-earths-project on 21 February 2019; ‘New Chinese JV for rare earth minerals from Greenland’,
World Nuclear News, 23 January 2019, accessed via www.world-nuclear-news.org/Articles/New-Chinese-JV-for-rare-earth-minerals-from on 21 February 2019;
P. Cai and P. Wen, ‘China blocks rare earth exporter’, The Sydney Morning Herald, 19 December 2011; A. Currie, ‘China set to define future market for rare earth
metals’, Rare Earth Investing News, 7 March 2012, accessed via http://rareearthinvestingnews.com/6335/china-define-future-market-rare-earth-metals-quota
on 7 August 2012; D. Palmer and S. Moffett, ‘US, EU and Japan take on China over rare earths at WTO’, Reuters, 13 March 2012, accessed via www.reuters.com/
article/2012/03/13/us-china-trade-eu-idUSBRE82C0JU20120313 on 8 August 2012.
INTRODUCTION
FREE TRADE
The absence of barriers to the free
flow of goods and services between
countries
104
PART 2
In Chapter 1, we described the growth and pattern of foreign trade and investment in
the global economy and the extent to which the countries of the world have increasingly
become linked economically. Chapter 2 laid out a case for free trade. Free trade refers to
a situation in which a government does not attempt to restrict what its companies and
citizens can buy from or sell to another country. In a world without trade barriers, trade
patterns are determined by the relative productivity of different factors of production in
different countries. As we saw in Chapter 2, free trade generates efficient use of resources
and greater competitive forces than is the case with restricted trade, and is thus a stimulus
to economic growth.
Although many governments are nominally committed to free trade, they are readily
persuaded by political and economic forces, both internal and external to the home
country, to intervene in international trade. Often the intervention is introduced to protect
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd
104
08/06/19 07:44 PM
the interests of politically important groups in the home country, although it may be
warranted on public interest grounds. The arguments for and against protectionism are
discussed in more detail later in this chapter. This chapter is titled ‘the political economy of
trade and investment’, a nomenclature given to issues surrounding government intervention
in trade and investment. As such, the politics enacted through government involvement
interact with the economics of international trade and investment. In Chapter 2, we also
looked at explanations and motives for foreign direct investment (FDI). These explanations
identified the circumstances where it was more advantageous for the company to conduct
its international business using FDI rather than an alternative mode. National governments,
however, may take the view that such investment is not in the public interest or that it
could do harm to certain interest groups. Governments therefore may not be prepared to
allow foreign companies to have complete freedom over FDI in host countries.
While strong cases can be made at the levels of the global economy, the national
economy and the company, for free international trade and investment, the reality is
that trade and investment is not unrestricted and companies have to conform to many
government interventions. However, the impacts on international business are not
necessarily always negative. Like most policy interventions there will be companies that
gain and companies that lose, and some policy interventions set out to positively assist
international business through trade and particularly through investment.
The Opening Case illustrates the nature of these political realities. The Chinese
government was quick to realise the strategic value of rare earths, and with the support
of its government, Chinese mining companies have come to be enormously influential in
global production. The case highlights both the economic and political motives for China
to maintain this dominance and the instruments it uses to attain this goal. Understandably,
other nations that have come to depend on Chinese rare earths imports have become
uneasy with China’s market dominance. Their concerns were warranted when China began
to reduce rare earths export quotas. Japan reacted in a tit-for-tat response by subsidising its
own manufacturers to find alternatives to China’s rare earths. The Australian government
reacted by prohibiting Chinese investment in the development of one of Australia’s largest
rare earth mines. A group of importers, the United States, the European Union and Japan,
reacted by challenging China’s restrictions on exports at the WTO. Their complaint to
the WTO was that China, as a member of the WTO, had violated the international rules
of trade by using export quotas to advantage its own manufacturers and to pressure
foreign companies that needed access to rare earths to relocate to China. China argued
that its export quotas were not trade protectionism and were necessary to control the
environmental problems caused by its rare earths mining.
The political dimension is clearly important in the rare earths case. But it is also clear
that the business dimension is equally dynamic. An obvious response to geographic
concentrations of important resources is to diversify supply if possible and that is happening
as Australian mining companies, along with companies from other nations, are seeking to
develop mines in other parts of the world. Chinese companies are doing this as well, to
pre-empt these defensive manoeuvres by competitors and to maintain the national resource
advantage—and market power—that China has. Clearly there is also an incentive to develop
technological alternatives to rare earths, as has been the case in energy markets, where
renewables (wind and solar in particular) have increasingly taken the place of fossil fuels such
as oil and coal. However, no clear alternatives for rare earths are currently on the horizon.
We start this chapter by describing the range of policy instruments that governments
use to intervene in international trade. This is followed by an explanation and assessment of
the trade-related political and economic arguments that governments put forward for such
intervention. The broader mix of political and economic forces and systems that together
CHAPTER 3
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd 105
PROTECTIONISM
Government intervention in
international trade and investment to
protect or advance the interests of
certain sections of the economy or
the nation as a whole
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
105
08/06/19 07:44 PM
POLITICAL ECONOMY
The political, economic and legal
systems and forces that govern an
economy and business activity
govern the economy and international business activity in general are part of a nation’s
political economy. Following an examination of trade issues, we then look at the benefits
and costs of FDI to host and home countries and at the policy instruments that countries
use to regulate FDI. In the penultimate section we outline attempts by governments at
the multilateral, regional and bilateral levels to establish agreements on the regulation of
international trade and investment. This section includes an examination of the role of the
WTO and regional economic integration (REI). We conclude the chapter with a discussion
on the implications of this material for international business decisions.
INSTRUMENTS OF TRADE POLICY
LO 3.1
There are many forms of government intervention in international trade. Some are aimed
at restricting or promoting trade—for example, import quotas and export subsidies. Others
intervene with trade even though they may appear to have been designed for some other
policy objective—for example, food labelling laws and product standards. The latter are
less obvious barriers to trade. Table 3.1 illustrates the variation in the barriers that are
imposed, particularly among the non-tariff barriers. The instruments of intervention that
we consider are tariffs, subsidies, import quotas, voluntary export restraints, local content
requirements, administrative policies and anti-dumping duties.
TABLE 3.1 Barriers to trade
Tariffs
Anti-dumping duties
Subsidies
Custom inspection practices
Quotas
Discretionary product classifications
Voluntary export restraints
Authorisation procedures
Embargoes
Multiple exchange rates
Local content requirements
Health and safety assessments
Licence fees
Labelling laws
Preferential licensing
Government preferred suppliers
Product standards
Tariffs
TARIFF
A tax levied by governments on
imports or exports
SPECIFIC TARIFF
A tariff levied as a fixed charge for
each unit of good imported
AD VALOREM TARIFF
A tariff levied as a proportion of the
value of the imported good
106
PART 2
A tariff is a tax levied on imports (or exports). Tariffs fall into two categories: a specific
tariff is levied as a fixed charge for each unit of a good imported (e.g. $3 per barrel of
oil); while an ad valorem tariff is levied as a proportion of the value of the imported
good (e.g. 15 per cent). In most cases, tariffs are placed on imports to protect domestic
producers from foreign competition by raising the price of imported goods. Tariffs also
produce revenue for the government.
An important aspect of an import tariff is who benefits and who loses. The government
benefits because the tariff increases government revenue. Consumers lose because they
must pay more for certain imports and/or purchase less desirable products. Domestic
producers, at least those in the targeted industry, gain because the tariff affords them
some protection against foreign competitors by increasing the cost of imported foreign
goods. They are able to increase prices. Those producers, however, who use the imported
product as an input to their own production lose as their costs of production rise. They are
penalised as it becomes more difficult for them in turn to compete in either the domestic
or the export market.
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd
106
08/06/19 07:44 PM
The Australian Productivity Commission provides dollar estimates of the extent
to which different industry groups are assisted or penalised by tariffs. As noted in its
­2016–17 report: ‘The Commission estimates that gross assistance to industry provided
by the Australian Government was $19.3 billion and that net assistance (after deducting
the cost penalty of tariffs) was $13.4 billion in 2016–17. This was a substantial increase
on last year’s estimate of $9.7 billion in net assistance. These estimates are conservative
as they exclude harder-to-quantify assistance: favourable finance (loans, debt, equity,
guarantees); local purchasing preferences, such as for defence equipment; and regulatory
restrictions on competition.’1
An important observation from these data is that not all industry groups receive
assistance from tariff protection but all industry groups incur input penalty costs from
tariffs. In general, two conclusions can be derived from economic analysis of the effect
of import tariffs.2 First, tariffs are pro-producer and anti-consumer. While they protect
producers from foreign competitors, this restriction of supply also raises domestic prices.
Second, import tariffs reduce the overall efficiency of the world economy because a
protective tariff encourages domestic companies to produce products at home that, in
theory, could be produced more efficiently abroad. Globally, agricultural trade is the most
distorted sector of trade in goods. Tariffs on manufactured goods tend to be much lower.
Average tariffs for agricultural goods are three times higher than for non-agricultural goods.
Some agricultural tariffs are as high as 800 per cent.3 As in other countries, Australia’s
tariffs on manufactured goods have declined. A tariff rate of 5 per cent is applied to most
manufacturing imports, and many items enter the country duty free.
Tariffs on exports are less common than tariffs on imports. In general, export tariffs have
two objectives: (1) to raise revenue for the government; and (2) to reduce exports from a
sector, often for political reasons. Argentina has just imposed a temporary two-year export
duty for any language translation services rendered in that country but used abroad in
some way. (Argentina is a major hub for Spanish translation services worldwide.) The intent
of this tax seems to be mainly for revenue, given its temporary nature and the fact that
obviously Argentina has no economic interest in reducing its translation services exports.4
Meanwhile, in 2012 Indonesia imposed a 20 per cent tax on the export of unprocessed
minerals, including nickel, tin and gold. While one aim of the tax was to raise revenue and
share the benefits of mining, other aims were to ensure domestic supplies and encourage
miners to locate processing plants in Indonesia.5
In 2018, US President Donald Trump engaged in a trade war with China, using tariffs
as a political instrument. On coming into office, President Trump committed to redressing
the large and widening trade imbalance between China and the United States. In trade
negotiations with China, he threatened to impose increased tariffs on a range of goods
imported from China (and some other countries) if the trade imbalance could not be
reduced by other means. He did impose the increased tariffs, with threats to impose more
if China and the United States could not agree on new arrangements more favourable to
the latter. After decades of unprecedented growth throughout the world, at least partially
attributed to declining tariffs and the freeing of international trade, President Trump’s trade
intervention has signalled that tariffs and other forms of trade intervention remain potent
instruments that some governments may use for political ends.6
Subsidies
A subsidy is a government payment to a domestic producer. As a non-tariff barrier,
subsidies take many forms, including cash grants, low-interest loans, tax breaks and
government equity participation in domestic companies. By lowering production costs,
CHAPTER 3
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd 107
SUBSIDY
Government financial assistance to a
domestic producer
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
107
08/06/19 07:44 PM
ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
FREE TRADE AND EFFICIENCY VS
FAIR TRADE AND JUSTICE
The fair trade approach is to use a product-labelling
system that assures customers that any certified
product they buy conforms to certain ‘standards’ in
the way that it has been produced, traded, processed
and packaged. These standards include direct
purchase from the producer, an agreed minimum
price for the producer, and an additional charge for
development and technical assistance to be paid to
the producer. WEF participants regard the labelling
system as a non-tariff barrier to trade but the fair trade
proponents argue that it enables the customer in the
supermarket to see a more direct connection between
their purchase and a positive benefit for the farmer
in the developing country. The fair trade approach
positions trade justice as a premium-brand value for
which the customer will be willing to pay more while
being assured that the farmer will get a fair share of the
benefits of trade.
© Thinglass/Shutterstock
The World Economic Forum (WEF) (www.weforum.
org) is an independent economic organisation whose
stated mission is to ‘improve the state of the world’. The
WEF is an advocate of free trade and investment. In its
view, the collapse of barriers to trade and investment
over time has led to increased efficiency and
global economic growth. According to the Fairtrade
Foundation (www.fairtrade.net), however, contrary
to the predictions of international trade theory, trade
liberalisation has not been a win–win outcome for all
participants. Because of market imperfections, the
benefits have not been evenly spread and free trade
has not relieved poverty—for example, poverty remains
for the agricultural producers in developing countries.
Fair trade organisations advocate a more even
distribution of the benefits of trade.
subsidies help domestic producers in two ways. They allow them to: (1) compete against
foreign imports; and (2) gain export markets.
Agriculture is one of the largest beneficiaries of subsidies in most countries. The Cairns
Group, founded in Cairns in 1986, is a group of 19 developed and developing agricultural
exporting countries. These include Australia, New Zealand, Brazil and Canada, but not
the United States or any European Union country. The group seeks to influence trade
negotiations in organisations such as the WTO and to reduce the domestic subsidies
and protection that farmers, particularly in developed countries, receive from their
governments. The group claims that the subsidies distort global agricultural markets and
reduce the earning capacities of the farmers of developing countries.
One study estimated that if developed countries abandoned subsidies to farmers, global
trade in agricultural products would be 50 per cent higher and the world as a whole would
be better off by US$160 billion.7 A more recent study estimated that removing all barriers
to trade in agriculture (both tariffs and subsidies) worldwide would raise world income by
US$180 billion.8 This increase in wealth arises from the more efficient use of agricultural land.
108
PART 2
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd
108
08/06/19 07:44 PM
When tariff support and subsidy support are combined for agriculture, as shown in Figure 3.1,
the equivalent of 20 per cent of farmers’ receipts on average in OECD countries is derived
from government assistance; that is, from taxpayers and additional charges to consumers.
FIGURE 3.1
Support for agriculture in selected
OECD and emerging economies
(percentage of gross farm receipts,
1995–97, 2008–10 and 2015–17)
80
70
Percentage
60
SOURCES: Data derived from OECD,
Agricultural Policy Monitoring and
Evaluation 2011: OECD Countries
and Emerging Economies, OECD,
September 2011, accessed via www.
oecd.org/​t ad/​agricultural​policies​and​
support/​agricultural​policy​monitoringand
evaluation2011oecdcountries
andemergingeconomies.htm on 8 August
2012; www.oecd.org/agriculture/topics/
agricultural-policy-monitoring-andevaluation/ accessed on 4 March 2019.
50
40
30
20
10
0
Japan
Korea
1995−97
European
Union
2008−10
Canada
United
States
Australia
New
Zealand
China
Russia
2015−17
Figure 3.1 also illustrates why countries such as Australia and New Zealand lobby
against the ‘unfairness’ of such support, which makes it more difficult for Australian and
New Zealand farmers to compete in foreign markets. For example, in the period 2015–17,
government support payments, as a percentage of gross income, accounted for an average
of 18.3 per cent for farmers in the European Union, 9.9 per cent for farmers in the United
States, 49.2 per cent for farmers in Japan and 53.5 per cent for farmers in the Republic of
Korea.9 In 2015–17, total support to domestic agriculture in the OECD countries averaged
US$317 billion (€285 billion) per year, on average. The objectives for agricultural support
policies vary across the OECD countries. For example, Japan and Korea are concerned about
self-sufficiency in rice production; the United States is concerned with providing an income
safety net for its farmers; and the European Union’s objectives are mixed as it attempts to
accommodate the interests of 28 members.
Non-agricultural subsidies tend to be much lower than agricultural subsidies, but
they can still be significant and the source of trade disputes between governments. For
example, subsidies were given to Boeing of the United States and Airbus of Europe by
their respective governments to help them lower the cost of developing new commercial
jet aircraft and to compete against each other in the aircraft market. Likewise, China has
heavily subsidised the development of its new commercial passenger jet and many other
internationally competitive industries. Claims and counterclaims of unfair competition as a
result of the subsidies found their way on several occasions to the WTO dispute settlement
process. In 2018–19 the US government threatened further tariffs against China, motivated
in part by claims of unfair government subsidies to Chinese companies delivered in a
variety of forms including state-directed lending, direct investments, tax breaks and local
government incentives.10 Of course, subsidies of this sort are common throughout the
world. The conflict is over how motivated countries are by a desire to distort world trade
and how effective they are in actually doing so.
The main gains from subsidies accrue to domestic producers, whose international
competitiveness is increased as a result. However, government subsidies must be paid for,
typically, by taxing individuals or by citizens forgoing government budget expenditures
on other desired public goods and services. The question of whether subsidies, as with
CHAPTER 3
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd 109
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
109
08/06/19 07:44 PM
other forms of protection, sustain the viability of business in the long term is debatable.
Rather, they tend to protect the inefficient and promote excess production. For example,
agricultural subsidies: (1) allow inefficient farmers to stay in business; (2) encourage
countries to overproduce heavily subsidised agricultural products; (3) encourage countries
to produce products that could be grown more cheaply elsewhere and imported; and
(4) therefore reduce international trade and business opportunities in agricultural products.
Import quotas and voluntary export restraints
IMPORT QUOTA
A direct restriction on the quantity
of some goods that can be imported
into a country
TARIFF RATE QUOTA
The process of applying a lower tariff
rate to imports within the import
quota than those over the quota
VOLUNTARY EXPORT RESTRAINT
(VER)
A quota on a trade imposed by the
exporting country, typically at the
request of the importing country’s
government
QUOTA RENT
The extra profit producers make
when supply is artificially limited by
an import quota
LOCAL CONTENT REQUIREMENT
A requirement that some specific
fraction of a good be produced
domestically
110
PART 2
An import quota is a direct restriction on the quantity of some good that may be
imported into a country. The restriction is usually enforced by issuing import licences to a
group of individuals or companies.
A hybrid of a quota and a tariff is the tariff rate quota. It is a two-tier tariff system. Under
a tariff rate quota, a lower tariff rate is applied to imports within the quota than those
over the quota. Often the in-quota tariff is zero but the above-quota can be prohibitive.
For example, until very recently a 10 per cent tariff was applied to up to 25 000 tonnes of
annual imports of whey for powdered baby formula in Japan. Imports exceeding the amount
were subject to a tariff rate of 29.8 per cent plus extra charges of ¥99 to ¥1023 per kilogram.
To promote the use of baby formula in the country (which Japanese health officials believe
improves health outcomes) a cut in the tariff was planned to begin mid-2019.11
A variant on the import quota is the voluntary export restraint. A voluntary export
restraint (VER) is a quota on trade imposed by the exporting country, typically at the
request of the importing country’s government. The implementation of a VER is generally
the result of bilateral negotiations. For example, in 2006, China and South Africa agreed
that China would restrict textile exports to South Africa to support the struggling South
African textile industry.12 Exporters agree to VERs because they fear more damaging
punitive tariffs or import quotas might follow if they do not.
As with tariffs and subsidies, both import quotas and VERs benefit domestic producers
by limiting import competition. Quotas do not benefit consumers. When imports are
limited to a low percentage of the market by a quota or VER, the price is bid up for that
limited foreign supply. If a domestic industry lacks the capacity to meet demand, an import
quota can raise prices for both the domestically produced and the imported good. Domestic
producers and licensed importers gain extra profit. This was the case for Fonterra when
it monopolised the EU import quota of New Zealand butter (see Another Perspective: ‘A
licence to profit’). This extra profit when supply is artificially limited by an import quota is
referred to as a quota rent.
Local content requirements
A local content requirement is a requirement that some specific fraction of a good be
produced domestically. The requirement can be expressed either in physical terms (e.g.
75 per cent of the component parts for a product must be produced locally) or in value
terms (e.g. 75 per cent of the value of a product must be produced locally). Local content
regulations have been widely used by developing countries to shift their manufacturing
base from the simple assembly of products whose parts are manufactured elsewhere
into the local manufacture of component parts. They have also been used in developed
countries to try to protect local jobs and industry from foreign competition.
A prevalent form of local content requirements is the so-called culture quota,
particularly as it applies to television and radio broadcasting. Cultural rationales for these
local content requirements tend to be couched in terms of preserving local culture and
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd
110
08/06/19 07:44 PM
ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
A LICENCE TO PROFIT
In July 2006, New Zealand butter exports to the
European Union were temporarily suspended,
threatening a loss to New Zealand of NZ$250 million
in trade per annum. Europe is New Zealand’s biggest
butter market, comprising 28 per cent of its total butter
exports. New Zealand’s global dairy giant, Fonterra,
markets nearly 95 per cent of New Zealand’s butter.
New Zealand had an EU quota of 77 204 metric tonnes
of butter per year. In effect, Fonterra, via a UK subsidiary,
became the sole licence holder in the European Union
to import New Zealand butter. The European Union gave
notice to Fonterra that it would lose its status as the sole
importer. The threat to the quota arose as a result of a
German dairy company, Egenberger, winning a case in
the European Court of Justice that found that Fonterra’s
control of New Zealand butter imports through its
London subsidiary was monopolistic and discriminatory.
Egenberger argued that any European importer should
be able to purchase butter from New Zealand.
Urgent government-to-government negotiations
ensued and a new agreement was struck. As
a traditional importer, Fonterra was allowed to
keep more than half the quota. At least six new
importers were to be guaranteed access over
time to the remaining share of the quota. The loss
of quota meant that Fonterra would lose significant
quota rents. Fonterra had long benefited from EU
price guarantees and quotas on butter and other
dairy products; but after the liberalisation of the
European dairy market, the demand for traditional
dairy products such as butter has fallen. With
increased life expectancy and people adopting
healthier lifestyles, Fonterra embarked on a strategic
reorientation of its European business. It has moved
into higher value-added dairy product ingredients
and products as convenience food and health food
products with less reliance on imported commodities
such as butter and cheese.
SOURCES: ‘EU to drop Fonterra butter monopoly’, Dairy Industries International, 71(11) (2006), p. 11; D. King, ‘The European Commission has agreed to
slash its tariff on New Zealand butter by almost 20% and ended uncertainty about the future of the $250 million trade’, The Press, 1 December 2006,
p. B10; Netherlands Embassy, ‘Reset for a dairy giant’, Investor Testimonial from Fonterra, Wellington, New Zealand, 2011, accessed via http://newzealand.
nlembassy.org/​trade-amp-investment/​investment/​investor-testimonial-from-fonterra.html on 12 August 2012.
promoting national cohesion and identity. An economic rationale is the protection of the
local film and music industries. Local culture is often perceived to be under threat from
US film, television and music. Despite the heavy negotiations, under the Australia–United
States Free Trade Agreement, which came into force on 1 January 2005, Australia was
not swayed to relax its culture quota requirements. Australia maintained the existing
requirement of 55 per cent local content transmission quota on programming on free-to-air
commercial television.13
As a consequence of the 2007–09 Global Financial Crisis (GFC), the WTO identified
that member countries had invoked more than 80 new protectionist measures for local
industry. One such measure was the US American Recovery and Reinvestment Act 2009,
which provided funding for a stimulus package of US$787 billion. It contained a ‘Buy
American’ provision that requires all iron, steel and manufactured goods used in any
government works to be produced in the United States.14 Local content regulations protect
the domestic producer by limiting foreign competition. Domestic producers benefit, but
the restrictions on imports raise the prices of imports or encourage overseas suppliers to
lower the quality of imports. Either way, the consumer loses.
CHAPTER 3
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd 111
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
111
08/06/19 07:44 PM
Administrative policies
ADMINISTRATIVE TRADE POLICIES
Rules and procedures adopted by
governments that can be used to
restrict imports or boost exports
Administrative trade policies are bureaucratic rules that, either by design or by default,
make it difficult for imports to enter a country. For example, at one point the Netherlands
exported tulip bulbs to almost every country in the world except Japan. In Japan, customs
inspectors insisted on checking every tulip bulb by cutting it vertically down the middle,
and even Japanese ingenuity could not put them back together. France once required that
all imported videotape recorders arrive through a small customs entry point that was both
remote and poorly staffed. The resulting delays kept Japanese VCRs out of the French
market until a VER agreement was negotiated.15
China is the major market for Australian wool. China’s wool imports are regulated by
a tariff quota, but there is also a mandatory re-inspection and re-classification of wool
by Chinese officials on the wool import’s arrival in China. These actions are considered
unnecessary, as the wool has already been tested by the Australian Wool Testing Authority
in accordance with internationally defined rules and regulations.16 China argues that the
threats to health from the insecticides contained in wool justify additional inspection. The
duplication increases the transaction costs of exporting wool to China. In this particular
case, however, the Australian wool trade with China boomed nonetheless. Australia
exported 271 million kilograms of wool fibre to China in 2017, a sharp rise from the pre1980 figure of less than 10 million kilograms. Strong economic demand can still trump
trade barriers if market conditions are right.17
Labelling regulations can be used to restrict trade. Different countries have different
wine labelling regulations. The Australian wine industry estimated that it incurred an
additional cost of nearly $25 million in 2012 because producers have to print a different
label for each export market. For example, there are 14 elements with requisite formats that
must be included in the design of a label for wine exports to the European Union.18
As with all instruments of trade policy, administrative instruments generally benefit
producers and hurt consumers, who are denied access to possibly superior foreign products.
It should be noted, though, that administrative procedures may nonetheless yield non-trade
benefits if properly designed and administered. Australian quarantine restrictions are meant
to keep out invasive and damaging species and microbes, and labelling requirements can
aid consumer health and safety. These non-trade benefits can potentially outweigh the
costs. A careful cost–benefit analysis should be applied to administrative policies, although
often this is not done.
Anti-dumping policies
DUMPING
Selling goods in a foreign market for
less than their cost of production or
below their fair market value
ANTI-DUMPING POLICIES
Rules designed to penalise foreign
companies that engage in dumping
and thus protect domestic producers
from unfair foreign competition
TRADE REMEDY
A measure taken by a country to
block market access on the grounds
of unfair pricing by exporters
112
PART 2
In the context of international trade, dumping is variously defined as selling goods in a
foreign market at below their costs of production or as selling goods in a foreign market
at below their ‘fair’ market value. The fair market value of a good is normally judged to
be greater than the costs of producing that good because the fair market value includes
a ‘fair’ profit margin. Dumping is a way to unload excess production in foreign markets.
Some dumping may be the result of predatory behaviour, with producers using substantial
profits from their home markets to subsidise prices in a foreign market with a view to
driving local competitors out of that market.
The aim of anti-dumping policies is to protect domestic producers from ‘unfair’ foreign
competition. Anti-dumping is an example of a ‘trade remedy’. A trade remedy is a national
measure to block market access on the grounds of unfair pricing by exporters. Other trade
remedies frequently imposed by governments include countervailing duties and safeguard
measures. As a WTO member, in order to apply anti-dumping measures, a country has
to demonstrate that the dumping is causing, or threatening to cause, material injury to
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd
112
08/06/19 07:44 PM
competing domestic producers. Anti-dumping measures include temporary customs duties
or tariffs. These tariffs increase the price of the import to a ‘non-injurious’ level.
Special duties may also be imposed on imports that benefit from subsidies granted by
foreign governments, which are deemed to threaten or cause injury to a local industry.
These measures are described as countervailing duties. The tariffs imposed can be
substantial and are intended to have an immediate protective effect, although they can
stay in place for an extended period of time, usually about five years. An aim of the WTO
rules is to prevent the use of anti-dumping measures as just another form of protection.
There was a nearly twofold increase in anti-dumping investigations in Australia in 2017 and
recent changes to Australia’s anti-dumping laws place a greater legal burden on overseas
businesses in pursuing them.19 Anti-dumping and countervailing duties are legitimate
responses in some cases to protectionist practices followed elsewhere. But, like other
tariff measures, their net effect is to restrict competition, cause higher prices and as a
consequence hurt consumers and domestic downstream industries.
WHY GOVERNMENTS INTERVENE IN TRADE
COUNTERVAILING DUTIES
Temporary tariffs imposed to
protect domestic producers from
the dumping of imports that have
benefited from foreign government
subsidies
LO 8.3
There are political and economic arguments for intervention in trade. The political
arguments are concerned with protecting the interests of certain groups within a nation
(normally, producers) often at the expense of other groups (normally, consumers). The
economic arguments for intervention are typically concerned with boosting the overall
wealth of a nation (to benefit all, producers and consumers).
Political arguments for intervention
Political arguments include preserving jobs, protecting industries deemed important for
national security, retaliating against unfair foreign competition, protecting consumers
from ‘dangerous’ or unsafe products, furthering the goals of foreign policy, advancing the
human rights of individuals in exporting countries, and more recently in confronting
climate change.
Protecting jobs and industries
The most common political argument for government intervention is that it is necessary to
protect jobs and maintain ‘essential’ industries, particularly those related to manufacturing.
There is political appeal in arguing that jobs should be protected from ‘unfair’ foreign
competition, and that certain industries should be protected and maintained for
defence reasons. With many international trade agreements restricting the use of tariffs,
governments have resorted to non-tariff barriers to protect domestic industries.
Until very recently, the motor vehicle industry in Australia had received substantial
government financial assistance over a long time period, the argument being, in the words
of several prime ministers, ‘for the good of the economy and the nation’. Before the removal
of government support and the subsequent exit of all motor vehicle manufacturers from
Australia, the Australian motor vehicle industry employed 55 000 workers directly and
another 200 000 in supporting sectors. It had been a political imperative for governments
to continue to provide financial assistance to keep the motor vehicle industry viable and to
maintain the associated jobs offered in key political districts. However, the fiscal expense of
supporting these jobs finally caused the government to cut all industry assistance in 2014
(although some assistance for retraining of displaced car workers is continuing for the near
term). The funds for these subsidies were finally determined to be better used elsewhere,
since the Australian motor vehicle industry will never be globally competitive.20
CHAPTER 3
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd 113
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
113
08/06/19 07:44 PM
Likewise, the EU Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) was designed to protect the
jobs of Europe’s politically powerful farmers by restricting imports and guaranteeing
prices. However, the higher prices that result from such interventions cost the
consumers of protected products dearly, support inefficiency and reduce the costcompetitiveness of other industries down the production chain that use the protected
products as inputs.
Meanwhile, after his election in 2016, US President Donald Trump vowed to bring
manufacturing jobs back to the United States that were sent overseas when the US
manufacturing industry sought to improve its international competitiveness by relocating
various value chain activities overseas to locations with the productive capabilities to
perform these activities competitively. For some time, the internationalisation of production
has seen millions of US manufacturing jobs move overseas.
National security
Countries sometimes argue that it is necessary to protect or restrict certain industries,
such as aerospace, advanced electronics and semiconductors, because they are important
for national security. Although import controls are not as common for defence and
national security reasons as they used to be, export controls over such sensitive products
remain pervasive. For example, 41 countries, including Australia and New Zealand, are
participating countries of the Wassenaar Arrangement.21 This arrangement seeks the
cooperation of members to enact legislation to control the export of conventional arms
and dual-use goods and technologies to certain countries as declared by individual
members. Many items and services used in the Australian mining and exploration
industries are subject to export controls and sanctions. These include certain survey
equipment, spectrometers, chemical processing equipment and even certain professional
services, depending on the destination.22 One technology export that raises considerable
security concerns is encryption technology. It is used to protect information sent over the
internet. A concern for law enforcement and national security agencies is that if terrorists
and organised crime get control of the so-called strong encryption technologies, the
agencies would be less able to secure public safety and combat terrorism.
Although formal import controls on foreign technology on the basis of national
security are not used as much as they once were, policy pronouncements against specific
foreign companies and rejection of those companies to install government projects has very
recently made a comeback. The US government has claimed that technology provided by
the Chinese company Huawei is a security risk because Huawei is said to be indirectly
controlled by the Chinese government and therefore the company’s components should not
be used in upgrades to mobile phone networks to the 5G standard. Several US allies have
said that they will no longer use Huawei for various projects as a result. Huawei denies
these charges and there is hot debate internationally over their veracity.23 This shows that
informal actions can be as important as formal controls. (See Management Focus: ‘Sanctions,
U-turns and accusations of money laundering at Standard Chartered’ on Iranian sanctions for
more about this issue.)
The protection of farmers is often justified as a political imperative for net foodimporting countries to ensure income and food security for the nation. In low-income
agricultural economies, such protection is seen as necessary to ensure viable incomes for
the large rural-based population. Food security dominates Japan’s agricultural policies. Japan
imports 60 per cent of its food. Japan argues that it needs to produce a certain portion of
food on its own to secure a safe and steady supply in the event of war, disease or natural
disaster. Six agricultural products, including rice and wheat, are declared by Japan to be too
politically sensitive to be included in negotiations on trade liberalisation and must continue
to be protected by high tariffs.
114
PART 2
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd
114
08/06/19 07:44 PM
Retaliation
Some argue that governments should use the threat to intervene in trade policy as a
bargaining tool to force policy changes—for example, to free up trade and force trading
partners to ‘play by the rules of the game’. The success of such intervention depends in the
main on the bargaining strength of the home government. A decade ago, the US government
used the threat of punitive trade sanctions to try to get the Chinese government to enforce
its intellectual property laws to combat copyright infringements. After the United States
threatened to impose 100 per cent tariffs on a range of Chinese imports, the Chinese
government agreed to tighter enforcement of intellectual property regulations.24
China is in a much stronger bargaining position today relative to the United States, and
in any case this is a risky strategy. Nonetheless, once again the United States and China
are engaged in a retaliatory trade war. While both countries understand that freer trade is
beneficial, they still revert to retaliatory trade intervention in an attempt to achieve political
and economic ends.25 The pressured government may respond to the imposition of punitive
tariffs by raising trade barriers of its own. The results could be higher trade barriers all
around and an economic loss to all involved, not to mention the loss of cordial diplomatic
relations. As is being evidenced at the present time, these interventions have the potential
to become systemic, affecting many more countries than those directly implicated.
Protecting consumers
Many governments have regulations to protect consumers from unsafe products. The
indirect effect of such regulations is to limit or possibly ban the importation of certain
products. The WTO Agreement on the Application of Sanitary and Phytosanitary (SPS)
Measures allows governments to restrict or prohibit trade in order to protect human,
animal or plant life and health, provided they do not discriminate or use this as disguised
protectionism. As noted above, China uses this argument to justify additional inspections
of wool imports from Australia. Australia itself has a strict quarantine regime and it has
often been accused of violating the SPS agreement and using quarantine as a means of
protection. Complaints to the WTO against Australia’s quarantine regime have related
to imports of salmon from the United States and Canada, fresh fruit and vegetables from
the Philippines, and apples from the United States and New Zealand. As one example,
the WTO was asked to rule on Australia’s regulations on plain packaging requirements
applicable to tobacco products and packaging by Ukraine, Honduras and the Dominican
Republic. It is a public health issue for Australia, but a trademark issue and restraint of
trade issue for the complainants. In June 2018 the WTO ruled in Australia’s favour, arguing
that the public health benefits justified the restrictions, a ruling that could open the way
for other countries to impose similar restrictions.26
Mad cow disease, foot-and-mouth disease, genetically modified (GM) grains and hormonetreated beef have been the trigger for the application of a number of SPS prohibitions over
the last decade in the beef trade, particularly between the United States, the European
Union and Japan. Australia as a beef exporter has often benefited by bans placed by Japan
and the European Union on US and Canadian beef imports under SPS provisions.
Furthering foreign policy objectives
Governments sometimes use trade policy to support their foreign policy objectives.27
Trade sanctions have been used to pressure or punish ‘rogue states’ that, in the view of the
government, do not abide by international law or norms. Usually the country imposing the
sanctions is relatively more economically powerful, and for sanctions to work effectively a
sufficient number of nations must simultaneously apply the sanctions. Getting cooperation
on the imposition of sanctions can be difficult, as each nation tends to have its own
economic and political interests to pursue. For example, Australia did not follow the United
CHAPTER 3
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd 115
TRADE SANCTIONS
Government actions that restrict or
prohibit trade with a country in order
to bring about a political change in
that country
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
115
08/06/19 07:44 PM
States and European countries in placing trade sanctions on Myanmar’s military regime
that were aimed at forcing political change and a return to democracy. For its ‘autonomous
sanctions’, Australia tends to resort to financial and travel sanctions on individuals and
the suspension of aid, rather than sanctions on the trade of goods and services from the
targeted countries. Australia currently imposes financial and travel sanctions on a variety
of countries, including Syria, Zimbabwe, Somalia, North Korea and Iran. Myanmar has had
sanctions eased and reimposed since 2012 as conditions in that country have fluctuated.28
Protecting human rights
Governments of Western democracies have often been pressured by civil society groups
to use trade policy to try to improve human rights and political freedoms in trading
partners. During the period leading up to China becoming a member of the WTO in 2001,
there was opposition to China’s application for membership based on China’s human rights
record. The debate focused on whether to grant most favoured nation (MFN) status to
China. If China did not attain MFN status, tariffs would have risen to about 40 per cent.
Opponents of China’s application pointed to the 1989 Tiananmen Square massacre, China’s
continuing subjugation of Tibet and the quashing of political dissent as indications of the
country’s disregard for human rights.29
The critics argued that the United States should withhold MFN status—that is, punish
China with higher tariff rates—until China showed measurable improvement in its human
rights record. In the end, the argument for coupling trade policy to human rights and
democratic reforms did not hold sway. The emergence of China as an economic superpower
has led the governments of Australia, New Zealand, Canada and the European Union
to take a somewhat similar pragmatic stance in their bilateral trade negotiations with
China. The Chinese government has been accused internationally of various human rights
abuses (such as discrimination against its ethnic Muslim Uighur minority) but Western
governments have given mostly muted responses.30
Pragmatism aside, a counterargument to using trade barriers in a punitive way to
advance democracy and human rights is that the best way to change the political and
social situation in a country is to engage it through increased international trade. This
is an argument discussed further in Chapter 6. Increasing international trade opens up
society to new ideas and raises the income levels of countries. As ideas spread and the
economy becomes richer and more open, people begin to demand, and generally receive,
better treatment with regard to their political freedom in line with their increased
economic freedom to trade. Limiting trade, on the other hand, may do more harm than
good to the people suffering abuse. The Australian and New Zealand governments
rejected calls to impose trade sanctions on Fiji following the military coup in December
2006. They did not wish to cause a loss of jobs and force consumer prices higher,
outcomes that would have affected mostly the poorer citizens of Fiji, generated further
political unrest and, as a consequence, brought about harsher repression by the military
regime.
Protecting the environment
This has become an important policy objective for many nations, fuelled by the growing
concern over carbon emissions and global warming. The nature of climate change is that it
is collectively caused and its solution requires collective action. To this end, 125 countries
signed up to the so-called Paris Agreement in 2015, agreeing to measures to keep the
global temperature rise this century well below 2 degrees Celsius above pre-industrial
levels and aiming for a hoped-for target of 1.5 degrees Celsius.31 Of course, there has been
both domestic and international push-back to this particular effort and other efforts to limit
carbon emissions. Trade unions and industry lobbyists in import-competing and export
116
PART 2
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd
116
08/06/19 07:44 PM
industries that are high emitters (such as steel, cement, glass, coal, aluminium, chemicals,
and pulp and paper) have argued that such controls would disadvantage them competitively
in world markets if other countries did not impose similarly strict controls on emissions.
Meanwhile, developing countries, particularly India and China, have made equity arguments
regarding the amount of sacrifice that they should make as opposed to developed countries.
Even though China has recently overtaken the United States as the world’s greatest polluter,
most of the harmful gas emissions today result from the actions of the now-rich industrial
nations over the past 200 years. There are claims that levels of per capita emissions are higher
in the industrial countries than in the developing countries, and that many of the goods
manufactured in developing countries are produced by subsidiaries of multinational enterprises
headquartered in industrial countries for export back to the industrial countries. Despite these
tensions, most countries, including the United States, did agree in Paris in 2015 to commit to
measures that could hurt some domestic industries but do so for the greater good.
Unfortunately, that moment of hope has since been overtaken by disagreement and
dispute. The Paris Agreement was mostly voluntary, with specifics to be negotiated later.
Donald Trump removed the United States from the accord after his election in 2016 and while
the remaining signatories still support the agreement, negotiations between them to come
up with detailed action plans have become mired in dispute.32 Few countries are currently
meeting the 1.5 degrees Celsius target, including Australia, and the Intergovernmental Panel
on Climate Change (IPCC) claims that the Paris Agreement will not achieve its stated goals.33
In part, this is occurring because domestic fossil fuel and other carbon-emitting industries
in the remaining Paris signatories have been fairly successful in getting local government
support or in interpreting the Paris Agreement in minimalist ways (e.g. claiming carbon
emission reductions that are more based on creative climate accounting than any real change).
International cooperation is made more complex when the existing policies applied by
governments are themselves contradictory in relation to mitigating carbon emissions. (See
Emerging Markets: ‘The BRICs: Electrical appliances and contrary energy-efficient policies’.)
Economic arguments for intervention
While there is strong endorsement of free trade based on the international trade theories
explained in Chapter 2, strategic trade policy and some acceptance of the infant industry
argument remains.
EMERGING MARKETS
THE BRICs: ELECTRICAL APPLIANCES AND
CONTRARY ENERGY-EFFICIENCY POLICIES
Emerging and populous economies such as Brazil,
Russia, India and China (the BRICs) are expected
to experience a substantial growth in the demand
for residential energy. Encouraging consumers to
CHAPTER 3
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd 117
use energy-efficient domestic appliances will be
an essential component of any strategy to reduce
greenhouse gas emissions in these countries. Trade
and energy policies, however, may actually be
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
117
08/06/19 07:44 PM
discouraging the uptake of the more energy-efficient
appliances. Table 3.2 shows the average electricity
prices charged to residential consumers in the BRIC
countries and the average tariffs imposed on the
imports of four common household appliances during
the period 2008–11.
The average prices paid by residents for electricity in
the BRIC countries are low. In Australia, Japan and the
European Union, the comparable prices are generally
much higher, such as 26 US cents per kilowatt hour
(kwh) in Australia in June 2018. Residents in three of
the BRIC countries are paying less than one-third of
the price paid in Australia. Governments maintain low
residential electricity prices in order to assist lowincome earners and to achieve income redistribution
and social welfare objectives. The import tariffs
imposed by the BRIC countries on appliances on the
other hand are high by international standards. Most
OECD countries and many developing countries apply
a tariff of 5 per cent or less on electrical appliances.
Most of the tariffs on these imports in BRIC countries
are two to four times higher than the OECD average.
The combined effect of low electricity prices and high
import tariffs is likely to continue to slow the take up
in the BRIC countries of the more energy-efficient
appliances. With low electricity prices, consumers
have little incentive to adopt energy-saving practices
and to purchase newer, energy-saving appliances.
Instead, they are encouraged to hold on to their
older, energy-inefficient appliances for longer. Import
tariffs favour the sale of the locally manufactured
product. If the local manufacturers have not kept pace
with the technological changes that have seen the
improvements in the energy efficiency of appliances,
consumers will continue to buy the cheaper, but
less efficient version, of the appliance. By limiting
international trade, the tariff limits product choice
and reduces the competitive pressure on the local
producers to match world best practice in the design
and manufacture of energy-efficient products. A
greater diffusion of energy-efficient appliances among
households could make a significant contribution to
meeting climate-change targets in the populous BRIC
countries, but their current energy and trade policies
are acting against such diffusion.
TABLE 3.2 Average ad valorem tariffs (per cent) on domestic appliances (2008–11), and average residential electricity prices (US cents per kwh,
2018)—BRIC economies
AVERAGE RESIDENTIAL
ELECTRICITY PRICE IN
JUNE 2018 (US CENTS)
AVERAGE AD VALOREM TARIFF (PER CENT) IN 2008–11
COUNTRY (BRIC
ECONOMIES)
AIR CONDITIONERS
REFRIGERATORS
TELEVISIONS
LIGHTING
Brazil
17.0
17
20
20
18
Russia
6.0
15
20
20
20
India
8.0
10
10
10
10
China
8.0
15
10
30
9
SOURCES: There is quite a bit of variation in estimates of residential electricity prices, although the order of magnitude and rank orderings tend to
be the same. The figures for the table are taken from ‘Electricity prices’, June 2018, accessed via www.globalpetrolprices.com/electricity_prices on 5
March 2019. Other sources include: ‘World energy prices: an overview, 2018’, International Energy Agency, accessed via www.iea.org/publications/
freepublications/publication/WorldEnergyPrices2018Overview.pdf on 6 March 2018 (note that raw data are available only for purchase); ‘Electricity price
statistics, 2018’, Eurostat, accessed via https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/statistics-explained/index.php/Electricity_price_statistics on 5 March 2019 (this
source only contains EU countries); K. Ahimoto, T. Homma, J. Oda, F. Sano, K. Wada, R. Janssen and R. Steenblik, Promoting Energy Efficiency Through
Trade, OECD Working Paper no. 2011-07, accessed via www.oecd.org/tad/environmentandtrade/49338989.pdf on 16 August 2012.
The infant industry argument
INFANT INDUSTRY ARGUMENT
This calls for the protection of an
emerging industry until it becomes
efficient enough to compete in the
world market
118
PART 2
The infant industry argument is one of the oldest economic arguments for government
intervention in trade. It was prevalent up until the 1970s in countries which adopted a
policy of import substitution by which high protective barriers were used to support and
encourage a growing manufacturing industry, resulting in a more diverse economy with
less dependence on agriculture. In Australia, tariffs, quotas, subsidies and local content
requirements were imposed to maintain the competitive position of the expanding
manufacturing industries against imports, culminating in high rates of protection for
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd
118
08/06/19 07:44 PM
manufacturers of textiles, clothing, footwear, motor vehicles and white goods.34 The
argument supporting protection is that many developing economies have a potential
comparative advantage in manufacturing, but new manufacturing industries cannot
initially compete with the established industries in the more developed countries.
Governments should temporarily support new industries until they have grown strong
enough to meet international competition.
Free trade economists remain critical of this argument, for two main reasons. First,
protection of manufacturing from foreign competition does no good unless the protection
helps make the industry efficient. There are a few historical examples where such
protection in some cases helped a domestic industry to take root sooner than it might
have (e.g. the tinplate industry in late 19th century America).35 However, more typical
is the experience of the Australian car industry. Through its import substitution policy,
Australia built up its motor vehicle industry behind tariff barriers and quotas. By the
­mid-1980s, tariffs on passenger motor vehicles were 57.5 per cent but the industry had
become one of the world’s most inefficient. By the end of the 1980s, labour productivity
in the Australian motor vehicle industry lagged substantially behind world best practice.
Whereas it took about 16 labour hours in Japan and 25 in the United States to assemble a
standard car, it took nearly 40 hours in Australia.36 Australia was not alone at the time in
adopting import substitution policies. The Brazilian motor vehicle industry has suffered a
similar fate. After 30 years of protection, the Brazilian industry had also become one of the
world’s most inefficient.37
Second, the infant industry argument relies on an assumption that companies are
unable to borrow money from the private domestic or international capital market to make
profitable long-term investments. Consequently, governments are required to subsidise longterm investments. Given the development of global financial markets over the past 20 years,
this assumption no longer looks as valid as it once did. Today, if a developing country has
a potential comparative advantage in a manufacturing industry, companies in that country
should be able to borrow money for required investments. The private financial markets
should be able to assess better than governments whether or not a company or an industry
can profitably exploit the potential comparative advantage. The only industries that would
require government protection would be those that are not worthwhile assisting.
Strategic trade policy
Some new trade theorists have proposed the strategic trade policy argument.38 As
explained in Chapter 2, the new trade theory argues that in industries where substantial
economies of scale exist, the world market will profitably support only a few companies.
Countries may come to dominate the export of certain products simply because they have
companies that were able to capture first-mover advantages. The long-term dominance of
Boeing in the commercial aircraft industry has been attributed to such factors.
The strategic trade policy argument has two components. First, a nation’s economy
will benefit if the government can somehow ensure that the company or companies that
gain first-mover advantages in an industry are domestic rather than foreign enterprises. The
government needs to pick a potential winner and use subsidies to support these promising
companies that are active in newly emerging industries. Advocates of this argument point to
the substantial research and development (R&D) grants that the US government gave Boeing
in the 1950s and 1960s, which helped give the company its competitive dominance in the
newly emerging market for passenger jets. In both the infant industry and strategic trade
policy argument, there is a requirement that government be able to pick potential winners—
industries or businesses that have the potential to prosper and stand on their own feet.
Governments are not always good at picking winners. See Management Focus: ‘Trying
to pick a winner: Government support of the magnesium industry’. In this case, some
CHAPTER 3
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd 119
STRATEGIC TRADE POLICY
Government policy aimed at helping
the country’s domestic firms gain
first-mover advantages or overcome
the first-mover advantages of foreign
firms in global markets that will
profitably support only a few firms
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
119
08/06/19 07:44 PM
interesting hypothetical scenarios arise. What would have been the cumulative costs to
taxpayers, shareholders and customers today if Australian governments had continued to
subsidise AML in the belief that they were on a winner over the long term in supporting
a magnesium smelter in Australia? Would the company have built the necessary
technological and entrepreneurial capacities to enable it to change strategic direction
and survive globally if it was to continue to be dependent on government subsidies?
In these types of cases, there is a presumption that government bureaucrats can better
spot a potential winner than private investors. Also, government policies can often have
unintended consequences. For example, see Emerging Markets: ‘The BRICs: Electrical
appliances and contrary energy-efficient policies’, earlier in this chapter.
The second component of the strategic trade policy argument is that it might pay a
government to intervene in an industry by helping domestic firms overcome the barriers
to entry created by foreign companies that have already reaped first-mover advantages. This
argument underlies government support of Europe’s Airbus, Boeing’s major competitor.
Airbus had less than 5 per cent of the world commercial aircraft market when it began
production in the mid-1970s. By 2010, it had increased its share to 45 per cent, threatening
Boeing’s long-term dominance of the market. Airbus achieved this position with the
assistance of US$15 billion in subsidies from the governments of Great Britain, France,
Germany and Spain.39 Without this subsidy, Airbus most likely would never have been able
to break into the world market.
If these arguments are correct, they support a rationale for government intervention
in international trade. A combination of home-market protection and subsidies may be
needed. Subsidies might be needed to support development work aimed at commercialising
emerging technologies, and export-promoting subsidies for the chosen companies to enable
them to establish first-mover advantages or overcome the established first-mover advantages
of foreign competitors in the world market.
The free trade argument revisited
BEGGAR-THY-NEIGHBOUR POLICY
A policy that yields economic
benefits to the home country but
only at the expense of making other
countries incur economic losses
Strategic trade policy arguments challenge the rationale for unrestricted free trade.
Economists are still generally sceptical. Paul Krugman, one of the economists responsible
for the development of the new trade theory, points out that strategic trade policy, in
practice, may be unworkable. The two reasons are retaliation and government capture.40
Strategic trade policy aimed at establishing domestic companies in a dominant position
in a global industry is a beggar-thy-neighbour policy, a policy that boosts national income
at the expense of other countries. A country that attempts to use such policies will
probably provoke retaliation resulting in a trade war between two or more interventionist
governments, with all being made worse off. The tit-for-tat granting of agricultural
assistance packages to appease the farming lobbies of Japan, the EU and the United States
is an example. Retaliatory action can be avoided if governments negotiate and establish ‘the
rules of the game’ that minimise the use of trade-distorting interventions. The WTO seeks
to do this, as we will examine later in this chapter.
Governments do not always act in the national interest when they intervene in the
economy. Politically important interest groups often influence them, not always to the
national good. The European Union’s support for the CAP arose because of the political
power of French and German farmers. A failing of strategic trade policy in the real world
of politics is that such a policy is almost certain to be captured by special-interest groups
within the economy, who will distort it to their own ends. Krugman concludes that in his
home country, the United States:
To ask the Commerce Department to ignore special-interest politics while formulating
detailed policy for many industries is not realistic: To establish a blanket policy of free
120
PART 2
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd
120
08/06/19 07:44 PM
trade, with exceptions granted only under extreme pressure, may not be the optimal policy
according to the theory but may be the best policy that the country is likely to get.41
MANAGEMENT FOCUS
TRYING TO PICK A WINNER: GOVERNMENT
SUPPORT OF THE MAGNESIUM INDUSTRY
Magnesium alloys allow the economic mass production
of strong, thin-walled, lightweight shapes and objects.
Similar aluminium objects would be 50 per cent heavier.
When it is used with aluminium it improves the strength,
corrosive resistance, weld-ability and tear-ability of
aluminium. In the late 1990s, magnesium was hailed
as the metal of the future, with the demand from the
world’s automotive industry expected to be immense.
This optimism spawned a number of mineral-processing
proposals in Australia, a process that turns raw
magnesite into finished magnesium. The largest proposal
at the time was that of the Australian Magnesium
Corporation (AMC). It proposed building a $1.7 billion,
90 000 tonnes per year, processing plant at Stanwell,
near Rockhampton, Queensland. As it was unable to
purchase an existing technology in what was now a very
competitive global market, AMC with the assistance
of the CSIRO developed its own low-cost process
technology. It built and operated a demonstration plant
to prove the technology to potential investors. To the
regional and national economies, the project promised
2000 jobs and $500 million in revenue per year.
During 2000–03, AMC set about raising capital and
commenced construction. However, signs of trouble
soon began to appear. Construction costs rose
above expectations and there was a shortfall in the
capital raising. The state government of Queensland
provided $100 million to guarantee dividend payments
to investors for three years. It provided another
$50 million for infrastructure assistance. The national
government provided $100 million to guarantee loans
and another $50 million for CSIRO to develop the new
processing technology.
After four years, with the plant in the very early phases
of construction, in June 2003 the project collapsed and
was mothballed. Shareholders lost $500 million and
taxpayers lost $240 million after salvaging some assets.
The blowout in the construction costs was widely
broadcast as the cause of the collapse, but perhaps
there were more fundamental causes. In an assessment
CHAPTER 3
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd 121
of the industry, the then chairman of AMC admitted to
the reality of the time that the persistent low magnesium
prices, the high value of the Australian dollar and cheap
metal imports from China would most likely preclude
any new investment in magnesium smelting in Australia.
How prophetic those sentiments were.
In the meantime, AMC looked to move on. By 2006, it
had changed its business model and, as a reflection
of the new direction, it changed its name to Advanced
Magnesium Limited (AML). The Brisbane-based AML’s
principal activities were now researching, developing,
manufacturing and selling new proprietary magnesium
alloys and technologies to die casters for end use in
the automotive, electronics and hardware industries.
AML no longer sought to manufacture magnesium
or its proprietary alloys itself. Instead, it outsourced
the manufacture of its alloys under licence to alloy
producers in China, Japan and Europe—AML’s main
regional markets.
In 2008–09, AML made another change to its business
model. It identified a number of weaknesses with
the licensing agreements with manufacturers. AML
realised that it lacked control over its supply chain
and as a consequence, the quality of the product
and the quality of service provided to its customers
was falling. Consequently, in 2009, AML returned to
manufacturing its magnesium alloys itself. It entered
into a joint venture to build and operate a greenfield
magnesium facility in China, the Henan Keweier Alloy
Materials Co. Ltd (HNKWE), of which AML owned 53 per
cent. HNKWE supplied AML’s alloys to all its customers
in China, Europe, the United States and Japan. China
is the world’s biggest producer of both primary
magnesium ingot (90 per cent of the global supply) and
magnesium alloys. AML’s executive chairman at the time
of establishing the joint venture declared, ‘[T]he ideal
location in Henan province, the availability of skilled
labour and the support of both local and provincial
governments should ensure that the company makes
significant market inroads over the next 12 months’.
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
121
08/06/19 07:44 PM
© Marianna Ianovska/Shutterstock
More company changes were to follow. In 2011, AML
took over the Magontec Group, originally a German
alloy maker, and changed its name to Magontec. With
the takeover, the company acquired more smelting
and manufacturing capacity in Germany and China,
together with recycling plants in Germany, China and
Romania. As a result of the takeover, it is now a more
diversified company. Magontec, now headquartered
in Sydney, continues to employ its research and
technology to develop and produce magnesium
alloys for the die-casting industries and it produces
magnesium anodes to combat corrosion for the water
storage and heating industries. Its latest project is on
a vast estate in China owned by its Chinese partner,
Qinghai Salt Lake Group (QSLG). QSLG was given
Australian Foreign Investment Review Board (FIRB)
approval to own a 30 per cent stake in Magontec. In
return, QSLG provided the capital for the company’s
Chinese cast-house facility, which opened on the
estate in April 2018. This facility converts solid pure
magnesium produced by QSLG into magnesium alloy.
Magontec is now a very different company from its
original AMC conception. In order to remain viable, it
has had to change strategic direction on more than one
occasion. Even if it had remained purely a primary ingot
smelting operation, AMC and its successors were able
to achieve in China what in essence they were unable
to achieve at Stanwell, even with significant taxpayer
support. And even so the company, while viable, is
not a great economic performer. The Chinese facility
remains well under capacity because QGSL is not able
to deliver the magnesium in the quantities it had hoped
to. And the company’s share price and economic
performance have been relatively flat. The AMC story
provides a cautionary tale for advocates of the infant
industry argument and for government support of
emerging industries.
SOURCES: K. Askew, ‘Flash burn’, The Sydney Morning Herald, 5 July 2003, ‘Business’, p. 43; A. Fraser, ‘Mag deal cost the taxpayers $240m’, The
Australian, 26 March 2004, ‘Finance’, p. 23; ‘Magnesium firm does its brass’, The Sunday Mail, Brisbane, 15 August 2004, ‘Finance’, p. 91; ‘Stanwell
smelter loses its political lifebuoy’, The Advertiser, 20 March 2004, ‘Finance’, p. 78; Advanced Magnesium Limited, Annual Report, 2006 and Annual
Report, 2009; Magontec, ‘Letter to shareholders’, Australian Stock Exchange, 23 May 2012, accessed via www.asx.com.au/asxpdf/20120523/
pdf/426f3m1054jlp4.pdf on 16 August 2012; Magontec, ‘Investor relations—Annual Report, 2011’, accessed via http://mgl.live.irmau.com/IRM/content/
welcome.html on 17 August 2012; M. Smith, ‘Magontec hunts for fortune on China’s salt lake plains’, Australian Financial Review, 6 August 2018,
accessed via www.afr.com/news/world/asia/magontec-hunts-for--fortune-on-chinas-salt-lake-plains-20180725-h135bj on 5 March 2019; Magontec
Limited (MGL.AX), ‘Yahoo Finance’, accessed via https://au.finance.yahoo.com/quote/MGL.AX?p=MGL.AX on 5 March 2019.
GOVERNMENT CAPTURE
When policy to regulate private
interest groups for the benefit of the
public interest is distorted by the
political pressure of these private
interest groups to serve their own
rather than the public’s interests
PART 2
WHY GOVERNMENTS INTERVENE IN FDI
As with trade, international business must contend with government interventions in
foreign direct investment. While there are benefits to a national economy of attracting FDI,
there are also costs and these costs often incite some form of political reaction. In the next
two sections, we explore the motives and means of government intervention in FDI. We
start by identifying the potential benefits and costs of FDI, first from the perspective of a
host (receiving) country, and then from the perspective of the home (source) country. In
the following section, we look at the policy instruments governments use to manage FDI.
LO 3.2
122
Because of retaliation and government capture, strategic trade policy could leave all
countries involved worse off, and trade more distorted, than if a hands-off approach had
been adopted in the first place. But, of course, hope springs eternal for those advocating
strategic trade policy, reinforced by the occasional seeming success (such as Airbus).
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd
122
08/06/19 07:44 PM
Host-country benefits and costs
The main benefits and costs of inward FDI for a host country arise from balance-of-payments
effects, resource-transfer effects, employment effects and the effects on competition,
economic growth and national sovereignty. Some effects are short term and direct; others
are more long term and have flow-on or spillover effects on other parts of the economy.
Balance-of-payments effects
A country’s balance of payments (BOP) summarises both its payments to and its receipts
from other countries. The balance of payments account is discussed in more detail in
Chapter 7. Governments normally are concerned when their country is running a large
deficit on the current account component of their balance of payments. (Colloquially, the
country is ‘living beyond its means’.) This current account balance tends to make the news
headlines. The current account records foreign expenditures and receipts relating to the
exports and imports of goods and services and income payments.
As explained in Chapter 7, the means by which a nation can continue to support a
persistent current account deficit is by borrowing from abroad or by selling off assets to
foreigners—for example, selling shares, real estate and whole businesses. Since national
governments and the general public invariably dislike increasing foreign debt and seeing a
large proportion of the country’s productive assets fall into foreign ownership, they prefer
their nation not to run large current account deficits. (Colloquial metaphors such as ‘selling
the family farm’ or ‘pawning the family silver’ raise political sensitivities.) There are two
ways in which FDI can help reduce a current account deficit.
FDI may be a substitute for imports of goods or services. For example, as a result of
Toyota once establishing a motor vehicle manufacturing plant in Australia, Australia’s
imports of Japanese vehicles are reduced. A second potential benefit arises when the
MNE uses its foreign subsidiary in a host country to export goods and services to other
countries. For example, in 2007, just before the onset of the global recession, Australia was
exporting $4 billion worth of motor vehicles out of plants that were all wholly owned
subsidiaries of foreign companies. There are, however, two possible adverse effects of FDI
on the balance of payments. First, set against the initial capital inflow that comes with FDI
must be the subsequent repatriation of profits (dividends) from the foreign subsidiary to its
parent company. Such outflows can contribute significantly to a current account deficit.
This is the case for Australia, as discussed in Chapter 7. A second concern arises when a
foreign subsidiary imports a substantial number of its inputs from abroad. A response by
foreign companies to this type of criticism is to pledge to use more local content.
BALANCE OF PAYMENTS (BOP)
The national accounts that
summarise both payments to and
receipts from foreigners
CURRENT ACCOUNT
The part of the balance of payments
that records transactions involving
the export or import of goods and
services and income payments
Resource-transfer effects
Foreign direct investment can make a positive contribution to the economic growth
of an economy by supplying capital, technology and management resources that would
otherwise not be available.42 While, for example, new technologies can raise the
productivity and competitiveness of existing industries and promote new industries,
many countries lack the R&D resources and management skills required to develop or
commercialise these new technologies. A study of FDI by the OECD found that foreign
investors invested significant amounts of capital in R&D in the countries in which
they had invested, suggesting that not only were they transferring technology to those
countries, but they may also have been upgrading existing technology or creating new
technology in those host countries.43 There are also spillover benefits. For example, local
personnel who are trained in the subsidiary of a foreign MNE may leave the company and
use their new skills to improve the operations of existing local businesses or to establish
new local businesses.
CHAPTER 3
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd 123
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
123
08/06/19 07:44 PM
Employment effects
Foreign direct investment can create new jobs. The employment effects are both direct
and indirect. Direct effects arise when a foreign MNE employs a number of host-country
workers. Indirect effects arise when jobs are created in upstream and downstream companies
in the supply chain. The indirect employment effects are often as large as, if not larger
than, the direct effects. For example, by the mid-2000s, Japan-based Toyota had invested
US$13.4 billion in the US economy. It directly employed through its operations 32 000
people, but in total it was responsible for nearly 400 000 jobs when account is taken of the
indirect employment in car dealerships and suppliers. These are gross totals, however. Against
these ‘new’ added jobs, domestic jobs may be lost as a result, yielding a lower net gain in
employment. Given the market success of the Toyota-branded motor vehicles at the time, the
Ford Motor Company planned to lay off nearly 30 000 workers and close 16 plants in North
America, and General Motors planned to lay off 25 000 employees and close 12 plants.44 And
even if these jobs were replaced by new ones, plant closures can result in significant costs to
individuals and their communities if people lose their jobs and are forced to relocate.
On the other hand, proponents of FDI would argue that the plant closures are not a
consequence of FDI per se but the result of Toyota’s superior competitiveness. This jobsubstitution criticism of FDI would seem to have more weight when it takes the form of
an acquisition of an established enterprise, as opposed to a greenfield investment. Jobs may
be lost as the MNC tries to restructure the operations of the acquired business to improve
its operating efficiency. However, even when taking over an existing company, research
suggests that enterprises acquired by foreign companies in OECD countries tend in the
long run to increase their employment base at a faster rate than domestic rivals. The same
study found that foreign companies also tended to pay higher wage rates than domestic
companies, suggesting that the productivity of employees was higher.45
Effect on competition and economic growth
When FDI takes the form of a greenfield investment, the result is to establish a new
enterprise which, in turn, can increase the level of competition in a national market. For
example, the German supermarket chain ALDI moved into Australia in the mid-2000s,
breaking down the market dominance previously enjoyed by Coles and Woolworths. After
that, foreign retailers such as Zara and H&M entered Australia, disrupting the domestic
retailing industry. Amazon’s 2017 entry into the country turned out to be less momentous
than expected, but the company continues to expand slowly, offering prospects for further
change.46, 47 New foreign competition such as this can broaden choice and drive down the
prices of goods and services for consumers, especially in countries like relatively oligopolistic
Australia. Increased competition tends to also stimulate capital investments in plant,
equipment and R&D as companies seek to gain an edge over their rivals. As a result, there is
increased productivity, product and process innovations, and greater economic growth.48
On the other hand, FDI may have an adverse effect on competition if subsidiaries of
foreign MNCs have greater economic power than locally owned competitors. The foreign
MNC may be able to draw on funds generated in the company elsewhere in the world
to subsidise its costs in the host market. It may have effective control of global marketing
networks and the control of upstream and downstream stages of the production chain in
the key markets of the world. Consequently, local companies will have difficulty competing
in both domestic and global markets. These restrictive practices could drive the local
company out of business.
If the FDI is in the form of acquisitions that involve the mergers and takeovers of
established companies rather than greenfield investments, then the effect on competition is
likely to be adverse as the subsidiary exploits its market power. This outcome, however, is
124
PART 2
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd
124
08/06/19 07:44 PM
more likely the result of the lax enforcement of the host government’s competition policy
than FDI per se. In Australia, the competition watchdog, the Australian Competition and
Consumer Commission (ACCC), can block mergers and acquisitions that are assessed to
have a detrimental effect on competition.
Host governments worry that FDI is accompanied by some loss of economic independence.
The concern is that key decisions that can affect the host country’s economy will be made
by a foreign parent that has no real commitment to the host country, and over which the
host country’s government has no real control. This is partially a felt psychic cost, but the
practice of transfer pricing provides evidence of a potential economic cost. Because of
TRANSFER PRICING
The pricing of goods and services
the high proportion of intra-company trade, the prices of a country’s imports and exports
traded between the subsidiaries
may be manipulated by the MNC among its own subsidiaries or related parties for its own
of the same company by the
benefit, rather than for the benefit of the host economy and its balance of payments.
company itself that best serves
the company’s interest
By manipulating the prices charged on the goods and services traded between related
parties in different countries with different rates of tax, an MNC can shift profits to low-tax
states and receive a tax benefit. The international shifting of profits may be beneficial to the
business, but it means some countries lose tax revenue. There are also balance-of-payments
effects, as the prices of exports and imports will not reflect true market prices. Along with
other governments, the Australian government has tax laws and tax treaties (Australia has
tax treaties with over 40 countries) to attempt to counter the inappropriate use of transfer
pricing to reduce tax obligations, but it is questionable how effective these laws are.
As we discussed in Chapter 1, another concern about the loss of national sovereignty
NATIONAL SOVEREIGNTY
The freedom of a nation from
and autonomy, particularly when overlaid with issues of national security, is the growth of
external control over domestic
sovereign wealth funds (SWFs). SWFs have existed since the 1950s, but it is the dramatic
matters
increase in their total size over the last 15 years that has given cause for concern. Many
in the Western industrial nations are concerned because a large number of SWFs are
controlled by authoritarian governments. For example,
government-controlled Chinese entities have increased their
investment in Australian agriculture, causing considerable
angst about food security and inciting several politicians
and farmer organisations to call for greater scrutiny and
control of such investment. (It is important to note,
however, that Britain, China and the United States are the
top three largest holders, in that order. It is not so much
foreign ownership itself that is seen to be a problem but
the perceived nature of the owner.)49 Over the past decade,
Chinese entities have also taken a large stake in Rio Tinto,
one of the largest mineral resources companies in the world;
the government of Qatar has sought a controlling interest
in Sainsbury, one of Britain’s largest supermarket chains; and
Gazprom airport workers refuelling an Airbus at Moscow
Gazprom, a Russian government-controlled conglomerate,
Sheremetyevo airport.
has a strategic interest in the energy sectors in a number of
countries and a stake in Airbus.50
There is concern that such investments are being undertaken to secure control
of strategically important industries in order to gain both political and financial
leverage. The danger for international business is that the political sensitivity over the
growth of SWFs will lead to greater investment protectionism, albeit aimed at foreign
government-controlled entities, but this will also limit the FDI opportunities of private
business investors.
CHAPTER 3
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd 125
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
125
08/06/19 07:44 PM
© Alexander Tolstykh/Shutterstock
National sovereignty and autonomy
Home-country benefits and costs
The benefits and costs of FDI to the home (source) country arise in three areas: balance-ofpayments effects, employment effects and resource-transfer effects.
Balance-of-payments effects
The home country’s balance of payments benefits from the inward flow of repatriated
foreign earnings. FDI can also benefit the home country’s balance of payments if the
foreign subsidiary creates demands for home-country exports such as capital equipment,
intermediate goods and complementary products. There are, however, negative impacts
of FDI on the home country’s balance of payments. First, the balance of payments suffers
from the initial capital outflow required to finance the FDI. This effect, however, is usually
more than offset by the subsequent inflow of foreign earnings. Second, the current account
of the balance of payments suffers if the purpose of the foreign investment is to serve the
home market with imports from a low-cost production location. Third, the current account
of the balance of payments suffers if the FDI is a substitute for direct exports.
Employment effects
Positive employment effects arise when the foreign subsidiary creates demand for homecountry exports. These effects can be enhanced when it is a deliberate policy of the home
government to tie aid given to developing countries for large capital projects with conditions
that favour home-country companies. These aid conditions may require that equipment
and other materials be imported from the donor country.51 A negative employment effect
occurs when outward FDI creates foreign operations that replace domestic production,
often described as ‘exporting jobs’ and ‘offshoring’. In the Management Focus: ‘Trying to
pick a winner’, the magnesium producer AML invested in smelters and manufacturing joint
ventures in China to produce its alloys. Jobs that could have been created in Australia have
been created offshore as a result of these FDI outflows. To put the extent of the potential job
loss from outward FDI in perspective for Australia, the aggregate FDI outflow from Australia
is in fact minor compared to the FDI inflow that Australia attracts.
Reverse resource-transfer effect
Benefits of FDI arise when the home-country MNC learns valuable skills from its exposure
to foreign markets that can subsequently be transferred back to the home country. This
amounts to a reverse resource-transfer effect. Through its exposure to a foreign market,
an MNC can learn about superior management techniques and superior product and
process technologies. These resources can then be transferred back to the home country,
contributing to the home country’s economic growth rate.52
GOVERNMENT POLICY INSTRUMENTS AND FDI
LO 3.1
In view of the benefits and costs of FDI, we now turn our attention to the policy
instruments that home (source) countries and host (destination) countries use to regulate
FDI to advance their economic and political interests.
Home-country policies
Depending on their economic and political goals, home countries may either restrict or
encourage certain FDI by their home country companies. Policies designed to encourage
outward FDI include foreign risk insurance, capital assistance, tax incentives and
political pressure. Policies designed to restrict outward FDI include exchange controls,
taxes and sanctions.
126
PART 2
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd
126
08/06/19 07:44 PM
Encouraging outward FDI
Many investor nations now have government-backed insurance programs to cover major
types of foreign investment risk. The types of risks insurable through these programs
include the risks of expropriation (nationalisation), war losses and the inability to transfer
profits back home. These political and legal risks are examined in more detail in Chapter 6.
Such programs are particularly useful in encouraging companies to undertake investments
in politically unstable countries.53 As a further incentive to encourage domestic companies
to undertake FDI, many countries have eliminated double taxation of foreign income (i.e.
taxation of income in both the host country and the home country). Last, and perhaps
most significantly, a number of investor countries have used their political influence
to persuade host countries to relax their restrictions on inbound FDI. For example, the
bilateral Australia–United States Free Trade Agreement (AUSFTA) gives US companies
easier investment access to Australia than that given to investment from other countries,
including New Zealand, even though Australia has a long-established free trade agreement
with New Zealand, the Closer Economic Relations (CER) agreement.
Restricting outward FDI
Controls on the movement of foreign currency have been used to limit capital outflows
out of concern for the country’s balance of payments and exchange rate volatility. As FDI is
for the long term, it is the short-term flows of foreign investment that are more the target
of such controls. Governments today are less likely to impose foreign exchange controls
except in times of financial and political crises. For example, during the 1997–98 Asian
financial crisis, one of Thailand’s responses was to impose foreign exchange controls and
limit outward capital flows. Brazil, India and China imposed exchange controls on capital
outflows during the 2007–09 GFC. In 2011, Argentina required its insurance companies to
repatriate all their investments abroad in order to stem the flight of capital.
Countries have occasionally manipulated tax rules to try to encourage their companies
to invest at home. The objective behind such policies is to create wealth—and hopefully
jobs—at home rather than in other nations. Finally, as a complement to trade sanctions,
countries impose sanctions that prohibit national companies from investing in certain
countries for political reasons. For example, US rules prohibited US companies from
investing in countries such as Cuba and Iran, because the regimes in these countries are
judged by US policymakers to be following policies contrary to US interests. Foreignowned companies can also be caught up in such regulations if they operate in the United
States. See, for example, how US sanctions almost resulted in a major British bank losing its
US banking licence, in Management Focus: ‘Sanctions, U-turns and accusations of money
laundering at Standard Chartered’.
Host-country policies
Host countries adopt policies designed to both encourage and restrict inward FDI.
Encouraging inward FDI
Given the economic benefits of FDI, it is common for governments to offer incentives to
foreign firms to invest in their countries, and in the current era, governments are actively
wooing FDI. Such incentives take many forms but the most common are tax concessions,
government-funded infrastructure, low-interest loans, and grants or subsidies. Nations, and
states within nations, often compete with one another to attract desirable investments.
In this competitive bidding environment, MNCs can often squeeze out very significant
concessions from host governments.
CHAPTER 3
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd 127
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
127
08/06/19 07:44 PM
Australia is one of the world’s largest food-producing countries, and it is strategically
located near the expanding South-East Asian markets, yet many of its value-adding foodprocessing factories closed or moved offshore in the first decade of the 2000s. Food
companies, many of which are foreign owned, that abandoned local processing during that
time include Heinz (tomato processing), McCain Foods (frozen vegetables), SPC Ardmona
(canned fruit) and Murray Goulburn (powdered milk), with thousands of jobs lost.54
Thailand tried to be the beneficiary of the restructuring of the Australian food-processing
industry at the time, with the government giving high-priority status to the foodprocessing sector, especially trying to attract FDI in higher value-adding food processing
rather than primary food production. An interesting example is medical foods. Medical
foods are foods developed for the specific dietary management of a disease or condition
for which there are distinctive nutritional requirements. For FDI in the manufacture of
medical food, the Thai government offers the following package of incentives: import duty
exemption on machinery; an eight-year corporate income tax exemption (a ‘tax holiday’); a
further 50 per cent reduction of corporate income tax for five years after the tax holiday,
a double deduction for transport, electricity and water supply costs; and a 25 per cent
deduction for construction costs in addition to the normal depreciation. The one restriction
is that the plant is to be located anywhere in Thailand except Bangkok.55
Did these inducements work? They seemed to for a while. After 2008, Australia became
a net importer of manufactured food and grocery products. Indonesia, Malaysia, Vietnam
and Thailand attracted the majority of FDI spent within the Association of Southeast Asian
Nations (ASEAN) in 2018. But Thailand has since fallen from first to fourth place, partly
because of political risk concerns around stability under military junta rule. However,
Thailand still receives a great deal of Japanese inward FDI.56
MANAGEMENT FOCUS
SANCTIONS, U-TURNS AND
ACCUSATIONS OF MONEY LAUNDERING
AT STANDARD CHARTERED
British-based bank Standard Chartered (SC) is one of
the world’s most international banks, operating in 63
markets worldwide and with more than 80 per cent
of its income and profits derived from Asia, Africa
and the Middle East (as of 2017). Although the bank
does provide domestic consumer banking in some of
the markets in which it operates, it is predominantly
a wholesale banker that provides banking and
financing services to multinationals and institutions,
including state-owned enterprises and wealth funds. It
specialises in the emerging markets of Asia, Africa and
the Middle East, where it has operated for 150 years.
Although SC’s presence in the United States is
seemingly small, it is an important operation for SC.
128
PART 2
The US dollar is the major currency of international
trade and finance (and thus referred to as a global
reserve currency). The United States is the major
economy of the world and the role of SC is to facilitate
cross-border trade and investment among its
customers in both the United States and the emerging
markets. This role involves the exchange of foreign
currencies and the clearing of interbank payments. In
the United States, SC was estimated to process about
US$195 billion every day in this role for its global
clients in 2012, earning itself considerable fees. In
that year, SC’s banking operations in the United States
were threatened with closure based on questions
about its past compliance with US sanctions law. The
New York State Department of Financial Services
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd
128
08/06/19 07:44 PM
(NYDFS) threatened to withdraw SC’s banking licence
over alleged illegal financial dealings with Iran. The
NYDFS, which oversees the core of the US banking
system, accused SC of wilfully hiding some 60 000
financial transactions worth nearly US$240 billion with
Iranian clients over the period 2001–07 in violation
of US sanctions. SC rejected the charges. On the
announcement of the charges, the value of shares in
SC fell by nearly 17 per cent.
US sanctions prevent banks operating in the United
States from doing business with Iran in response to the
concerns of the US government over the funding of
terrorism and the spread of nuclear weapons. SC was
accused of violating and exploiting, for its own benefit,
an exemption to these sanctions known as the U-turn
exemption. This exemption applied during the period
2001–07 and was revoked later in 2008. Under this
exemption, banks in the United States were allowed
in some circumstances to undertake so-called U-turn
transactions with Iranian financial institutions. U-turn
transactions move money for Iranian clients among
non-Iranian foreign banks, such as banks in the UK
and the Middle East. Under the U-turn exemption, a
US financial institution could clear these transactions
as long as they were initiated through non-Iranian
banks offshore from the United States and outside Iran,
and were routed back to non-Iranian banks offshore
and outside Iran.
The aim was to deny Iran access to the United States
and international financial systems while still allowing
non-Iranian banks access to a dollar clearing-house
function in the United States. US banks were expected
to abide by documentary and due diligence obligations
to comply with the exemption. They were expected
to monitor the wire-transfer messages that they got
from the other banks. Wire transfers were conducted
using the SWIFT (Society for Worldwide Interbank
Financial Telecommunication) payment system. These
messages contained customer names, bank names and
addresses associated with the payments. If the banks
did not have enough identifying information related
to the transfer or the information identified proscribed
entities or individuals, they were supposed to cease
the transaction and freeze the assets.
The allegations against SC were centred on U-turn
transactions undertaken between 2001 and 2007. SC
was accused of ‘wire-stripping’; that is, SC was accused
of removing the identifying information from payment
messages or falsifying such information so that Iranian
transfers would pass undetected through sanctions
filters. The NYDFS claimed that SC had ‘laundered’
as much as US$250 billion of Iranian money over
the period in question in this manner. SC denied that
the alleged deception had occurred. It responded by
declaring that it had not intentionally removed critical
information from wire messages. It declared that
following a voluntary review by external consultants
and lawyers of its U-turn transactions involving Iran,
it had found that ‘99.9 per cent of the transactions’
(nearly all of some 150 million messages) did comply.
It claimed that the value of transactions about which
there was some doubt was under US$14 million. SC
went open with its internal review, waiving its lawyer–
client privileges and providing all the relevant US
agencies with the information and analysis. The bank
also declared that it had ceased all new business with
Iranian customers in 2008.
SC was called before the NYDFS to explain the
apparent violations of the sanctions laws and
demonstrate why its New York banking licence should
not be revoked. The outcome of the hearing announced
in 2013 was an agreed settlement and a fine of
US$340 million. Under the terms of the agreement SC
agreed to allow a government anti-laundering monitor
to operate in their New York office for two years and to
increase its own staff of in-house auditors to monitor
compliance with US sanctions. The fine impost is
relatively insignificant for a company with an annual
profit of US$3.95 billion, but SC remains under the
threat of additional penalties from other US regulatory
authorities, such as the US Treasury and the FBI.
These agencies are concerned about possible ‘criminal
conduct’ involved when removing the Iranian names to
evade detection by US banking authorities. Other than
the possibility of losing its New York banking licence,
the most serious outcome of these money-laundering
charges is the reputational damage done to SC’s brand,
particularly in its major markets, the emerging markets,
where Standard Chartered is a household name.
SOURCES: Standard Chartered, Annual Report 2017, accessed via www.sc.com/annual-report/2017/media/doc/standard-chartered-annual-report-2017.
pdf on 6 March 2019; K. Scannell and T. Braithwaite, ‘Size of StanChart problem U-turn dependent’, Financial Times, 7 August 2012; BBC News,
‘Standard Chartered shares plunge on laundering charges’, BBC News Business, 7 August 2012, accessed via www.bbc.co.uk/news/business on 8
August 2012; D. Rushe and J. Treanor, ‘Standard Chartered bank accused of scheming with Iran to hide transactions’, The Guardian, 7 August 2012;
Australian Financial Press, ‘Standard Chartered fined $340m over Iran deals’, AFP, Yahoo!7 News, 15 August 2012, accessed via http://au.news.yahoo.
com/world on 7 August 2012.
CHAPTER 3
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd 129
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
129
08/06/19 07:44 PM
EXPORT PROCESSING ZONE (EPZ)
Area of a country where barriers
to trade are reduced and other
incentives are created in order to
attract foreign investors
The creation of an export processing zone (EPZ) is one means of providing incentive
packages to foreign investors. In an EPZ, barriers to imports are reduced and the occupants
enjoy a variety of concessions compared to the regulatory and fiscal demands placed on
businesses in the rest of the country. For example, concessions may relate to more liberal
employment and environmental regulations, less rigorous approval processes, better-quality
infrastructure at lower cost, and tax reductions or exemptions. EPZs attract a significant amount
of FDI, and significant shares of developing countries’ manufactured exports originate in EPZs.57
EPZs have been widely used in Vietnam, for example. The first EPZ was established
in the Socialist Republic of Vietnam in 1991. These are joined with industrial zones (IZs).
By mid-2016, there were 16 EPZs and 325 IZs, together attracting foreign investment
amounting to US$150 billion, about half of the total cumulative FDI inflows. Investment in
industrial parks (IP) and EPZs rose by close to 40 per cent between the first half of 2016
and 2017 to US$384.3 million.58
Restricting inward FDI
Host governments use a wide range of controls to restrict FDI. Table 3.3 lists the types of
barriers that an investor may face. The two most common are ownership restraints and
performance requirements. Ownership restraints can take several forms. In some countries,
foreign companies are excluded from specific fields, such as exclusion from tobacco
and mining in Sweden and from the development of certain natural resources in Brazil,
Finland and Morocco. In other industries, foreign ownership may be permitted, although
a significant proportion of the equity of the subsidiary must be owned by local investors.
Foreign ownership is restricted to 25 per cent or less of an airline in the United States.
TABLE 3.3 Host-country
barriers to FDI
Entry and
establishment
Prohibited or restricted entry to sensitive or strategic industries
Confinement of foreign investment to priority sectors and selected locations
Requirement to meet social and environmental obligations
Discretionary interpretations of the ‘national interest’ criteria
Visa restrictions on key personnel
Location of headquarters for a specific region or global market in the host country
Ownership and
control
Requirement for joint ventures
Limits to level of foreign ownership
Ownership restrictions contingent on satisfying performance requirements
Nationality requirements for executives and managers
Listing on local stock exchanges
Mandatory transfer to some local ownership in the future
Performance
requirements
Export a given level or percentage of goods and services
Supply exports to a particular region or global market exclusively from the host country
Restrict imports according to levels of exports and foreign exchange earnings
generated by the foreign investment
Achieve a given level or percentage of local content and give preference to local
suppliers
Transfer technology and intellectual property to local business
Achieve a given level of R&D in the host country
Hire a given level or share of nationals
Procedural
restrictions
Prolonged application, authorisation and registration processes
Extensive and ongoing reporting requirements
Involvement of different levels of bureaucracy and government
Discriminatory
treatments
Affirmative actions that apply restrictions, incentives and criteria differently for
local and foreign investors
Corruption in official decision making
Lack of transparency with respect to laws, regulations, procedures and
administrative rulings and judicial decisions
SOURCES: Based in part on M. Kohr, The Investment Issue in Trade Agreements: A Development Perspective, Third
World Network, November 2006, accessed via www.twnside.org.sg; Bureau of Industry Economics, Foreign Direct
Investment in APEC: A Survey of the Issues, Commonwealth of Australia, November 1995, ch. 5.
130
PART 2
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd
130
08/06/19 07:44 PM
In Australia, foreign ownership in Qantas is restricted to less than 50 per cent and no
single foreign entity can control more than 25 per cent. Specific legislation governs the
foreign ownership of Qantas, the Qantas Sales Act 1992. In India, foreign companies were
prohibited from owning media businesses until 2001, when the rules were relaxed, allowing
foreign companies to purchase up to 26 per cent of a foreign newspaper.59 In New Zealand,
consent is required if the foreign investor intends to acquire or establish a 25 per cent or
more ownership or controlling interest in a business worth more than NZ$100 million,
‘sensitive land’ or fishing quotas. When giving consent based on an assessment of the
‘national interest’, the relevant government minister is required to take into account
various cultural and environmental factors, including the protection and enhancement of
indigenous fauna and flora, salmon and protected wildlife, and historic heritage.60
The rationale underlying establishment and ownership restraints seems to be twofold.
First, foreign companies are often excluded from certain sectors on the grounds of national
security or unfair competition. There is a view that local companies might not be able to
develop unless foreign competition is restricted by a combination of import tariffs and
controls on FDI. This is a variant of the infant industry argument discussed earlier. Second,
ownership restraints, typically in the form of mandatory joint ventures, are based on a
belief that local ownership maximises the resource-transfer and employment benefits of
FDI for the host country. It is believed that shared ownership speeds up the diffusion of the
MNC’s valuable technology.
Performance requirements are controls over the behaviour of the MNC’s local subsidiary
and can take many forms, as shown in Table 3.3. The most common set of conditions relate
to local content, exports, technology transfer and local participation in top management.
As with establishment and ownership restrictions, the logic underlying performance
requirements is that they help to maximise the benefits and minimise the costs of FDI for
the host country. Performance requirements tend to be more common in less developed
countries where governments seek to maximise the development potential of FDI.61
TRADE AND FDI LIBERALISATION
As we have seen, there are strong economic arguments for unrestricted trade and for the
free movement of investment across borders to enable production to occur in optimal
locations. Moves to achieve liberalisation, with varying degrees of success, have occurred
at different levels—unilateral, bilateral, regional and multilateral. Because of the quid pro
quo nature of international negotiations, unilateral action by a government to extensively
liberalise trade on its own is not common. Unilateral action on trade tends to be taken
only for a specific purpose; for example, to give aid to a developing country by providing
duty and quota-free market access for its products. Similarly, unilateral action on FDI is
usually in the form of the relaxation of regulations or the offer of incentives to encourage
an inflow of FDI to a particular industry.
Governments, however, are often willing to negotiate with other governments to
formulate agreements on how to proceed with liberalisation. These agreements may be
bilateral, as with the CER agreement between Australia and New Zealand. They may be
regional, such as the United States–Canada–Mexico Agreement (USCMA, the successor
to the North American Free Trade Agreement [NAFTA]; see Country Focus, ‘USA: The
new protectionism’) between the United States, Canada and Mexico. And some are more
global or multilateral, such as the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), which
now operates under the auspices of the WTO. As of 2019, 164 countries were members
of the WTO. The vast majority of members are also parties to one or more regional trade
agreements (RTAs). There has been a marked increase in the number of regional and
CHAPTER 3
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd 131
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
131
08/06/19 07:44 PM
bilateral agreements in the last two decades. The WTO estimates that 479 cumulative
notifications of RTAs were in force as at 2019.62
We will focus here on the multilateral and regional agreements, with bilateral
agreements considered as a type of regional agreement. We begin by examining
multilateral agreements and follow with an examination of regional economic integration.
COUNTRY FOCUS
USA: THE NEW PROTECTIONISM
It was almost done and dusted: the Trans-Pacific
Partnership (TPP) would have been the world’s largest
free trade deal, covering 40 per cent of the global
economy, when former US President Barack Obama was
preparing to finalise the deal to be submitted to Congress
for ratification. However, the election of 2016 intervened
and Obama’s successor, Donald Trump, decided to pull
out of the deal entirely. Trump also threatened to
pull out of NAFTA—which had established a largely
free-trading area between the United States, Canada
and Mexico—unless he could renegotiate it to eliminate
what he considered unfair disadvantage to the United
States. The result was USMCA, concluded in 2018,
which readjusted NAFTA more towards US interests
(e.g. lowering existing protections for Canadian dairy
farmers), though not as radically as some might have
expected. Early in his administration Trump raised
tariffs on certain imports, especially from China, in
order to force China and others to open up more to
US exports.
Trump’s overall stated rationale for these moves is
that the United States is too highly subsidising a
world economic order that benefits other countries.
With respect to trade in particular, Trump argues
that other countries impose unfair barriers to US
exports, and that US manufacturing employment
and output have suffered as a result. His constant
refrain is that while the United States should be
a leader in the world, the current arrangements
are against US interests, a situation he is trying
to correct.
Of course, the United States can afford to act
unilaterally. It remains the largest economy in the
world, by far the largest military power, and the
US dollar is still the currency used to price many
international commodities such as oil. Australia,
though quite wealthy in GDP per capita terms, is too
small to be able to ‘go it alone’. Indeed, after the
United States pulled out of the TPP, the Australian
government pushed the Comprehensive and
Progressive Agreement for Trans-Pacific Partnership
(TPP-11), a free trade agreement between Australia,
Brunei Darussalam, Canada, Chile, Japan, Malaysia,
Mexico, Peru, New Zealand, Singapore and
Vietnam. The TPP-11 was signed by 11 countries
on 8 March 2018, with a few modifications to the
original agreement and without the participation of
the United States. While trade agreements always
© Pool/Getty Images
132
Trump has pushed against other major multilateral
arrangements outside trade as well, pulling out of the
agreement to remove sanctions on Iran in exchange
for Iran’s agreement to end its development of nuclear
isotopes needed for nuclear weapons, and pulling out
of the Paris Accord on climate change. He has also
called on other countries to pay more into various
collective security arrangements such as the North
Atlantic Treaty Organization (NATO).
PART 2
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd
132
08/06/19 07:44 PM
involve costs to particular sectors in particular
countries, and present specific policy problems at
times, Australia and its TPP-11 co-signatories thought
the deal was beneficial enough, even without the
United States and with questions remaining about
particular provisions (such as investor dispute
resolution mechanisms that would override national
government policies in some cases). Even Donald
Trump indicated he might bring the United States
back into the deal at a later stage, although it is
unclear how serious he was.
What is clear is that the United States is currently leading
the charge for the primacy of national over common
interests in international agreements, even though the
United States was instrumental in shaping those very
agreements. There is an obvious domestic political
motivation behind this. But if every country goes this way,
and the United States slowly loses its global economic
primacy over time, the future looks very unsettled indeed.
Cameron Gordon
Australian National University
SOURCES: J. McBride and A. Chatzky, ‘What Is the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP)?’, Council on Foreign Relations, 4 January 2019 accessed via www.cfr.
org/backgrounder/what-trans-pacific-partnership-tpp; Australian Government, accessed via https://dfat.gov.au/trade/agreements/not-yet-in-force/tpp11/Pages/transpacific-partnership-agreement-tpp.aspx; Country profile, The World Bank, accessed via https://databank.worldbank.org/data/embed-int/
CountryProfile/id/b450fd57.
Trade and FDI liberalisation and the WTO
LO 3.3
While many governments may recognise the value of trade liberalisation, they may be
unwilling to unilaterally lower their trade barriers for fear that other nations might not
follow suit. The essence of the problem is a lack of trust. Such a deadlock can be resolved
if both countries agree on a set of rules, a trade agreement, to govern cross-border trade
and lower trade barriers. But who is going to monitor the governments to make sure that
they are playing by the trade rules? And who is going to impose sanctions on a government
that cheats? An independent referee is needed. This referee could monitor trade between
the countries, make sure that all abide by the rules, and impose sanctions on a country if
it transgresses. While it might sound unlikely that any government would compromise
its national sovereignty by submitting to such an arrangement, since World War II an
international trading framework has evolved that has exactly these features. For its first 50
years, this framework was known as GATT. Since 1995, it has been known as the WTO.
From an international business point of view, three key functions of the WTO provide a
more orderly and predictable trading environment. These functions are:
•
the provision of a global forum in which to negotiate lower trade barriers
•
the application of the principle of non-discrimination to negotiations to avoid a complex
of different trading regimes among nations
•
the provision of a rules-based system for the orderly means of resolving trade disputes
among nations.
TRADE AGREEMENT
Defines the set of rules for the
conduct of trade
GATT and the WTO
The foundation for the current WTO global trading system was GATT, established in
1947. GATT was a multilateral agreement whose objective was to liberalise trade. It was a
response to the economic damage wreaked on the world economies prior to World War II
as a result of protectionist, beggar-thy-neighbour trade policies. GATT provided a set of
rules on the conduct of trade policy and a means for their enforcement. Agreements on
the rules were struck through negotiation and reached by consensus. Negotiations have
continued over a number of ‘rounds’ (which take their name from the place of the initial
negotiation). The last and longest round completed to date was the Uruguay Round, which
CHAPTER 3
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd 133
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
133
08/08/19 11:28 AM
MOST FAVOURED NATION (MFN)
PRINCIPLE
Requires a member of the WTO to
extend to all its trading partners
the same trading concessions that
it gives to its most favoured trading
partner
NATIONAL TREATMENT PRINCIPLE
Requires that national and foreign
trade and investment be treated
equally
134
PART 2
went from 1986 to 1994. The Doha Round commenced in 2001, but it has made halting
progress, punctuated by missed deadlines and on-again, off-again negotiations.
Non-discrimination underpins the negotiations and agreements of GATT and now the
WTO. It is embodied in two principles: the Most Favoured Nation (MFN) principle and the
National Treatment principle. Member countries cannot normally discriminate between
trading partners. MFN requires that if a country and its trading partner have agreed to
reduce a trade barrier (usually a tariff), then that same favour must be granted to all other
members of the WTO. The National Treatment principle requires that national and foreign
businesses be treated equally in all areas of trade and investment. By applying these
principles, trade liberalisation initiatives are diffused across the entire membership.
Under GATT, the enforcement of compliance with the agreements relied on the
cooperation of members. If a country believed that one of its trading partners was violating
a GATT regulation, it could ask the Geneva-based bureaucracy that administered GATT to
investigate. If the complaints were valid, member countries could be asked to pressure the
offending party to change its policies. In general, such pressure was sufficient, but a greater
pressure could be applied with the threat of expulsion from GATT. During the 1970s and
1980s the global economy was racked with a series of economic recessions. Governments
in Western Europe and North America were confronted with factory closures and rising
unemployment in the face of increasing import competition, particularly from the rapidly
developing Asian economies.
In response, these governments sought to devise forms of protection other than tariffs
for their manufacturing industries and began to use subsidies to maintain their share of
global agricultural trade. In the assessment of the later WTO, ‘These changes undermined
GATT’s credibility and effectiveness’.63 Other shortcomings with GATT became evident.
GATT tended to focus on tariffs and trade in manufactured goods, but non-tariff barriers
were becoming more prevalent, trade in services was growing rapidly, and efforts to
liberalise agricultural trade had been unsuccessful.
Against this background, in 1986, GATT members embarked on their eighth round of
negotiations, the Uruguay Round. After seven years, an agreement was reached that finally
went into effect on 1 July 1995. The agreement contained such provisions as reducing the
developed countries’ tariffs on manufactured goods to below 4 per cent, substantially reducing
agricultural subsidies, improving market access for trade in services, enhancing the protection
of intellectual property, and establishing the WTO to implement the GATT agreement.
The clarification, strengthening and extension of GATT rules and the creation of the
WTO held out the promise of more effective policing and enforcement of the global trading
system. For example, the Uruguay Round agreement gave the WTO a mandate to extend
global trading rules to three areas of growing interest to international business—trade in
services, the protection of intellectual property and the liberalisation of FDI. The WTO’s
General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS) extended free trade agreements to services.
The WTO’s Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS)
aimed to narrow the gap in the way intellectual property rights were protected around
the world and to bring them under common international rules. The Agreement on TradeRelated Investment Measures (TRIMS) partially liberalised FDI. As the name suggests,
TRIMS applied not to all government controls of FDI but only to national regulations on
FDI that might restrict trade. For example, agreement was reached to reform national FDI
regulations that prohibited or restricted foreign investment in the telecommunications and
financial services industries. The TRIMS agreement acknowledged two realities of these
industries: (1) the link between services and FDI, that is, that services in the main need
to be produced where they are consumed; and (2) the global nature of industries such as
telecommunications and financial services. TRIMS had the potential as a set of ground rules
to bring about an extensive liberalisation of FDI; however, its scope was severely curtailed
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd
134
08/06/19 07:44 PM
by WTO members. Few nations, particularly the net recipients of FDI, were prepared to
cede control of FDI to an international body.
Multilateral institutions have had little success in the pursuit of a universal and binding
investment agreement, similar to the one governing trade. An investment agreement,
sponsored mainly by the developed countries, was put forward for inclusion on the 2001
Doha agenda. Led by Malaysia and India, the developing country members rejected the
proposed agenda item, and negotiations for an investment agreement were officially
dropped off the Doha agenda in 2004. The developing countries argue that to apply GATTtype rules and principles such as MFN and national treatment to investment flows would
damage their development prospects. They argue that MFN and national treatment would
make it virtually impossible to regulate the quantity and quality of foreign investment in
a manner that is consistent with their individual development goals. Developing countries
also argue that today’s developed countries are somewhat hypocritical in what they are
pushing to impose on developing countries in relation to FDI liberalisation. When today’s
developed economies including the United States, Germany, Japan, Taiwan and Korea were
developing and were the net recipients of foreign investment, they had imposed strict
regulations on foreign investment.64
In 1995, the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) initiated
discussion on an investment agreement. The OECD, often described as the ‘rich nations
club’, provides a forum in which governments consider research and analysis and avenues
for collaboration on a variety of economic and policy issues affecting their economies.
The members include most EU countries, the United States, Australia, New Zealand, Japan
and South Korea. A draft of a multilateral agreement on investment (MAI) was drawn up
that would make it illegal for signatory states to discriminate against foreign investors. It
proposed a dispute settlement process and it would be open to non-members. The talks
broke down in early 1998, primarily because the United States refused to sign the proposed
agreement on the grounds that it contained too many exceptions that would weaken its
powers. Environmental and labour groups also campaigned against the MAI, criticising the
proposed agreement because it contained no binding environmental or labour agreements.
Under the Uruguay Round agreement, the WTO took over the responsibility for
arbitrating trade disputes and monitoring the trade policies of member countries, which
before had relied on a mutual monitoring mechanism. While the WTO operates on the
basis of consensus as GATT did, in the area of dispute settlement member countries
are no longer able to block adoption of arbitration decisions. Once appeals, if any, have
been determined, trading partners have the right to compensation or, in the last resort,
to impose commensurate trade sanctions on offenders who fail to comply with the
recommendations of the arbitration process.
Unresolved issues and the Doha Round
In Doha, Qatar, in November 2001, member governments agreed to launch a new round of
negotiations. Agreeing on an agenda for the Doha Round proved difficult. First, a proposed
agenda would need to include a number of issues that had remained unresolved in the
WTO for some years after the Uruguay Round and persisted in the main post-2001. Inside
the WTO, these key issues included the increase in anti-dumping policies, the high level
of protectionism in agriculture, the lack of strong protection for intellectual property
rights in many nations, and the continued limited market access caused by high tariff
rates on non-agricultural goods and services in many nations, particularly in emerging
economies. We will examine each of these issues shortly.
Second, adding to the difficulty of gaining consensus on any agenda and agreement
for new trade and investment rules was the greater diversity of objectives and priorities
of a much larger WTO membership. Developing countries make up nearly two-thirds of
CHAPTER 3
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd 135
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
135
08/06/19 07:44 PM
the WTO membership. There was a growing concern among these countries and among a
diverse collection of civil society groups outside the WTO that the WTO agreements on
trade and investment liberalisation had not yielded the economic development outcomes
promised and instead had tended to favour the interests of developed countries. In light
of the concerns and debates about free trade and economic development that surfaced in
Seattle and elsewhere, as a concession to the developing countries, the new talks in Doha
were launched with a general focus on development through fairer trade. The round was
named the Doha Development Agenda (DDA) with the promise of boosting global trade
with a development focus.
Anti-dumping actions The first of the issues that Doha might have been expected to
resolve is the extensive use by some countries of anti-dumping policies—as we noted earlier,
a type of trade remedy. Over the period from 1995 to 2017, WTO members reported
initiating 5529 anti-dumping actions to the WTO. India, the European Union and the United
States initiated the largest number of anti-dumping actions, accounting for almost one-third
of the total of these actions over this period. India initiated 888, the United States 659 and
the European Union 302 actions. The top three sectors for which actions were invoked
over this period were the base metals and articles sector (1692); products of the chemical
and allied industries (1114); and resins, plastics and articles, and rubber and articles (726).65
These industries have experienced intense competition and excess production capacity.
The WTO suggested that the trend reflected persistent protectionist tendencies. When the
WTO signalled that anti-dumping would be a focus of the Doha Round, the number of antidumping actions declined somewhat for a period after 2001, as seen in Figure 3.2, but with
the advent of a global recession in 2008, the number of actions began again to rise.
FIGURE 3.2
Anti-dumping actions, 2000–2017
400
SOURCE: Constructed by the author from
WTO statistics. World Trade Organization,
‘Anti-dumping’, accessed via www.
wto.org/english/tratop_e/adp_e/AD_
InitiationsByRepMem.xls on 7 March 2019.
350
300
250
200
150
100
Rest of the world
European Union
United States
2017
2016
2015
2014
2013
2012
2011
2010
2009
2008
2007
2006
2005
2004
2003
2002
2001
2000
1999
1998
1997
1995
0
1996
50
India
Agricultural protection The second issue is agricultural protection. Protectionism
in agriculture remains high, as we outlined earlier in this chapter. Whereas the world
trade-weighted average of manufactured goods tariffs was about 7 per cent in 2016, in
136
PART 2
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd
136
08/06/19 07:44 PM
agriculture it was around 16 per cent and some individual rates can be much higher.66 In
all cases except Australia, the tariff protection given to agricultural products is higher than
that for non-agricultural products. In addition to high tariffs, agricultural producers also
benefit from substantial subsidies. The extent of the total combined government assistance
given to farmers was shown earlier in Figure 3.1. The biggest defenders of the existing
system of agricultural assistance have been the advanced nations of the world, which tend
to use income and price support instruments rather than tariff protection. In contrast,
developing nations have been pushing hard for reforms to such financial assistance
packages, which they cannot match in order to allow their producers greater access to the
protected agricultural markets of the developed nations.
Intellectual property protection The third issue is the enforcement of rules for
intellectual property (IP). The TRIPS regulations obliged WTO members to grant and
enforce patents lasting at least 20 years and copyrights lasting 50 years. Developing
countries initially were given some leeway in regard to how long they had to implement
this agreement and later, as a further concession as part of the Doha negotiations, easier
access to new technologies—in particular, pharmaceuticals. The WTO believes that
reducing piracy rates in areas such as pharmaceuticals and software will have a significant
impact on the volume of world trade and increase the incentive for producers to invest in
the creation of intellectual property.
Within the WTO, however, opinions differ on the effectiveness of TRIPS. Some
believe, particularly the developed countries whose industries undertake significant
R&D expenditure, that the WTO protections of IP do not offer sufficient protection. As
a consequence, some developed countries have gone outside the WTO and used bilateral
agreements to secure their IP rights. (We discuss further the protection of IP in Chapter 6.)
Civil society groups have expressed concern that although the TRIPS agreement within
the WTO had been strengthened in favour of developing countries by giving them easier
access to IP, it was now being circumvented by bilateral agreements. These bilateral
agreements are in favour of the industries of the developed countries, with detrimental
effects on the citizens of the poorer members of the WTO (see Another Perspective:
‘Patents versus patients’).
Market access The fourth issue is the tariff protection of non-agricultural products and
services imposed by the emerging countries. In the WTO negotiations, the developed
countries have pushed for a reduction in the industrial tariffs of these emerging economies.
They claim that these markets have been closed to their manufacture exports by the
high tariffs. Some, although limited, agreement on liberalisation was achieved during the
initial phases of the Doha Round. For example, countries with big pharmaceutical sectors
acquiesced to demands from African, Asian and Latin American nations on the issue of
drug patents and generic drugs. The TRIPS agreement declares that WTO regulation on
intellectual property ‘does not and should not prevent members from taking measures
to protect public health’. The United States bowed to pressure from virtually every other
nation to negotiate revisions of anti-dumping rules, which the United States has used
extensively to protect its steel producers from foreign competition. The European Union
had to scale back its efforts to include environmental policy in the trade talks, primarily
because of pressure from developing nations that see environmental protection policies as
trade barriers by another name.
Progress in the Doha Round of global trade talks over the past decade, however, has
been minimal when compared to the agenda of unresolved issues, despite the urging of
influential organisations such as the G8 + 5 to complete the round.67 The key stumbling
blocks remain the differences among major WTO members on agricultural trade and
CHAPTER 3
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd 137
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
137
08/06/19 07:44 PM
industrial market access. The United States, the European Union and Japan are reluctant to
make significant cuts to their agricultural assistance packages. India and Indonesia, as low
per capita income countries, insist on maintaining the right to impose ‘safeguard’ tariffs
to protect their own farmers in the case of a sudden surge in food imports. Low-income
countries argue that they should be given the flexibility to be able to impose such tariffs
to protect their small-scale farmers, even if it means breaching pre-Doha bound tariffs.
Larger emerging market economies such as Brazil, India, Chile and Turkey remain reluctant
to open up their industrial goods and services markets to foreign competition, and in the
case of India this extends to agricultural products as well. In addition, the current trade
environment, with aggressive imposition of selective tariffs by the United States, is not
boding well for further general opening.
ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
PATENTS VERSUS PATIENTS
© Tom Grill/Getty Images
In 2001, at the commencement of the Doha Round,
WTO members amended the TRIPS agreement.
The intellectual property rules were relaxed to allow
developing countries easier and more affordable access
to generic pharmaceuticals to counter life-threatening
diseases such as HIV/AIDS. The concession was
permitted under a public health safeguard exemption.
The US government, allegedly at the behest of its
pharmaceutical industry, has been accused of seeking
higher levels of IP protection in developing countries
than applied at the time of the WTO safeguards
agreement. Outside the WTO framework, the United
States has negotiated numerous bilateral free trade
agreements that impose what are described as ‘TRIPSplus’ IP rules. These rules weaken or eliminate the public
safeguards allowed under TRIPS. The time period for IP
protection of branded and patented drugs is extended
and parallel imports are limited. Brand name companies
are able to conceal for a longer period of time data
that generic companies would use to bring their own
versions of drugs to the market. Generic production and
competition is reduced and drug prices remain high.
Access to the more affordable generics is delayed.
SOURCE: Oxfam, ‘Patents vs patients: five years after the Doha Declaration’, Policy and Analysis, 95 (14 November 2006), accessed via www.oxfam.org/​
en/​policy on 30 January 2007.
It remains to be seen if and when the Doha Round of talks will be completed. At
a meeting in late 2011, the WTO Trade Negotiations Committee concluded that an
agreement on agriculture, non-agriculture market access, trade remedies and intellectual
property was unlikely to be achievable in the near term.68 The last WTO ministerial
138
PART 2
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd
138
08/06/19 07:44 PM
meeting was held in Nairobi in December 2015 and no meeting has been held since.69 It is
now accepted that, although not formally concluded, the Doha Round, and the agenda it
represents, is informally ‘dead’.
New contexts, new agenda for Doha
The relevance of the Doha Round agenda has come under question for two reasons. The
first set of questions relates to the plight of the developing countries and the perceived
failure of the Doha Round to deliver on the promise that it would be a ‘development’
round, a promise offered to get the developing countries to buy into another round of
trade liberalisation talks. According to the critics, developing countries were expecting
special and differential treatment in their favour in negotiated agreements. Expectations
were raised, for example, that the rich countries would reform their agricultural policies to
end the dumping of surplus product. The agreements would provide developing countries
with sufficient ‘policy space’, as with ‘safeguard’ tariffs, to protect their vulnerable farmers
and infant manufacturing and service industries, and the negotiations would include
increasing the access to rich-country markets for the manufactures and farm products of
the developing countries.
Instead, according to the critics, the Doha Round descended into a rather traditional
‘market-access’ round with negotiations crafted more around the interests of the developed
countries by focusing on issues such as agricultural and non-agricultural market access,
access to the market for services and the protection of intellectual property. This led one
critic to ask, ‘What happened to “development” in the WTO’s Doha Round?’70
In the meantime, the developed countries, using their bargaining power, have gone
outside the WTO framework and negotiated bilateral and regional trade agreements
which have included rules governing FDI, services, intellectual property and government
procurement that grant more favourable conditions than could have been negotiated at the
WTO, yet do nothing about trade-distorting agricultural subsidies. These agreements were
viewed with angst by the developing world because they both place severe restrictions
on the very policies that developing countries need to fight poverty and inequality and
threaten the multilateral trade system. According to the critics, to restore the credibility
of the Doha Round and to continue to champion the causes of multilateralism and the
benefits of trade and investment liberalisation, the Doha Round needs to be put back on
the ‘development’ track.71
The second set of questions relates to the fundamental shifts that have occurred in
the global economy since 2001, leading one group of researchers to conclude, ‘The Doha
process has been Nero-like in dwelling on issues of relatively minor consequence while
the burning issues of the day are not even on the agenda’.72 Between 2002 and 2007, the
world experienced the largest consecutive period of economic growth ever. Since then
the landscape has changed from one of surpluses to one of shortages. Today the issue is
the threat to economic security, broadly defined. The rising price of commodities has
threatened the food and energy security of countries. The global recession of post-2007 has
strengthened the belief of the middle class and workers in developed countries that freer
trade will threaten their economic security and standard of living.
There is concern that the increasing volume of sovereign wealth funds could threaten
the financial security of countries as sudden changes (perhaps politically motivated) may
destabilise foreign currency exchange rates and share markets. There is the added threat to
national security if these funds gain control of strategic industries. And there is the threat
of the effect of climate change on environmental security. The rules being negotiated
at Doha do not have sufficient scope to address these security issues adequately.73 For
example, two types of trade policy interventions have exacerbated the food crisis, export
restrictions on food and trade-related biofuels policies in the industrial countries.
CHAPTER 3
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd 139
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
139
08/06/19 07:44 PM
The lack of progress at Doha has the potential to seriously erode the legitimacy of the
WTO and multilateralism. Does multilateralism still matter? Although there has been little
recent progress on trade and FDI liberalisation at the multilateral level (see Figure 3.3), trade
in goods and services and investment flows have been continuing to grow. This growth,
in large part, is due to the rapid expansion of the number of regional trade agreements.
This is the very time, however, when multilateralism may matter more than ever. There are
many salient issues where there is a commonality of interests that need to be dealt with
at a global level including global terrorism, food security and climate change. And there
are the issues relevant to the developing countries that now make up the vast majority of
the WTO membership and include the emerging global trading powerhouses of Russia,
China and India. The developed countries may find more comfort in bargaining with these
emerging powers in a multilateral context than a bilateral or regional context.
FIGURE 3.3
FDI regulatory changes 2007–17:
liberalising and restricting
(percentage)
90
80
70
Percentage
SOURCE: Drawn from data from UNCTAD,
World Investment Report 2018, Table III.1,
p.80, accessed via https://unctad.org/en/
PublicationsLibrary/wir2018_en.pdf on 7
March 2019.
100
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
2007
2008
Liberalising
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
Restricting
REGIONAL ECONOMIC INTEGRATION
The move towards regional economic integration
REGIONAL ECONOMIC
INTEGRATION (REI)
The integration of economies arising
from agreements among countries to
reduce the barriers to the international
flow of goods, services and factors of
production among them
EUROPEAN UNION (EU)
A group of European nations,
originally established as a customs
union, now well progressed towards
an economic union and with some
features of a political union
140
PART 2
As noted earlier, the last few decades have witnessed an unprecedented proliferation
of regional trade arrangements. National governments have been active in negotiating
agreements with other selected national governments to facilitate increased cooperation
among themselves. The political economy of trade and investment extends to increased
government involvement in negotiating regional economic agreements. This is evidence
of an accelerated trend towards a reliance on regional agreements as opposed to the
more global and multilateral agreements to trade and investment liberalisation conducted
under the auspices of the WTO. Many of these regional agreements are bilateral. As
these agreements aim to liberalise cross-border trade and investment flows between the
signatory countries, their economies become more closely integrated. Regional economic
integration (REI) arises from agreements (usually but not always among countries in a
geographic region) to reduce to varying degrees the barriers to the free flow of goods,
services, capital and human resources across national borders. The European Union, the
ASEAN Free Trade Area (AFTA), the Japan–Australia Economic Partnership Agreement
(JAEPA), the United States–Mexico–Canada Agreement (USMCA) (NAFTA) and Asia–Pacific
Economic Cooperation (APEC) are examples of REI, at varying degrees of integration.
Nowhere has the movement towards REI been more comprehensive than in Europe.
While the seeds for the formation of the European Union were sown back in 1951, on 1
January 1993 the European Union (EU) formally removed many barriers to doing business
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd
140
08/06/19 07:44 PM
across borders within the EU in an attempt to create a single market. The member states,
with a few exceptions, have adopted a single currency, the euro. They established over
time EU-wide supranational political and economic institutions in an attempt to harmonise
economic policy across all members. In 2007, the EU expanded to 27 countries covering
most of the continent of Europe. The current membership of 28 is shown in Map 3.1.
(However, the EU could shrink back to 27 if the United Kingdom leaves in 2019.) The
EU has the world’s third-largest population after China and India, with, as of 1 January
2018, a population of about 512.6 million people74 and with a nominal GDP estimated at
$18.8 trillion (nominal) representing around 22 per cent of the global economy.75 As the
EU has grown, it has become a major global economic and political power.
Similar, but less ambitious, moves towards REI via bilateral and regional trade agreements
are being pursued elsewhere in the world and they are proliferating. Australia has negotiated
many such agreements. Australia and New Zealand established the Closer Economic
Relations (CER) Trade Agreement in 1983, but more recently Australia has completed
bilateral trade agreements with the United States, Thailand, Singapore, Chile, Korea,
Malaysia, Indonesia, China and Japan. Australia and New Zealand completed a plurilateral
trade agreement, a region-to-region multi-country agreement: the ASEAN–Australia–New
Zealand Free Trade Area (AANZFTA). AANZFTA exists while at the same time Australia
and New Zealand individually retain their bilateral agreements with a number of these same
ASEAN countries. Australia is also involved in negotiations on regional agreements—a Pacific
Agreement on Closer Economic Relations (PACER) with Pacific Island Forum members, the
China–Australia Free Trade Agreement (ChAFTA) and the TPP-11.
Elsewhere in the world, Canada, Mexico and the United States long ago implemented
NAFTA, which has been replaced with USMCA. In South America in 1991, Argentina,
Brazil, Paraguay (currently suspended) and Uruguay implemented an agreement known as
Mercosur, with Venezuela joining in 2012. In 2003, AFTA came into full effect between
the original five member states of the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN)—
Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines, Singapore and Thailand—but has since been expanded
to include Myanmar (formerly Burma), Cambodia, Laos, Brunei Darussalam and Vietnam
(see Map 3.2). The Common Market for Eastern and Southern Africa (COMESA), established
in 1994, currently has 19 member countries, stretching from Egypt in the north to
Swaziland in the south of the African continent.
The Asia–Pacific Economic Cooperation (APEC) was founded in 1990 at the suggestion of
Australia. APEC currently has 21 member states, including such economic powerhouses as the
United States, Russia, Japan and China. APEC is much more of a forum for discussion about the
ways member states could work together for greater economic integration than an agreement
that binds member governments to implement trade and investment liberalisation. Trade and
investment liberalisation goals are to be achieved by members acting unilaterally according to
their own, individually constructed action plans that are voluntary and non-binding.
While the move towards REI is generally seen positively, some observers worry that
it will lead to a world in which regional trade blocs compete against each other. In this
possible future scenario, free trade will exist within each bloc, but each bloc will develop
a ‘fortress’ mentality and protect its market from outside competition, possibly with tariffs.
The spectre of the EU and USMCA turning into economic fortresses that shut out foreign
producers with high-tariff barriers is worrisome to those who believe in unrestricted free
trade. If such a situation were to materialise, the resulting decline in trade between blocs
could more than offset the gains from free trade within blocs.
With these issues in mind, the following sections will explore the economic and
political debate surrounding REI, paying particular attention to the economic and political
benefits and costs of integration. We begin by examining the levels of integration that are
theoretically possible.
CHAPTER 3
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd 141
CLOSER ECONOMIC
RELATIONS (CER)
A free trade agreement between
Australia and New Zealand dating
from 1983
NORTH AMERICAN FREE TRADE
AGREEMENT (NAFTA)
Free trade area between Canada,
Mexico and the United States
MERCOSUR
Pact between Argentina, Brazil,
Paraguay, Venezuela and Uruguay to
establish a free trade area
ASSOCIATION OF SOUTHEAST
ASIAN NATIONS (ASEAN)
Formed in 1967 and has since
established a free trade agreement
involving Brunei, Cambodia,
Indonesia, Laos, Myanmar, Malaysia,
the Philippines, Singapore, Thailand
and Vietnam
COMMON MARKET FOR EASTERN
AND SOUTHERN AFRICA (COMESA)
Established in 1994 with now 19
countries of Eastern and Southern
Africa working towards forming a
customs union
ASIA–PACIFIC ECONOMIC
COOPERATION (APEC)
Made up of 21 member states
whose goal is to increase multilateral
cooperation in view of the economic
rise of the Pacific nations
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
141
08/06/19 07:44 PM
Lisbon
French
Guyana (FR)
PORTUGAL
S
P
A
I
Madrid
C EL T IC
S EA
N
BAY OF
BISCAY
I R ELA ND
Réunion (FR)
Mayotte islands (FR)
Canary Is. (ES)
Madeira (PT)
UNITED
Paris
M
E
GULF OF
LIONS
D
I
SOURCE: www.consilium.europa.eu/media/30582/061_14_carte_a4_en_web.pdf
T
E
F
E
R
R
A
K
RW
Copenhagen
NO
D E N MA R K
A G
S K
O
AY
R
R
A
E
A
D
R
SL O VENIA
Ljubljana
T
N
IA
IC
S
A
E
A
S
E
HUNGAR Y
A
Budapest
LATVIA
Riga
ESTONIA
Tallinn
Helsinki
FINLAND
Athens
GREECE
A EG EAN
S EA
Luxembourg
Bulgaria
Romania
Slovenia
Slovakia
Finland
Sweden
Spain
France
Croatia
Italy
Cyprus
CYPRUS
Nicosia
The protocol order of the Member States is based on
the alphabetical order of their geographical names
in the original language.
United Kingdom
Portugal
Greece
Latvia
Poland
Ireland
EA
Austria
Netherlands
Germany
Estonia
Malta
Denmark
Hungary
Lithuania
Belgium
Czech Republic
WHITE
SEA
BARENTS
SEA
Bucharest
B ULG AR IA
Sofia
RO MAN IA
Vilnius
LITHUANIA
Warsaw
SL OV A K IA
Bratislava
IONIAN
SEA
CROATIA
Zagreb
Vienna
A USTRIA
M A LT A Valletta
N
TYRRHENIAN
SEA
Rome
Prague
Stockholm
P O L A N D
B
SWEDEN
CZ ECH R EPUBL IC
Berlin
ITAL Y
G E R M A N Y
A
SE
Luxembourg
LUXEMBOURG
BELGIUM
Brussels
THE
NETHERLANDS
Amsterdam
F R A N C E
C HANNE L
London
KINGDOM
LIS H
ENG
Dublin
NORTH
SEA
MAP 3.1 European Union members, 2019 (prior to slated exit of the United Kingdom)
Council of the
European Union
Martinique (FR)
Guadeloupe (FR)
Azores (PT)
NON-CONTINENTAL AND OVERSEAS TERRITORIES
OF MEMBER STATES
O
C
I
T
N
A
L
T
A
N
A
E
C
L
A
G ULF
OF
BO
TH
NI
S E
A
C
I
T
© European Union, 2019
S
142
K
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd
AC
PART 2
BL
142
A
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
08/06/19 07:44 PM
© Vector Value/Shutterstock
MAP 3.2 ASEAN countries, 2018
Levels of economic integration
LO 3.4
Several levels of economic integration are possible in theory. Figure 3.4 shows the different
levels of integration and how they differ. From the least integrated to the most integrated—
that is, from the shallowest to the deepest form of integration—are the free trade area
(FTA), a customs union, a common market, an economic union and a political union as
the most highly developed integrated area. There is a strong hierarchy of requirements as
development from a FTA towards a political union progresses. The FTA as it relates to the
trade in goods is the most common form, followed by the customs union. Many regional
trade agreements cover international trade in both goods and services.76
A basic reason for the prevalence of FTAs is that the deeper the level of integration, the
greater the loss of autonomy that member states have over not only trade and investment
matters but also a broad range of domestic monetary and fiscal matters. There is concern
over the loss of national sovereignty. A FTA, for example, typically concentrates on
reducing import tariffs and quotas but a fully-developed economic union requires, among
other features, a common currency, which involves a much greater sacrifice of national
sovereignty, as Britain’s retention of its pound sterling attests, even though it is (at the
time of writing) a member of the EU. In a free trade area, all barriers to the trade of goods
and services among member countries are removed. Each country, however, is allowed to
determine its own trade policies with non-members. For example, the tariffs placed on the
products of non-member countries may vary from member to member. CER and USMCA
are examples of FTAs.
Because members in an FTA typically have different tariffs on their imports from
non-members, it is necessary to have rules of origin. Rules of origin are designed to
prevent trade deflection—that is, the re-routing of imports from non-members through the
CHAPTER 3
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd 143
FREE TRADE AREA
An area in which all barriers to the
trade of goods and services among
member countries are removed
RULES OF ORIGIN
Rules of origin are designed to
prevent the re-routing of imports
from outside a free trade area
through the member that has the
lowest trade barriers
TRADE DEFLECTION
The re-routing of imports from nonmembers through the member that
has the lowest tariffs in a free trade
area
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
143
08/06/19 07:44 PM
member that has the lowest tariffs. The common criterion adopted for a rule of origin is
the proportion of local content. For example, in the case of CER, the origin of a product
is determined by the proportion of the value added to the inputs within Australia and
New Zealand, typically 50 per cent for manufactured products, to enable the product to
qualify for preferential treatment.77 Basically, rules of origin arise from the discriminatory
preferential trade treatment that members of an FTA receive from each other but, unlike
the MFN principle of the WTO, are not accorded to non-members. Rules of origin are
complex and require a bureaucracy to implement them.
FIGURE 3.4
Levels of integration, general
characteristics
Increasing integration, complexity and loss of autonomy
Supranational
government
Common currency,
harmonised
monetary and
fiscal policy
Liberalised
movement of the
factors of
production among
members
Common external
tariffs
Free trade among
members
Free trade
area
CUSTOMS UNION
A group of countries committed
to eliminating trade barriers and
adopting a common external trade
policy
COMMON MARKET
A group of countries committed to
eliminating trade barriers, adopting
a common external trade policy, and
allowing factors of production to
move freely between members
144
PART 2
Customs
union
Common
market
Economic
union
Political
union
A customs union eliminates trade barriers between member countries and, in addition,
adopts a common external trade policy. Establishment of a common external trade policy
necessitates significant administrative machinery to oversee trade relations with nonmembers. The European Union began as a customs union but it has now moved beyond
this stage. The Andean Community, consisting of the Latin American nations of Bolivia,
Colombia, Ecuador and Peru, seeks to be a customs union.78 The Andean Community
established free trade between member countries and imposed common external tariffs
on products imported from outside at one of four levels (5, 10, 15 or 20 per cent of the
product’s ad valorem value) depending on the product’s level of processing and the
domestic need.
The previous levels of integration address trade barriers. A common market has no
barriers to trade between member countries, includes a common external trade policy,
but involves a greater degree of integration by allowing factors of production to move
freely between members. Human resources and capital are free to move because there
are no restrictions on immigration, emigration, or cross-border flows of capital between
member countries. Establishing a common market demands a significant degree of
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd
144
08/06/19 07:44 PM
harmony and cooperation on fiscal, monetary and employment policies. Achieving this
degree of cooperation has proven very difficult. This level of integration is made all
the more difficult while immigration remains a politically sensitive issue. For years, the
European Union functioned as a common market, although it has now moved beyond this
stage. Mercosur, the South American grouping, hopes to eventually establish itself as a
common market.
An economic union entails even closer economic integration and cooperation than
a common market. Like the common market, an economic union involves the free flow
of products and factors of production between member countries and the adoption of a
common external trade policy, but it also requires a common currency, harmonisation
of members’ tax rates, and a common monetary and fiscal policy. Such a high degree of
integration demands a coordinating bureaucracy and a significant sacrifice of national
sovereignty to supranational institutions. The European Union is an economic union,
although an imperfect one since not all its members have adopted the common currency
(the euro) and differences in fiscal policy and regulations across members still remain.
The 2011 eurozone crisis highlighted the dangers of a partial move towards an economic
union—the adoption of a common currency but failure to harmonise members’ fiscal and
monetary stances. We discuss the eurozone crisis in more detail in Chapter 4.
The move towards economic union raises the issue of how to make the supranational
institutions and coordinating bureaucracy accountable to the citizens of member
nations. This happens through a political union in which a central political apparatus
coordinates the economic, social and foreign policy of the member states. The EU is on
the road towards a political union (interestingly, even though it has not achieved fullydeveloped economic union status). The European Parliament, which is playing an ever
more important role in the EU, has been directly elected by citizens of the EU countries
since the late 1970s. In addition, the Council of Ministers (the controlling, decision-making
body of the EU) is composed of government ministers from each EU member. Historically,
and somewhat peripherally to this discussion, Australia and the United States provide
examples of political unions. Once independent states in these countries have been
effectively combined into a single nation, politically, with all the features of an economic
union. Ultimately, the EU may move towards a similar federal structure: the United States
of Europe.
But that is a big if, as the ‘Brexit’ (a term conflating the words ‘British’ and ‘Exit’) crisis
shows. A referendum held in the United Kingdom on 23 June 2016 asked voters whether
the United Kingdom should leave or remain in the EU. Prior to the vote most pundits
expected the referendum to fail. But the ‘leave’ side won by 52 per cent to 48 per cent and
a long process was set in motion that was still ongoing at the time of writing. Secession
from more complete political unions is very hard or impossible.79 The United States fought
a bloody civil war in 1861–65 over secession by the southern states, with the union being
victorious, and secession has never been seriously considered by any state or region since.
But the EU’s political union is a work in progress, choosing a gradual approach which has
had the benefit of achieving some real integration but at a cost of potential instability. The
ultimate fate of the EU remains uncertain.
ECONOMIC UNION
A group of countries committed to
removing trade barriers, adopting
a common currency, harmonising
tax rates, and pursuing a common
external trade policy
POLITICAL UNION
A central political apparatus
coordinating the economic, social
and foreign policy of its member
states
The case for regional economic integration
In this section, we examine the economic and political arguments for REI. We also
identify two impediments that explain why most attempts to achieve comprehensive
REI have been contentious and are faltering. In the section following, we look at the case
against integration.
CHAPTER 3
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd 145
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
145
08/06/19 07:44 PM
The economic case for integration
STATIC EFFECT
The effect of freer trade on the
economy and business resulting
from a reallocation of resources from
a less efficient to a more efficient
use of resources
DYNAMIC EFFECT
The ongoing effect of freer trade on
the economy and business resulting
from the stimulus of expanding
markets and more intense
competition
The economic case for REI consists of essentially the economic arguments for free
trade. Freer trade as a result of REI will allow firms and countries to shift resources and
specialise in the production of goods and services that they can produce most efficiently,
resulting in economic growth and higher standards of living. This reallocation to a more
efficient use of resources is the static effect of freer trade. With free trade also comes
access to larger markets and more intense international competition, which stimulate
enterprise and innovation. This longer term, ongoing effect is the dynamic effect of freer
trade. We identified earlier in this chapter how FDI can transfer technological, marketing
and managerial know-how to host nations. In sum, economic theory suggests that opening
up economies to free trade and investment is an economic growth, positive-sum game, in
which all participating countries stand to gain in the longer run.
Although the WTO has been moving the world towards a free trade regime on a
multilateral basis, in a world of many nations and many political ideologies, it is very difficult
to get all countries to agree on a common set of rules. It has not yet happened, and free
trade globally is unlikely ever to be achieved. REI can be seen as an attempt to achieve the
gains from the free flow of trade and investment between countries that have not yet been
attainable under the WTO. REI is a second-best outcome when global free trade is unlikely.
The political case for integration
TEST PREP
Preparing for a test?
Use LearnSmart to
help you remember
what you’ve learned.
The political argument for REI is of no lesser importance than is the economic case.
Linking neighbouring economies and making them increasingly economically dependent
on each other creates incentives for political cooperation and reduces the potential for
conflict. In addition, by grouping their economies, the countries can enhance their
political weight in world affairs. This leads to the establishment of cooperation and
political dialogue with global economic and political powers that a country as an
individual would be unlikely to achieve. In fact, the EU was originally initiated to best
ensure European countries would not again go to war among themselves. The argument is
that when independent countries are inextricably tied economically, there are compelling
incentives not to engage in political hostilities.
Impediments to integration
Comprehensive REI has not been easy for countries to achieve or sustain. One impediment
is that REI will generate winners and losers, and the losers will be an ongoing source
of political opposition. Moving to a freer trade regime involves painful adjustments. For
example, progress on the Japan–Australia Economic Partnership Agreement (JAEPA),
particularly in relation to agricultural issues, was slow because of the Japanese government’s
reluctance to reduce the assistance given to Japanese farmers. The Japanese stance on
agriculture was motivated by a self-sufficiency imperative resulting from the food shortages
and starvation experienced by Japan during and after World War II. Again, this is an issue
of national sovereignty, which takes us to the second impediment to integration.
A second impediment to integration, very much related to the first, arises from
concerns over national sovereignty, which we identified earlier to explain the prevalence
of FTAs. This has been a major stumbling block in the EU. To achieve full economic union,
the EU introduced a common currency, the euro, controlled by a central EU bank. Most
countries joined, but the United Kingdom refrained, unwilling to relinquish control of its
monetary policy to the EU. This was in part due to the financial sector in London, which
feared losing some control over its business, and in part because of pride in economic
independence under the pound sterling, a currency that has existed for many centuries.
(This was also a prime reason for not joining the eurozone as well.)
146
PART 2
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd
146
08/06/19 07:44 PM
As mentioned earlier, issues of national sovereignty have become major concerns for
the United Kingdom as the public voted to exit the EU, a process that created profound
problems for the UK government. No other country has elected to exit the EU and, as
such, there are no guidelines on how this exit is to be achieved. Brexit set off extended
negotiations between the UK government and EU bureaucracy, but no final determination
had been achieved at the time of writing. The UK parliament voted against adopting the
terms of the exit put forward by former British Prime Minister Theresa May, an historic
parliamentary loss to a British prime minister. Brexit is an unprecedented phenomenon
in the context of regional economic integration, as exit from such a formal agreement is
contrary to the general trend of increased regional economic integration and countries’
willingness to engage in increased economic integration. There remains much uncertainty
as to the final outcome regarding Brexit, but it is clear that issues of national sovereignty
remain high even in our globalising world.80
The case against regional economic integration
Irrespective of Brexit, most agree that any reduction in trade barriers is likely to be
beneficial and that REI agreements such as FTAs are building blocks towards freer global
trade—freer in the sense that totally free trade does not seem possible. Some economists,
however, have expressed concern that the benefits of regional integration have been
oversold while the costs have often been ignored.81 They point out that the benefits
of regional integration are determined by the extent of trade creation, as opposed to
trade diversion. Trade creation occurs when an FTA can create trade that would not
have existed otherwise. For example, it occurs when a member’s higher-cost producers
are replaced by the lower-cost producers of other members from within the FTA.
The benefits of trade creation are about replacing an inefficient supplier with a more
efficient supplier from within the FTA, which is a positive static effect. Trade creation
will also generate dynamic effects. Trade diversion occurs when lower-cost non-member
suppliers are replaced by higher-cost suppliers from within the FTA. As a result of the
FTA, trade is diverted away from a more efficient supplier outside the FTA towards a less
efficient supplier within the FTA, a negative static effect. Under the right conditions, a
regional FTA will benefit the world only if the amount of trade it creates exceeds the
amount it diverts.
Although, by strict interpretation, FTAs violate the WTO’s Most Favoured Nation
principle, in theory WTO rules should ensure that an FTA does not result in trade
diversion. These rules allow FTAs to be formed only if the members set tariffs that
are not higher or more restrictive to outsiders than the ones previously in effect. A
study of the ASEAN FTA found that the FTA did not lessen import growth from nonmembers. It also found that the reduction of tariffs among members flowed on to a
reduction of tariffs to non-members; that is, in accord with MFN tariff reduction.82
However, as we saw earlier, GATT and the WTO do not cover some non-tariff barriers.
As a result, regional trade blocs could emerge whose markets are protected from outside
competition by high non-tariff barriers. In such cases, the trade diversion effects might
outweigh the trade creation effects. Another potentially trade-distorting outcome of
the proliferation of FTAs is the increasing bureaucracy associated with the administration
and enforcement of the diverse and overlapping rules that govern FTAs. The costs
of doing international business in certain regions may increase, diverting trade and
reducing overall productivity.
CHAPTER 3
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd 147
TRADE CREATION
Occurs within a free trade area due
to the replacement of high-cost
domestic or external producers by
low-cost producers inside the free
trade area
TRADE DIVERSION
Occurs within a free trade area
when low-cost external suppliers
are replaced by high-cost suppliers
inside the free trade area
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
147
08/06/19 07:44 PM
FOCUS ON
MANAGERIAL IMPLICATIONS
How should the international
manager respond to changes
in government policies regulating international trade
and FDI? There are two approaches to this question.
The first concerns the impact of trade and investment
barriers on a company’s strategy. The second relates to
the role that companies can play in influencing trade and
investment policies. How does the accelerated movement
towards regional economic integration affect international
business? International businesses need to consider
how to position themselves so that they can realise the
opportunities that REI creates and minimise any threats.
LO 3.5
BARRIERS AND FIRM STRATEGY
Trade and FDI barriers affect a company’s location
choices by constraining into what countries the
company can disperse its value activities. For example,
import tariff barriers put a foreign company at a
competitive disadvantage vis-à-vis local competitors.
In response, the company may find it economical to
relocate production facilities to the protectionist country
so that it can compete on an even footing and benefit
itself from the protection. Import quotas may encourage
a similar relocation response even though it may result
in higher production costs. In order to conform to local
content regulations, a company may have to locate
more production activities in a given market than it
would otherwise. Even when trade barriers do not exist,
the company may still want to locate some production
activities in a given country to reduce the threat of trade
barriers being imposed in the future. Other strategies
are affected. For example, the threat of anti-dumping
action limits the ability of a company to use aggressive
pricing to gain market share in a country.
Similarly, FDI barriers such as ownership restraints
and performance requirements reduce the company’s
flexibility to respond to competitive market forces. It
may be forced to commit more resources, or a different
mix of resources and products, to a location than is
optimal. One strategy the company can adopt is to play
one country or level of government off against another
in order to reduce or evade investment barriers.
The strategy, however, could be detrimental to the
company in the long run as the abandoned countries
may restrict the company’s imports in the future.
148
PART 2
POLICY IMPLICATIONS
Companies can and do exert a strong influence on
government policy. This influence can encourage
protectionism, for example, as we saw in the cases
involving anti-dumping policies, or it can encourage
removal of barriers, such as the push by farmers
through the Cairns Group to reduce agricultural
protection. It is probably in the best long-run interests
of the business community to encourage their
governments to aggressively promote freer trade and
investment, and to achieve this by strengthening the
multilateral trade system of the WTO, even though
in the short run they are benefiting from bilateral
and regional trade agreements. Companies have
much more to gain from government efforts to open
protected markets to imports and FDI than from
government efforts to support certain domestic
industries. For example, companies of all national
origins increasingly depend for their competitive
advantage on globally dispersed supply chains and
production systems. Where a company depends
on a global supply chain, for that company to argue
for protection results not so much in a ‘beggar-thyneighbour’ outcome but a ‘beggar-thyself’ outcome.
International business groups have been a driving force
in the formation of bilateral and regional FTAs.83 They
have had success in lobbying their governments to
win market access for their goods and services, which
they were unable to achieve through the multilateral
WTO system. They have been able to use their political
influence to have strong and binding agreements
related to FDI and intellectual property included in
bilateral RTAs, which are not included in WTO rules. For
example, the Australia–United States FTA (AUSFTA)
applies the principle of national treatment to FDI and
raises the threshold value of FDI, below which no host
government review is required.
Bilateral FTAs, however, have sometimes caused
a political backlash against foreign companies,
particularly when there is significant difference between
the economic and political powers of the two member
countries. MNCs are seen as being able to exploit the
favourable power differential of their home government.
For example, the US pharmaceutical MNCs have been
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd
148
08/06/19 07:44 PM
able to have regulations governing the development,
production and pricing of pharmaceutical products in
partner countries relaxed via bilateral FTAs. Such power
under AUSFTA brought about changes to Australia’s
Pharmaceutical Benefits Scheme. (See also Another
Perspective: ‘Patents versus patients’.)
If the political backlash is potentially significant, there
is need for the MNCs to allay the concerns of host
governments and of the relevant civil society groups
in order to win their support. Corporate Watch (www.
corporatewatch.org.uk), Corpwatch (www.corpwatch.
org) and Oxfam International (www.oxfam.org) are
three organisations that communicate positive and
negative stories about MNCs and their operations in
both developed and developing countries.
OPPORTUNITIES FROM REGIONAL
ECONOMIC INTEGRATION
The creation of a single integrated region opens up
markets that were formerly protected from foreign
competition. The single market becomes more
attractive to companies external to the region, and for
companies in the region, foreign competition intensifies.
Nonetheless, to fully exploit the opportunities, it may pay
companies external to the region to set up subsidiaries
within the region. Opportunities arise from the inherent
lower costs of doing business in a single market as
opposed to many national markets. Free movement of
goods across borders, harmonised product standards
and simplified tax regimes make it possible for
companies to realise significant transaction cost savings.
There are also location economies and economies of
scale. Production can be centralised in those locations
in the region where the mix of factor costs and skills
is optimal. As a cautionary note, however, enduring
differences in culture and competitive practices, as
across the EU members, can still limit the ability of
companies to realise cost economies by centralising
production and producing a standardised product.84
THREATS FROM REGIONAL ECONOMIC
INTEGRATION
REI also presents a number of threats to international
business. The business environment within each
grouping will become increasingly more competitive.
For example, before the Single European Market came
CHAPTER 3
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd 149
into force in 1993, a Volkswagen Golf cost 55 per cent
more in Britain than in Denmark and 29 per cent more
in Ireland than in Greece.85 Over time, these price
differentials virtually vanished as a result of the EU
single market.
A threat to those companies outside these trading
areas arises from the likely long-term improvement
in the competitive position of many companies within
the areas. This is particularly relevant in the EU,
where many companies that historically had a highcost structure were limited in their ability to compete
globally with North American and Asian companies.
The creation of a single market and the resulting
increased competition in the EU forces EU companies
to reduce their cost structure. This is transforming
many companies into efficient global competitors.
Another threat to companies outside the region is
the threat of being shut out of the single market by
the creation of a trade ‘fortress’. The charge that
REI might lead to a fortress mentality is most often
levelled at the EU. This tends to apply to imports and
investment in certain politically sensitive areas, such
as motor vehicle manufacturing. Non-EU companies
might be well advised, therefore, to set up their own
EU operations and so enjoy the protection afforded
by the EU.
Finally, where the level of REI has developed to that of
the EU, institutions and regulations governing business
are more uniformly and consistently applied across
the member nations. For example, this is the role of
the European Commission with respect to competition
policy. There is less opportunity for foreign investors
to exploit any differences in regulations or in the
consistency of the enforcement of these regulations
among member countries. The bargaining power of
the MNC is reduced. The European Commission is
increasingly willing and able to intervene and impose
conditions promoting competition, including the
regulation of mergers and acquisitions. This is a threat
to international business in so far as it limits the ability
of companies to pursue the corporate strategy of their
choice. The ability of an MNC to take advantage of the
political and economic power of its home government
in bilateral as well as multilateral negotiations is also
curtailed. The European Commission is responsible for
negotiating agreements such as FTAs on behalf of the
EU. It enables the member countries to speak as one in
international forums such as the WTO.
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
149
08/06/19 07:44 PM
KEY TERMS
PAGE
112 administrative trade policies
106 ad valorem tariff
112 anti-dumping policies
141Asia–Pacific Economic Cooperation
(APEC)
141Association of Southeast Asian
Nations (ASEAN)
123 balance of payments (BOP)
120 beggar-thy-neighbour policy
141 Closer Economic Relations (CER)
144 common market
141Common Market for Eastern and
Southern Africa (COMESA)
113 countervailing duties
123 current account
144 customs union
112 dumping
146 dynamic effect
145 economic union
140 European Union (EU)
130 export processing zone (EPZ)
104 free trade
143 free trade area
122 government capture
110 import quota
118 infant industry argument
110 local content requirement
141 Mercosur
134Most Favoured Nation (MFN)
principle
125 national sovereignty
134 National Treatment principle
141North American Free Trade
Agreement (NAFTA)
106 political economy
145 political union
105 protectionism
110
140
143
106
146
119
107
106
110
133
147
143
147
112
115
125
110
quota rent
regional economic integration (REI)
rules of origin
specific tariff
static effect
strategic trade policy
subsidy
tariff
tariff rate quota
trade agreement
trade creation
trade deflection
trade diversion
trade remedy
trade sanctions
transfer pricing
voluntary export restraint (VER)
SUMMARY
The goal of this chapter was to explain how the political and economic realities of international trade and FDI impact on
companies as they venture across international borders, and how governments intervene in trade and investment across
national borders. We reported the various instruments of trade and FDI policy and reviewed the political and economic
arguments for government intervention. We then described attempts to liberalise international trade and investment. At
the multilateral level, we examined the progress of liberalisation at the WTO. Most attempts at liberalisation in recent times
have occurred at the regional and bilateral levels. Following an account of how the various levels of economic integration
differ, we reviewed the economic and political debates surrounding regional economic integration. The chapter concluded
with an assessment of how business may be affected by the various government interventions in international trade and
investment and the various attempts to liberalise trade and investment at the multilateral and regional levels.
The chapter made the following points:
1. Trade policy instruments, including tariffs and non-tariffs
measures such as subsidies, anti-dumping regulations,
local content requirements and administrative
procedures tend to be pro-producer and anti-consumer.
4. The problems with protectionist trade policies are twofold:
(a) such a policy may invite retaliation, in which case all
will lose; and (b) the policy may be captured by specialinterest groups, which will distort it for their own ends.
2. Political arguments for intervention are concerned
with protecting the interests of certain groups, often at
the expense of other groups, and with using trade to
promote political goals such as foreign policy, human
rights and environmental and consumer protection.
Economic arguments for intervention are about boosting
the overall wealth of a nation.
5. While host countries benefit from FDI in terms of
resource transfer effects, employment effects and
balance-of-payments effects, there are also costs.
Governments, particularly those in developing countries,
insist on retaining autonomy over the regulation of FDI
in order to maximise its development benefits. Host
countries offer incentives to attract FDI to advance their
development policies.
3. The infant industry argument for government intervention
contends that governments should temporarily support
particular new industries. Strategic trade policy suggests
that governments can help domestic companies gain firstmover advantages in global industries where economies
of scale are important. These arguments assume that
governments can identify potentially successful industries.
150
PART 2
6. A cost to a home country of FDI is the export of jobs, and
while there are calls for restrictions on the outflow of FDI,
most restrictions on FDI are imposed by host countries.
7. The GATT and its successor, the 164-member WTO,
seek to provide a more orderly and predictable trading
framework by establishing principles and rules governing
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd
150
08/06/19 07:44 PM
the imposition of trade and investment barriers and
the resolution of trade and investment disputes among
nations.
8. The last completed round of negotiations, the Uruguay
Round, which established the WTO, strengthened
the world trading system by extending GATT rules to
services, increasing protection for intellectual property
and enhancing monitoring and enforcement mechanisms.
Progress in the current Doha Round of negotiations
on a number of longstanding, unresolved issues has
stalled. Two issues that are restricting progress are
the unwillingness to date of countries such as the
United States, the European Union and Japan to make
significant cuts to their agricultural protection and of the
developing countries, particularly the larger emerging
market economies such as Brazil, India and China, to
open up their markets to industrial goods and services.
9. New global contexts have presented new challenges for
the Doha Round to which it is not adequately responding.
Developing countries, the majority of WTO members, feel
that they are disadvantaged when required to implement
WTO agreements and, therefore, seek compensation.
The current negotiation agenda is failing to address
issues relevant to the economic security of nations and
individuals. The lack of progress in the Doha Round is
threatening multilateralism.
10. The slow progress with the WTO multilateral negotiations
on the liberalisation of international trade and investment
CHAPTER 3
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd 151
is a factor promoting the proliferation of regional and
bilateral agreements. With the move towards bilateral
agreements, many countries are members of more than
one agreement.
11. Regional and bilateral agreements can result in different
levels of economic integration. In order of increasing
integration, they include a free trade area, a customs
union, a common market, an economic union and a
political union. Few have moved beyond the free trade
area level of integration largely because of fear of loss of
national sovereignty.
12. There are political and economic arguments in favour of
regional economic integration. The economic arguments
stand on the balance between trade creation and trade
diversion effects.
13. The opening up of markets to foreign competition by
regional trade agreements creates investment and trade
opportunities and threats for companies both within and
outside these regions.
14. Trade and investment barriers act as a constraint on
a company’s ability to disperse its various production
activities to optimal locations around the globe. With
global supply chains, international business may have
more to gain from government efforts to open protected
markets to imports and foreign direct investment than
from government efforts to protect domestic industries
from foreign competition.
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
151
08/06/19 07:44 PM
INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS
GRADUATE ATTRIBUTES (IBGAs):
LEARNING AND ASSESSMENT TASKS
IBGA1: DISCIPLINE KNOWLEDGE AND SKILLS
1. While many countries recognise the benefits of
dismantling trade barriers through the multilateral
WTO system, the developing countries have significant
reservations. Establish an argument against developing
countries withdrawing from WTO negotiations on the
liberalisation of trade and investment.
2. Outline the economic and political arguments for REI.
Given these arguments, explain why there are not more
substantial examples of integration such as the EU in
the world economy. Brexit retains daily news headlines
worldwide: are the issues that have created the incentive
for the United Kingdom to want to exit the EU systemic to
the concept of REI?
IBGA3: PROBLEM SOLVING
3. Your company is considering exporting its food and
agriculture products to Malaysia, but management’s current
knowledge of the country’s trade policies and barriers for
this sector is limited. Conduct research of relevant traderelated databases to identify any information on Malaysia’s
current requirements governing trade in agriculture
products. Starting points for research could be Austrade
(www.austrade.gov.au/country-profile-index/default.aspx),
APEC Import Regulations site (www.apec.org/Home/
Groups/Committee-on-Trade-and-Investment) and the
globalEDGE site (http://globalEDGE.msu.edu). Prepare an
executive summary of your findings and an assessment of
the ease of entry to the Malaysian food market.
4. Your company exports to a country that is negotiating a
bilateral trade agreement with your home country. Your
export will be subjected to some form of trade restriction.
Your government asks your advice as to whether, from the
point of view of your business, you would prefer a tariff or
a quota to be applied. Both would be set at reasonable,
non-punitive levels. Outline your decision and the reasons
for it. You may be able to illustrate your reasoning with
arithmetic examples or diagrams.
IBGA4: ETHICAL DECISION MAKING
5. ‘Governments should not consider human rights when
granting preferential trading rights to countries.’ Debate
this issue.
6. Trade and investment liberalisation is going to harm
certain industries, companies and workers and benefit
152
PART 2
others. Role-play the positions of the various beneficiaries
and losers. During debriefing as a group, develop a set
of agreed values to guide the kinds of policies, domestic
and international, that governments should adopt when
pursuing trade policy reform.
IBGA5: COMMUNICATION
7. Prepare a table with at least four columns that
summarises the membership, goals and performance of
at least five regional trade agreements (other than the
EU, NAFTA, ASEAN and CER). Headings for the columns
could include: ‘Official name’, ‘Membership’, ‘Target
level of integration’ and ‘Current status’. ‘Current status’
could include a brief assessment of the progress towards
integration.
8. Australia and Thailand have a free trade agreement that
took effect in 2005. In 2006, Australia imposed antidumping duties in the form of increased tariffs on canned
tuna and canned pineapple imports from Thailand. Thai
imports had exceeded the quota and, as a safeguard
to protect Australian food producers, the anti-dumping
measures were triggered. You are a researcher for the
general manager of an Australian company that processes
canned tuna and pineapples in Thailand and then exports
them to Australia and other countries in the region. Prepare
a 15-minute presentation to managerial staff examining
and recommending alternatives on how the company
should respond should such an event occur again.
IBGA1: DISCIPLINE KNOWLEDGE AND SKILLS
IBGA2: CRITICAL ANALYSIS
9. CASE ANALYSIS Read again the Opening Case, ‘Unease
over China’s rare earths trade policies’ and answer the
following questions.
a. Are governments justified in identifying the mining
and refining of rare earths as a strategic priority?
b. What goals does China expect to achieve by
restricting the export of rare earths? Will these
restrictions be effective in the long run?
c. What role is the WTO expected to play in this case?
d. Whose interests are government interventions in the
mining and refining of rare earths serving?
10. CASE ANALYSIS Read the following Closing Case and
answer the questions that follow.
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd
152
08/06/19 07:44 PM
CLOSING CASE
MAKE IT AUSTRALIAN? FREE TRADE
VERSUS NATIONAL IDENTITY
The British like to joke that Australians are devoid
of culture, but Australia most definitely has a
distinct identity of its own. Australians are laid back,
informal, good-humoured, extrovert, beach-dwelling
individualists with an unusual affection for barbecued
prawns. Australia is known for its fair-mindedness,
tolerance, forthrightness and accomplishments in
art, sport and industry. Australians are entitled
to regard their defining differences as something
worth cultivating and protecting and, like other
countries, Australia has stories that need retelling:
stories of crises, failure, hardship, enmity and errors
of judgement that challenged its people and shaped
their character. International law acknowledges that
all nations, even those without their own states, are
entitled to preserve and celebrate their distinctive
attributes and histories in order to maintain their
collective identities. Indeed, this principle is
foundational to contemporary international order.
Problematically, healthy contemporary international
order also necessitates that countries should engage
in unobstructed exchange with one another. Clearly,
there is a contradiction at work here, because the more
business a country has with another, the more like
that other nation it will become. As globalisation has
proceeded over the last half century, virtually every
CHAPTER 3
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd 153
© structuresxx/Shutterstock
Trade policy is not just about taxing incoming freight
from abroad to fund government spending, or cynical
vote-winning protectionism that delays structural
economic adjustment. It is ultimately a matter of
balancing the general good of international commerce
against legitimate domestic priorities that demand
tight control over cross-border flows. One such
priority is the cultivation and protection of national
culture. A nation is not merely a geographic market: it
is defined by the values, practices, symbols and sense
of history and destiny that its members share.
country has opened itself to influences from abroad,
principally in the form of traded goods and services,
foreign investment, and immigration and tourism.
This has given rise to dire warnings that national
identities are being erased in the face of global cultural
homogenisation, or overwhelmed by the sheer volume
of cultural product from the United States.
In response to the threat of erosion of national
identity posed by trade and investment liberalisation,
many countries, Australia included, legislate special
protections for industries associated with the
reproduction of their distinctive culture, such as
music, film and television. Limited protection of these
industries is permitted under multilateral trading
rules administered by the WTO, on the grounds that
they uphold non-commercial values and should not be
subject to the rules applied to general manufactured
goods, like washing machines and sports equipment,
or services like insurance and banking. The General
Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS) adopts what
is known as a positive list approach to deregulation:
it allows countries to nominate how they will open
specific services to non-discriminatory access for
fellow WTO members. Australia, like many other
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
153
08/06/19 07:44 PM
countries, has not listed broadcasting and audiovisual
services among them.
Protection of creative industries from global
competition is not done through tariffs, but through
an array of industry regulations that inhibit the
participation of foreign competitors. Content quotas,
for example, reserve a minimum amount of airtime
for locally produced shows and songs. Public
broadcasters, such as SBS in Australia, are subsidised
by the state to ensure local programming, from news
and documentaries to children’s programs, soap
operas and game shows. These give the country a
chance to see itself in action. Domestic producers of
media content may also be eligible for government
grants or favourable tax treatment from which foreign
competitors are excluded.
Policies concerning protection for creative and
cultural industries vary with successive governments,
depending on their commitment to free market
principles, shifting international circumstances
and the sense of threat to national security. In
the 1950s, the liberal government of the day was
the first to consider the regulation of Australian
television, which was then free to screen content
from any source. Australian writers warned that
an unregulated industry would buy ready-made
foreign programs rather than exert itself to create
local alternatives. Sure enough, by the early 1960s
Australian-made television accounted for only 1
per cent of broadcast time. The bulk of what was
screened was imported from the United Kingdom
and the United States. Later that decade, the Coalition
government, persuaded by the need to protect
Australian culture and foster a stronger sense of
national identity, decided to devote public funds to
support the Australian film and television industries.
Unlike today, the need to protect jobs in the creative
industries was not relied on as motivation for
government intervention.
Protection of the creative and cultural industries
became entrenched in Australian policy over the
following five decades. But in 2017 the pro-market
Turnbull administration announced an ‘Australian
154
PART 2
screen content review’ that considered dismantling
many of the protections enjoyed by the $3 billion
Australian entertainment industry. Local actors,
writers and directors feared the result would be
an avalanche of foreign content, primarily from the
United States, that would erase Australian stories from
Australia’s screens. In response, a public lobby group
called Make it Australian coalesced to apply pressure
on the government to retain protective measures.
The group is a collaboration of concerned nongovernment organisations, including the Australian
Directors’ Guild, the Australian Writers’ Guild, the
Media, Entertainment & Arts Alliance and Screen
Producers Australia.
The Make it Australian campaign not only relies on
the cultural cost of deregulation, but also worries
about lost jobs. This is normally a powerful political
concern, if not a compelling economic one, but it
is not clear how serious the impact of deregulation
would be on Australian employment levels. The
production of movies and television programming
for overseas studios is big business in Australia and
already sustains thousands of workers. Although
actors like Chris Hemsworth, Cate Blanchett
and Rose Byrne lent their voices to the Make it
Australian campaign, all three are famous for their
work in movies made by the major Hollywood
studios—some of which, like Thor: Ragnarok, were
filmed in Australia.
The fundamental problem is that, without
government support, Australians may see less of
their own country reflected in the entertainment
products they consume, which in turn erodes the
nation’s sense of itself. In the words of playwright
David Williamson, Australians might come to believe
‘that real life happens somewhere else and it’s spoken
in American accents’. Furthermore, the world would
hear less of, and lose an appreciation of, Australia’s
unique storytelling voice. Movies like Mad Max,
Crocodile Dundee, The Castle, Priscilla: Queen of the
Desert, Romper Stomper, Gallipolli and Muriel’s Wedding
have influenced audiences far beyond Australian
shores. Just as important in this regard is Australian
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd
154
08/06/19 07:44 PM
music, which has been supported by local content
quotas for radio. A senator from Western Australia
recently proposed that the government should go
even further, establishing a national station devoted
entirely to Australian music.
wants to offer even more generous tax breaks to
offshore companies to entice them to film in its
jurisdiction. Critics of this position complain that
this would turn the Australian film industry into a
Hollywood back-lot.
Still, not all Australians are in favour of protection. For
political parties like Australia’s Liberals and Nationals,
cultural protection seems an unjustified intervention
in entertainment trade that leads to inefficient
allocation of resources and compromises Australia in
its international relations with pro-trade allies such
as the United States. To devoted trade enthusiasts,
given how pervasive and amorphous culture is, all
goods are ‘cultural’ goods due to how they are made
or what they represent: a hamburger, sneakers, video
games, wine, rice, clothing, even washing machines
and insurance. Thus, there is no rationale to privilege
popular music, films or television programs, and to
do so is an admission that Australian-made products
are not as marketable as their glamorous foreign
counterparts. If Australian storytellers cannot lift their
game, they should step aside.
Australian-made campaigners fear that any reduction
in quotas for local content will be binding on future
governments thanks to obligations imposed by
Australia’s free trade agreement with the United
States, the Australia–United States Free Trade
Agreement (AUSFTA). Unlike the multilateral GATS
administered by the WTO, AUSFTA does not allow its
signatories to nominate particular service industries
to be opened to free trade. Instead, it presumes that
protection of all service activities will be eliminated
unless an exception was created for specific
protective measures when the treaty came into force.
Although Australia created reservations for its local
broadcast quotas, this so-called negative list system
of liberalisation means that any change by Australia
favouring US imports will be irreversible while
AUSFTA is in force.
At a less ideological level, commercial television
networks such as Seven, Nine and Ten want quotas
replaced and regulations eased to give them greater
strategic freedom. They want a more flexible system
where they are awarded points based on the types
of dramas they produce, and are opposed to any
obligation to produce children’s programming. These
companies observe that the competitive landscape
has changed substantially since the 1960s, with
online viewing and new service providers playing an
increasingly important role. They consider the quota
system increasingly unfair and ineffective. However,
the same companies demonstrate the limitations of
the private sector in serving the public interest with
respect to cultural representation. For example, they
do not use money saved on reduced broadcast licence
fees to produce more local content. Instead, they
buy shows from New Zealand that they can count as
locally made thanks to the CER, with a resulting fall
of 30 per cent in screen time for genuine Australian
programs. Meanwhile, the Queensland government
CHAPTER 3
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd 155
The Make it Australian campaign is concerned by
recent experience in the United Kingdom, where local
children’s programming collapsed so dramatically
with the elimination of quotas that the government
rushed to reinstate them. This example, in their
view, makes it imperative that Australia maintain
its existing quota levels, and extend them to new
digital media platforms. An ever-larger proportion of
the Australian media diet is comprised of streaming
services from the likes of Netflix and Amazon. The
Make it Australian campaign insists that the quotas
imposed on radio and television can and should
be extended to online video and music providers.
If Australia were to take this path, it would be
following the example of the EU, which requires
that 30 per cent of a provider’s catalogue consists of
European content.
In the end, the demand for public protection of
creative and cultural industries depends not on
quantifiables like jobs created or revenue earned,
but on intangible goods like cultural distinctiveness
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
155
08/06/19 07:44 PM
and tradition. As the world becomes ever more
integrated, national communities feel an urgent
need to assert their uniqueness, even as that same
integration undermines their ability to do so.
The dilemma is stark: how important is increased
efficiency to us, if that efficiency might mean the
end of ‘us’?
Brent Burmester
University of Auckland
SOURCES: J. Bavas, ‘Veteran screenwriter David Williamson calls for more local movies, as Queensland chases blockbusters’, ABC News, 17 March 2018,
accessed via www.abc.net.au/news/2018-03-17/screenwriter-david-williamson-calls-for-more-local-movies/9557966; A. Broinowski, ‘The industry will
be gutted: why Australian film and TV is fighting for its life’, The Guardian, 29 April 2018, accessed via www.theguardian.com/culture/2018/apr/29/thewhole-industry-will-be-gutted-why-australias-film-and-tv-industry-is-fighting-for-its-life; ‘Protectionism: a matter of national pride’, The Conversation,
25 January 2012, accessed via http://theconversation.com/protectionism-a-matter-of-national-pride-4983; ‘Make it Australian campaign takes the fight
to Canberra’, IF Magazine, 26 June 2018, accessed via www.if.com.au/make-it-australian-campaign-takes-the-fight-to-canberra; N. Jolly, ‘Will higher
Australian music quotas for radio make people buy Australian?’, The Industry Observer, 22 June 2018, accessed via https://theindustryobserver.thebrag.
com/will-higher-australian-music-quotas-for-radio-make-people-buy-australian; I. Kostaki, ‘EU ministers agree to raise Netflix quota to 30%’, New
Europe, 23 May 2017, accessed via www.neweurope.eu/article/eu-council-raises-eu-content-netflix-quota-30; A. Meade, ‘Children’s TV should be left to
the ABC, Australian networks say’, The Guardian, 2 October 2017, accessed via www.theguardian.com/tv-and-radio/2017/oct/02/childrens-tv-shouldbe-left-to-the-abc-australian-networks-say.
CLOSING CASE DISCUSSION QUESTIONS
a. What might make it so difficult for Australian creative industries to produce local content that competes against
imported media?
b. Is the television business really any different from the breakfast cereal industry or from manufacturing sun
umbrellas in terms of its cultural importance?
c. Is there a contradiction in the idea that products of national cultural importance need protection from foreign
imports? If something locally made is genuinely intrinsic to life in a particular country, how could there be any
threat from something made somewhere else?
156
PART 2
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd
156
08/06/19 07:44 PM
ENDNOTES
1. Productivity Commission, Trade and Assistance Review 2016–17, Australian
Government, 26 April 2018, accessed via www.pc.gov.au/research/
ongoing/trade-assistance/2016-17 on 28 February 2019.
2. For a detailed welfare analysis of the effect of a tariff, see P.R. Krugman
and M. Obstfeld, International Economics: Theory and Policy, New York:
HarperCollins, 2000, ch. 8.
3. Department of Foreign Affairs and Trade, World Agricultural Markets—
Unfair and Distorted, Agriculture and the WTO, DFAT, accessed via
www.dfat.gov.au/trade/negotiations/trade_in_agriculture.html on
8 August 2012.
4. ‘Argentina’s language industry hit by new export tax 3 weeks ago’,
Slator, Marion Marking, 4 February 2019, accessed via https://slator.com/
industry-news/argentinas-language-industry-hit-by-new-export-tax on
28 February 2019.
5. ‘Govt claims victory on mineral-export tax’, The Jakarta Post, 25 May 2012.
6. ‘A quick guide to the US–China trade war’, BBC News, 7 January
2019, accessed via www.bbc.com/news/business-45899310 on
28 February 2019.
7. The study was undertaken by K. Anderson, University of Adelaide. See
‘A not so perfect market’, The Economist; Survey of Agriculture and
Technology, 25 March 2000, pp. 8–10.
8. K. Anderson, W. Martin and D. van ber Mensbrugghe, ‘Distortions to
world trade: Impact on agricultural markets and farm incomes’, Review of
Agricultural Economics, 28 (Summer 2006).
9. www.oecd.org/agriculture/topics/agricultural-policy-monitoring-andevaluation/ accessed on 4 March 2019.
10. M. Martina and D. Lawder, ‘Exclusive: China offers to end market-distorting
subsidies but won’t say how’, Reuters, 15 February 2019, accessed via
www.reuters.com/article/us-usa-trade-china-subsidies-exclusive/exclusivechina-offers-to-end-market-distorting-subsidies-but-wont-say-howidUSKCN1Q32X6 on 4 March 2019.
11. Jiji, ‘Japan to cut tariffs on whey for liquid baby formula’, Japan Times, 6
December 2018, accessed via www.japantimes.co.jp/news/2018/12/06/
business/japan-cut-tariffs-whey-liquid-baby-formula/#.XHyTN8AzaUk on
4 March 2019.
12. G. Mandigora, ‘South Africa’s textile export restraint agreement with China’,
Trade Law Centre for Southern Africa, 4 July 2006, accessed via www.
tralac.org/scripts/content.php?id=5040 on 22 January 2007.
13. Department of Foreign Affairs and Trade, ‘The Australia–United States
Free Trade Agreement: the outcome on local content requirements in
the audiovisual sector’, Australia–United States Free Trade Agreement,
Backgrounders, n.d., accessed via www.dfat.gov.au/trade/negotiations/
us_fta/backgrounder/audiovisual.html on 27 January 2007.
14. Reported in Productivity Commission, Trade and Assistance Review ­
2007–08, Australian Government Productivity Commission Annual
Report Series, 2009, p. 118.
15. J. Bhagwati, Protectionism, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1988; and ‘Japan to
curb VCR exports’, The New York Times, 21 November 1983, p. D5.
16. ABARE, Agriculture in China: Developments and Significance for Australia,
ABARE Research Report 06.2, Prepared for the Australian Government
Department of Agriculture, Fisheries and Forestry, Canberra, March 2006.
17. ‘Australia celebrates over 50 years of wool trade to China’, The Land, 5
July 2018, accessed via www.theland.com.au/story/5507528/australiacelebrates-over-50-years-of-wool-trade-to-china/ on 6 March 2019.
18. Wine Australia, Label Approval Checklist—European Union, accessed
via www.wineaustralia.com/australia/Portals/2/Exporting/Label%20
Approval%20Checklist%20-%20EU.pdf on 12 August 2012.
19. G. Di Lieto, ‘Australia may be engaging in “free trade” but it’s becoming
more protectionist too’, The Conversation, 20 February 2018, accessed via
https://theconversation.com/australia-may-be-engaging-in-free-trade-butits-becoming-more-protectionist-too-92025 on 6 March 2019.
20. ‘Transitioning Australia’s automotive manufacturing industry’,
Department of Industry, Innovation and Science, 29 November 2018,
accessed via www.industry.gov.au/funding-and-incentives/manufacturing/
transitioning-australias-automotive-manufacturing-industry on
4 March 2019.
21. For details of the Wassenaar Arrangement, consult the site www.wassenaar.org.
22. Department of Defence, ‘Export Controls on Mining and Exploration
Equipment’, Australian Government, Fact Sheet, n.d., accessed via www.
defence.gov.au/deco/publications/brochures/Mining_fact_sheet.pdf on
12 August 2012.
CHAPTER 3
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd 157
23. J. Stubbs, ‘Europe calls for facts not fears in Huawei row’, IT News, 27
February 2019, accessed via www.itnews.com.au/news/europe-calls-forfacts-not-fears-in-huawei-row-519856 on 4 March 2019.
24. N. Dunne and R. Waters, ‘US waves a big stick at Chinese pirates’, Financial
Times, 6 January 1995, p. 4.
25. D. Ten Kate, ‘Trump’s trade war with China may end in a draw’, Bloomberg, 4
March 2019, accessed via www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2019-03-04/
trump-s-trade-war-with-china-may-end-in-a-draw on 5 March 2019.
26. T. Miles, ‘Australia wins landmark WTO ruling on plain cigarette packaging’,
Sydney Morning Herald, 29 June 2018, accessed via www.smh.com.au/
politics/federal/australia-wins-landmark-wto-ruling-on-plain-cigarettepackaging-20180629-p4zoft.html on 5 March 2019.
27. P.S. Jordan, ‘Country sanctions and the international business community’,
American Society of International Law Proceedings of the Annual Meeting,
20(9) (1997), pp. 333–42.
28. Department of Foreign Affairs and Trade, Australia and Sanctions, accessed
via https://dfat.gov.au/international-relations/security/sanctions/Pages/
sanctions.aspx on 5 March 2019.
29. ‘Waiting for China: human rights and international trade’, Commonwealth,
11 March 1994; and ‘China: the cost of putting business first’, Human Rights
Watch, July 1996.
30. ‘China events of 2017’, Human Rights Watch, accessed via www.hrw.org/
world-report/2018/country-chapters/china-and-tibet on 5 March 2019.
31. ‘What is the Paris Agreement?’, United Nations Climate Change, accessed
via https://unfccc.int/process-and-meetings/the-paris-agreement/what-isthe-paris-agreement on 5 March 2019.
32. K. Mathiesen, ‘The “climate diaspora” trying to save the Paris Agreement
from Trump’, The Guardian, 3 December 2018, accessed via www.
theguardian.com/environment/2018/dec/03/save-paris-climate-agreementfrom-trump on 5 March 2019.
33. A. Ericson, ‘Few countries are meeting the Paris climate goals. Here are
the ones that are’, Washington Post, 11 October 2018, accessed via www.
washingtonpost.com/world/2018/10/11/few-countries-are-meeting-parisclimate-goals-here-are-ones-that-are/?utm_term=.a52da77d9c05 on 5
March 2019.
34. G. Banks, ‘Gaining from trade liberalisation: Some reflections on Australia’s
experience’, New Horizons in Trade Conference, Adelaide, Australian
Productivity Commission, 5 June 2003, accessed via www.pc.gov.au/
speeches/cs20030605/index.html on 30 January 2007.
35. D.A. Irwin, ‘Did late-nineteenth-century US tariffs promote infant industries?
Evidence from the tinplate industry’, The Journal of Economic History, 60(2)
(2000), pp. 335–60.
36. Industry Commission, The Automotive Industry, Vol. 1, The Report, 58 (26
May 1997), p. xxxi.
37. ‘Brazil’s auto industry struggles to boost global competitiveness’, Journal of
Commerce, 10 October 1991, p. 6A.
38. For reviews, see J.A. Brander, ‘Rationales for strategic trade and industrial
policy’, in P.R. Krugman (ed.), Strategic Trade Policy and the New
International Economics, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1986; P.R. Krugman, ‘Is
free trade passé?’, Journal of Economic Perspectives 1 (1987), pp. 131–44;
and P.R. Krugman, ‘Does the new trade theory require a new trade policy?’,
World Economy, 15(4) (1992), pp. 423–41.
39. ‘Airbus and Boeing: the jumbo war’, The Economist, 15 June 1991, pp. 65–6.
40. For details see Krugman, ‘Is free trade passé?’ (1987), op. cit. and Brander,
‘Rationales for Strategic Trade and Industrial Policy’, op. cit.
41. Krugman, ‘Is free trade passé?’ (1987), op. cit.
42. R.E. Lipsey, ‘Home and host country effects of FDI’, National Bureau of
Economic Research, working paper no. 9293, October 2002; and X.
Li and X. Liu, ‘Foreign direct investment and economic growth’, World
Development, 33 (March 2005), pp. 393–413.
43. Reported in ‘Foreign friends’, The Economist, 8 January 2000, pp. 71–2. See
also K. Saggi, ‘Trade, foreign direct investment and international technology
transfer’, World Bank Research Observer, 17 (2002), pp. 191–235.
44. K. Thuermer, ‘Automotives: Toyota: land of opportunity’, Foreign Direct
Investment (London), 1 December 2006, p. 1; ‘Contribution of Toyota to the
economies of fourteen states and the United States’, Center for Automotive
Research, June 2005, accessed via www.cargroup.org/documents/Toyota.
pdf on 30 January 2007.
45. ‘Foreign friends’, The Economist (2000), op. cit.
46. L. Busby, ‘From Bi-lo to Lidl: the changing face of Australia’s retail sector and
tips for staying relevant’, Smart Company, 23 November 2017, accessed
via www.smartcompany.com.au/business-advice/bi-lo-lidl-changing-faceaustralias-retail-sector-tips-staying-relevant/ on 5 March 2019.
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE AND INVESTMENT
157
08/06/19 07:44 PM
47. S Sarkar, ‘Amazon Prime Day in Australia: What to expect during Prime Day
2019’, TechRadar, 27 February 2019, accessed via www.techradar.com/au/
news/amazon-australia-prime-day on 5 March 2019.
48. R. Ram and K.H. Zang, ‘Foreign direct investment and economic growth’,
Economic Development and Cultural Change, 51 (2002), pp. 205–25.
49. M. Cranston, ‘Foreigners increase farmland ownership’, Australian Financial
Review, 20 December 2018, accessed via www.afr.com/real-estate/
foreigners-increase-farmland-ownership-20181220-h19bta on 7 March 2019.
50. A. Mattoo and A. Subramanian, Currency Undervaluation and Sovereign
Wealth Funds: A New Role for the World Trade Organization, Policy
Research Working Paper Series 4668, The World Bank.
51. ‘Discreditable exports’, Financial Times, London, 14 July 2000, p. 16.
52. This idea has been articulated, although not quite in this form, by C.A.
Bartlett and S. Ghoshal, Managing Across Borders: The Transnational
Solution, Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1989.
53. EDS, ‘EDS best shore SM ensures right blend, great value’, accessed via
www.eds.com/services/bestshore/ on 31 January 2007; T. Pullar-Strecker,
‘EDS meets job-creation target’, The Dominion Post, 26 January 2006, p. C3.
54. S. Neales, ‘Grim forecast for food industry’, The Australian, 8 March 2012.
55. N. Thirawat, ‘International Investment Policy and Thailand’s Food
Processing Sector’, European Journal of Scientific Research, 78 (4), 2012.
56. Australian Food and Grocery Council and A.T. Kearney Australia, The
2020 Industry at Crossroads, November 2011, accessed via www.
afgc.org.au on 21 August 2012; ‘Thailand: ASEAN Insights: Thailand
— Onward To Industry 4.0’, Clyde & Co, 17 January 2019, accessed
via www.mondaq.com/x/772052/Inward+Foreign+Investment/
ASEAN+Insights+Thailand+onward+to+industry+40 on 7 March 2019.
57. World Trade Organization, World Trade Report 2006, WTO, Executive
Summary, p. xxv.
58. Dezan Shira & Associates (K. Das), ‘Vietnam’s industrial zones focusing on
SMEs for investment’, Vietnam Briefing, accessed via www.vietnam-briefing.
com/news/vietnams-industrial-zones-focusing-smes-investment.html on 7
March 2019.
59. S. Rai, ‘India to ease limits on foreign ownership of media and tea’, The New
York Times, 26 June 2002, p. W1.
60. Overseas Investment Office, Selling New Zealand Assets to Overseas
Investors, Land Information New Zealand, accessed via www.linz.govt.nz/
overseas-investment on 21 August 2012.
61. L.D. Qiu and Z. Tao, ‘Export, foreign direct investment and local content
requirements’, Journal of Development Economics 66 (October 2001),
pp. 101–25.
62. World Trade Organization, ‘Welcome to the Regional Trade Agreements
Information System (RTA-IS)’, accessed via https://rtais.wto.org/UI/
PublicMaintainRTAHome.aspx on 7 March 2019.
63. World Trade Organization, Understanding the WTO (WTO, 2005), ch. 1,
p. 17, accessed via www.wto.org/english/thewto_e/whatis_ e/tif_e/utw_
chap1_e.pdf on 3 January 2007.
64. H-J. Chang, ‘Foreign investment regulation in historical perspective?
Lessons for the proposed WTO agreement on investment’, Third World
Network, March 2003, accessed via www.twnside.org.sg/title/joon2.doc on
31 January 2007.
65. World Trade Organization, ‘Anti-dumping initiations: by sector’, accessed
via www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/adp_e/AD_InitiationsBySector.xls on 7
March 2019.
66. Trade Policy 2016: G20 Policies and Export Performance of the Least
Developed Countries, United Nations Conference on Trade and
Development (UNCTAD), Key Statistics and Trends, 2017, Table 3b, page
7, accessed via https://unctad.org/en/PublicationsLibrary/ditctab2016d2_
en.pdf on 7 March 2019.
67. The G8 + 5 consists of the G8 (Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan,
Russia, United Kingdom, United States) and five emerging economies
(Brazil, China, India, Mexico, South Africa).
158
PART 2
68. Reported in Productivity Commission, Trade and Assistance Review
2010–11, Annual Report, June 2012, p. 95, op. cit.
69. F. Ismail, ‘Why there’s an urgent need to revive the Doha Round of
trade talks’, The Conversation, 4 October 2016, accessed via https://
theconversation.com/why-theres-an-urgent-need-to-revive-the-doharound-of-trade-talks-66286 on 7 March 2019.
70. Oxfam International, Empty Promises: What Happened to ‘Development’ in
the WTO’s Doha Round, Oxfam Briefing Paper 131, 16 July 2009.
71. The importance of freeing up agricultural trade for development is
discussed in K.A. Elliot, Delivering on Doha: Farm Trade and the Poor,
Washington: Center for Global Development, Institute for International
Economics, 2006.
72. A. Mattoo and A. Subramanian, Multilateralism Beyond Doha, The World
Bank, Policy Research Working Paper, 4735, September 2008, p. 2.
73. For a detailed discussion of how well the WTO is equipped in dealing with
trade barriers that have arisen in response to security issues, see Mattoo
and Subramanian, Multilateralism Beyond Doha (2008), op. cit.
74. ‘Population on January 1’, Eurostat, accessed via https://ec.europa.eu/
eurostat/tgm/table.do?tab=table&init=1&language=
en&pcode=tps00001&plugin=1 on 7 March 2019.
75. ‘Gross domestic product at market prices’, Eurostat, accessed
via https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/tgm/refreshTableAction.
do;jsessionid=9ea7d07e30dd3bf0a52b9a8a474c872db039e243c026.
e34OaN8Pc3mMc40Lc3aMaNyTa3eQe0?tab=
table&plugin=1&pcode=tec00001&language=en on 7
March 2019.
76. ‘WTO Regional Trade Agreements and the WTO’, accessed via www.wto.
org/english/tratop_e/region_e/scope_rta_e.htm on 7 March 2019.
77. Productivity Commission, Rules of Origin under the Australia–New Zealand
Closer Economic Relations Trade Agreement, June 2004, accessed
via www.pc.gov.au/__data/assets/pdf_file/ 0011/16499/roo.pdf on
30 August 2012.
78. Membership of RTAs can change frequently as economic and political
circumstances change. Such has been the experience of the Andean
Community. In 2006, Venezuela, a long-term member, withdrew from
the Andean Community because other members had established FTAs
individually with the United States, a political foe of Venezuela.
79. ‘Brexit: your simple guide to the UK leaving the EU’, BBC News,
28 February 2019, accessed via www.bbc.com/news/uk-46318565 on
7 March 2019.
80. Ibid.
81. See J. Bhagwati, ‘Regionalism and multilateralism: an overview’,
Columbia University discussion paper 603, Department of Economics,
Columbia University, New York; A. de la Torre and M. Kelly, ‘Regional
trade arrangements’, International Monetary Fund occasional paper
93, Washington DC, March 1992; J. Bhagwati, ‘Fast track to nowhere’,
The Economist, 18 October 1997, pp. 21–4; J. Bhagwati, Free Trade
Today, Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press, 2002; and
B.K. Gordon, ‘A high risk trade policy’, Foreign Affairs, 82(4) (August 2003),
pp. 105–15.
82. H. Calvo-Pardo, C. Freund and E. Ornelas, The ASEAN Free Trade
Agreement: Impact on Trade Flows and External Trade Barriers, The World
Bank, Policy Research Working Paper, 4960, June 2009.
83. Mattoo and Subramanian, Multilateralism Beyond Doha (2008), op. cit.,
pp. 17–19.
84. Consider the case of Atag Holdings, a Dutch maker of kitchen appliances,
in T. Horwitz, ‘Europe’s borders fade’, The Wall Street Journal, 18 May 1993,
pp. Al, A12; ‘A singular market’, The Economist, 22 October 1994, pp. 10–16;
and ‘Something dodgy in Europe’s single market’, The Economist, 21 May
1994, pp. 69–70.
85. E.G. Friberg, ‘1992: Moves Europeans are making’, Harvard Business
Review, May–June 1989, pp. 85–9.
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch03_101-158.indd
158
08/06/19 07:44 PM
© ashwin/123RF.com
CHAPTER 4
FOREIGN
EXCHANGE AND
THE INTERNATIONAL
MONETARY SYSTEM
CHAPTER 4
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd 159
FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
159
08/07/19 04:03 PM
INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS GRADUATE
ATTRIBUTES (IBGAs)
This chapter’s content, learning resources and case studies provide you with the
opportunity to develop a number of International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs),
including the following:
IBGA1
IBGA2
IBGA3
IBGA5
IBGA7
Discipline Knowledge and Skills
Critical Analysis
Problem Solving
Communication
Global Perspective
LEARNING OBJECTIVES (LOs)
LO 4.1
LO 4.2
LO 4.3
LO 4.4
LO 4.5
160
PART 2
Explain the forces that influence exchange rates.
Outline the nature and functions of foreign exchange markets, and
the international monetary system and its institutions.
Assess the effectiveness of different exchange rate regimes in
reconciling national policy goals and the goal of international
monetary stability.
Demonstrate the impact of exchange rates on international
business decisions.
Recommend strategies that international business can use to
reduce foreign exchange rate risks.
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd
160
08/07/19 04:03 PM
OPENING CASE
THE MEXICAN PESO, THE JAPANESE
YEN AND POKÉMON GO
The diverging values of the yen and the peso are a
function of their exchange rates against the US dollar.
Most trades between the yen and the peso are converted
through the US dollar, rather than traded directly. This is
because the US dollar is the world’s most widely traded
and liquid currency. It is easier to trade dollars for yen,
and dollars for pesos, than it is to trade yen for pesos. For
much of 2016, the yen gained against the dollar, while
the Mexican peso fell, leading to a fall in the peso/yen
exchange rate.
The strength of the yen reflected the belief that Japan is a
safe haven in which to park cash. Although the Japanese
economy has been stagnant for decades, inflation is low
and the yen has been a strong currency. The Mexican
peso is the most liquid emerging market currency, which
makes it an easy one to sell when investors worry about
the economic strength of developing economies, which
they did in 2015 and 2016. To compound matters, worries
about the health of the Mexican economy following the
election of Donald Trump to the US presidency put further
pressure on the peso. The Mexican peso hit a record low
against the US dollar following Trump’s election.
© Bloomberg/Getty Images
Nintendo’s hit game Pokémon Go is a lot less lucrative
in Mexico than the Japanese company originally
thought it would be. This is because Mexicans
purchase the ‘PokéCoins’ they need to navigate the
game in Mexican pesos, and the peso has been falling
in value against the Japanese yen. Back in early 2015,
1 Mexican peso bought 8 Japanese yen. By September
2016, 1 peso was worth only about 5.1 Japanese yen.
This meant that when pesos spent on Pokémon Go were
translated back into Japanese yen, they were worth less
in yen, which negatively affected Nintendo’s profits
from Mexico.
In addition to Nintendo, the fall in the value of the peso
against the yen has created problems for other Japanese
companies. Japanese car makers have significant assembly
operations in Mexico. Companies such as Toyota and
Mazda import a large number of specialty electronic
components from suppliers in Japan. The price of these
components has gone up when translated into pesos,
raising costs for their Mexican operations and making
them less profitable.
On the other hand, the weak peso has boosted demand
for some Mexican products in Japan. For example, Japan
imports a large quantity of frozen Mexican pork. The
price has fallen when translated into yen and demand
has surged. Mexico dices up the pork and exports it to
Japanese convenience stores, where it is sold in bento
boxes. The dicing process is labour-intensive—and one
less step they have to perform in Japan. Mexico can do it
cheaper, and the currency moves have only added to the
cost savings, which is good for Japanese consumers.
SOURCES: J. Wernau, ‘Pokéman Go illustrates a currency problem’, The Wall Street Journal, 11 August 2016; E. Holodny and P. Crowe, ‘Mexican peso crashes to
record low’, Business Insider, 8 November 2016; ‘Peso falls to session lows after meeting between US and Mexico presidents falls through’, Reuters, 26 January
2017.
CHAPTER 4
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd 161
FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
161
08/07/19 04:03 PM
INTRODUCTION
LO 4.1
Like many enterprises in the global economy, the Japanese companies discussed in the
opening case are affected by changes in the value of currencies on the foreign exchange
market. The case illustrates that what happens in the foreign exchange market can have a
fundamental impact on the sales profits of an enterprise. Accordingly, it is very important
for managers to understand how the foreign exchange market works and what the impact
of changes in currency exchange rates might be for their enterprise and its strategy.
When conducting business domestically, the buyer and the seller use a single
currency, typically their home country currency. In a foreign transaction, however,
the buyer and seller may use two or more different currencies which are continuously
changing in relative buying or selling power to each other, through the dynamic foreign
exchange market mechanism. As exchange rates change, the price competitiveness of
traded goods will change, as will the currency value of costs and sales earnings. Some
businesses will gain, while others will lose. Consequently, the exchange rate is often
the most crucial variable in international business decisions and performance, and
what happens in the foreign exchange market can have a fundamental impact on the
sales, profits and strategy of an enterprise. Hence, one of the most important aspects of
successful international trade is understanding the movement and volatility of different
currencies and determining which represent the least risk when agreeing to payment
terms and transactions.
For example, an Australian importer may agree to purchase organic cocoa from a
Malaysian exporter who requests to be paid in the Malaysian currency, ringgits (MYR).
The Australian importer will need to buy the appropriate number of ringgits in the foreign
currency (or foreign exchange) market at the going market rate (the exchange rate) using
Australian dollars (AUD). The importer will then, usually through an intermediary such as
a bank, make a payment as agreed to the Malaysian exporter in ringgits. If the exporter
requested payment in US dollars (USD) rather than ringgits, which is quite often the case,
the importer would need to enter the foreign exchange market to purchase US dollars
and remit the payment in that currency. The Australian importer in effect operates in two
markets—the organic cocoa market and the foreign exchange market—and must consider
the price in each market to assess whether the international transaction is profitable. The
Malaysian price of organic cocoa in ringgits may be low, but that advantage could be
negated if the Australian dollar falls in value relative to the ringgit—that is, if the dollar
price of a ringgit rises. The higher dollar price may make Malaysian organic cocoa difficult
to sell in Australia. On the other hand, if the Malaysian ringgit fell in value relative to the
Australian dollar, Malaysian organic cocoa imports in terms of price competitiveness would
become more attractive to Australian consumers. In that case, a fall in the value of the
ringgit would benefit Malaysian exporters.
The foreign exchange rate also influences decisions beyond those related to the
international trade in goods and services. For example, to undertake foreign direct
investment (FDI), a business needs to buy foreign currency to move capital into a country
or sell foreign currency to repatriate profits. Portfolio investors buy and sell foreign
currencies as they seek the best returns from trading internationally in financial assets
as shares and government securities. Consequently, the exchange rate is a key variable in
many international decisions and needs to be closely monitored. Exchange rate implications
arise when the following strategic questions are considered.
162
PART 2
•
Where will the company get the best return on foreign investment?
•
Where will the company locate production?
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd
162
08/07/19 04:03 PM
•
From where will the company source its supplies?
•
In which currency will the company borrow?
•
In which currency will the company quote prices?
•
What will be the forecast earnings of the company’s subsidiaries in home currency
terms?
How can the company best protect future foreign cash flows against currency volatility
and risk?
•
Owing to the importance of understanding exchange rate complexities for international
business success, companies employ specialist finance and accounting experts to help them
closely monitor currency exposure risks and strategically manage their foreign exchange
activities. This chapter provides an overview of the main features of the international
financial system in relation to the conduct of global business activity, and the strategic
implications for management.
The international financial system comprises a number of different financial markets and
institutions. Figure 4.1 provides an overview of the different financial markets.
Foreign exchange market:
includes interbank market and
securities exchanges
FIGURE 4.1
International financial markets
International
financial markets
International capital market:
includes the bond market, the equities
market and eurocurrency market
The ‘foreign exchange market’ is the market where global currencies are bought
and sold, and their exchange rates are determined. The ‘international capital market’
allows participants to invest and borrow across international borders through a variety
of financial institutions managed by specialist bank and fund managers. Because most
of the commercial and financial decisions undertaken by an international business are
affected by the exchange rate, whether the business be a large multinational or a small
exporter, this chapter will focus on the foreign exchange market and the regimes put in
place to manage that market. It begins by examining how the foreign exchange market
works and the forces that determine the exchange rate. It looks at the different exchange
rate regimes to see how and why governments intervene in the foreign exchange
market. The role and functions of an international monetary system are discussed, as
well as the policy trade-offs for governments and the potentially destabilising impacts
of policy spillovers. It is then illustrated how challenging this role is by examining the
attempt to put in place an international rules-based system to govern the international
monetary system (the Bretton Woods system), the international financial crises and the
role of the International Monetary Fund (IMF). The final section examines the effect
of exchange rate changes on international business, and the setting of prices in foreign
markets to maintain profit mark-ups while remaining price competitive. The chapter
concludes by highlighting the risks to international business of foreign exchange rate
changes, along with the strategies that can be adopted to manage foreign exchange rate
risk exposures.
CHAPTER 4
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd 163
FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKET
A market for converting the currency
of one country into that of another
country
FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
163
08/07/19 04:03 PM
THE FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKET
EXCHANGE RATE
The rate at which one currency is
converted into another
CRYPTOCURRENCIES
Ditigal currencies that are
independent of central authorities
and use cryptography for their
security
The role of the foreign exchange market is to convert the currency of one country
into that of another country. An exchange rate is the rate at which one currency is
converted into another, or the price of a currency. The United Nations recognises 180
different currencies as legal tender, and as yet there is no single, globally accepted
currency in the world economy, unlike the single, nationally accepted currency that
is used in each domestic economy. Digital cryptocurrencies such as the bitcoin are
also playing an increasingly important role as an alternative to hard global currencies,
despite their unregulated ‘rogue’ reputation. (See Another Perspective: ‘The rise of
cryptocurrencies’.) The foreign exchange market, therefore, is the mechanism that
enables businesses and clients based in different countries to financially transact
business trade with each other.
The nature of the foreign exchange market
The foreign exchange market is a global network of banks, brokers and foreign exchange
dealers connected by electronic communications systems. When companies wish to
convert currencies, they typically go through their own banks, rather than entering
the market directly. The foreign exchange market has been growing at a rapid pace.
Globally, between April 2004 and April 2016, foreign exchange turnover grew from
ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
THE RISE OF CRYPTOCURRENCIES
164
PART 2
level. However, developing an integrated regulatory
framework that has minimal impact on the existing
payment, retail and banking sectors has proven
complex and difficult. Leading banks from around the
world, including the Lloyds Bank in the UK, the Bank
of Scotland, JP Morgan and the Bank of America,
have blocked their customers from purchasing
© spaxiax/Shutterstock
Will cryptocurrencies such as the bitcoin revolutionise
the financial services industry? They are said to
represent a faster, cheaper and more secure means
of transacting online business processes all around
the world, superseding the need to transact in foreign
exchange markets. Owing to its decentralised peer-topeer exchange model, transacting in cryptocurrency
circumvents central banking systems and authorities,
enabling businesses to save on transaction fees and
processing time delays. The genius of cryptocurrency
lies in the underpinning encryption technology, which
controls and verifies the issuing and transfer of funds,
and negates the need for human auditing processes.
This has raised many unique and challenging issues
for traditional finance and accounting governance
policy setters and financial regulators. Still in their
infancy, in terms of mainstream institutional integration,
many predict that transformative technologies such
as the bitcoin may significantly drive the next wave
of online small business proliferation at the global
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd
164
08/07/19 04:03 PM
cryptocurrencies owing to security concerns. Many
countries around the world, as well as in Asia
(Bangladesh, Cambodia, China, Indonesia, Nepal,
Pakistan, Taiwan), have officially banned the use of
bitcoin, and warn individuals of the risks associated
with trading in unregulated cryptocurrencies.
Risks include currency value volatility, technical
security vulnerabilities (hacking), lack of institutional
governance and its close association with money
laundering and illegal black-market trading. Will
country bans and bank blocking measures delay
the mainstream global uptake of cryptocurrencies
such as bitcoin? Or will their use continue to
proliferate unfettered? Either way, the development
of cryptocurrencies and their impact on the future of
foreign exchange transactions is likely to be significant.
US$1.9 trillion per day to US$5.1 trillion per day.1 In 2016, the most important trading
centres were London (37 per cent of activity), New York (19 per cent), Singapore
(8 per cent), Tokyo (6 per cent) and Hong Kong SAR (7 per cent).2 Major secondary
trading centres include Zurich, Frankfurt, Paris and Sydney. The currencies that were
traded the most (in descending order) were the US dollar (88 per cent), the euro (31 per
cent), the Japanese yen (22 per cent), the pound sterling (13 per cent) and the Australian
dollar (7 per cent). The Chinese renminbi was one of the highest performing emerging
ARBITRAGE
market currencies in 2016, as it almost doubled in turnover since 2013 to become the
The purchase of securities in one
eighth most traded currency, representing over 4 per cent of global trading. Obviously,
market for immediate resale in
the volume of foreign exchange trading far exceeds the needs of end users such as
another market to profit from a price
discrepancy
importers, exporters and foreign direct investors. Most of the currency trading reflects
interbank transactions and short-term international
capital flows—for example, by hedge funds and
superannuation funds diversifying their portfolios
in foreign financial markets—and currency
speculators.
Three features of the foreign exchange market
are of particular note. The first is that the market
itself never sleeps, as the major trading centres
are positioned around the world to accommodate
the different time zones. The second feature
of the market is the integration of the various
trading centres around the world through highspeed computer linkages that have effectively
created a single market. This integration
implies there can be no significant difference
in exchange rates quoted in the trading centres
where a dealer could make a profit through
arbitrage. Arbitrage is the buying of a currency
Even though the British pound has declined in its importance as a
that is priced low in a particular trading centre,
vehicle currency, London still remains the key location for global
and then immediately selling it in another for
foreign exchange.
CHAPTER 4
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd 165
FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
165
08/07/19 04:03 PM
© Megan Hunter
SOURCES: D. Chau, ‘Westpac, ANZ and NAB aren’t planning a bitcoin crackdown . . . yet’, ABC News online, 6 February 2018, accessed via www.abc.net.
au/news/2018-02-05/big-four-banks-not-planning-bitcoin-clampdown-yet/9398234 on 4 December 2018; ‘Is bitcoin speculative foolery or a financial
services breakthrough?’, Entrepreneur, accessed via https://au.finance.yahoo.com/news/bitcoin-speculative-foolery-financial-services-130000684.html
on 7 December 2018; S. Cioroiu, ‘Update on bitcoin developments’, Diplo, 28 October 2014, accessed via www.diplomacy.edu/blog/update-bitcoindevelopments on 7 December 2018.
ALGORITHMIC TRADING (AT)
The application of computational
algorithms to assist with the
monitoring, identification and
management of financial market
transactions
VEHICLE CURRENCY
A national currency that is widely
used in international transactions
and is used as an intermediary unit
to convert one currency to another
a higher price, resulting in a profit yield from the transaction. If all dealers tried to
cash in on the opportunity, however, the demand for the under-priced currency
would quickly rise, resulting in an appreciation of its value and the disappearance
of the price differential. Because foreign exchange dealers are always watching their
computer screens for arbitrage opportunities, the few that arise tend to be small,
and they disappear in minutes. Profiting from arbitrage speculation is increasing for
dealers leveraging Algorithmic Trading (AT), however, which is the use of user-defined
computerised algorithms to help monitor, identify and manage arbitrage opportunities
occurring in high-frequency trading executions. AT has enabled dealers to capture
advantage within milliseconds.3
The third feature of the foreign exchange market is the important role played by the
US dollar. Although a foreign exchange transaction can involve any two currencies, most
transactions involve US dollars on one side. This is true even when a dealer wants to sell
a non-dollar currency and buy another. A dealer wishing to sell Korean won (KRW) for
Brazilian real (BRL), for example, will usually sell the won for US dollars and then use the
US dollars to buy real. Although this may seem a roundabout way of doing things, it is
actually cheaper than trying to find a holder of real who wants to buy won. Because the
volume of international transactions involving US dollars is so great, it is not hard to find
dealers who wish to trade US dollars for won or real.
Due to its central role in so many foreign exchange deals, the US dollar is a vehicle
currency. The most traded currencies are also described as reserve currencies, hard
currencies or key currencies in different contexts, which are often used to calculate cross
rates (which are explained later in this chapter).
The functions of the foreign exchange market
FOREIGN EXCHANGE RISK
The risk that changes in exchange
rates will hurt the profitability of a
business deal
We will now look in more detail at the two main functions of the foreign exchange
market: to ‘convert’ the currency of one country into the currency of another; and to
provide some ‘hedge’ or insurance against foreign exchange risk.4
© RomanR/Shutterstock
Currency conversion
A distinguishing feature of international business is the need to
transact in different currencies.
166
PART 2
Each country has a currency in which the prices
of goods and services are quoted and transactions
are financed. In Australia it is the dollar ($); in
Great Britain, the pound sterling (£); in France
and Germany it is the euro (€); in Japan, the yen
(¥); and so on. In general, within the borders of
a particular country, one must be able to access
and use the national currency. For example, an
Indonesian tourist visiting Australia wishing to
purchase a souvenir must pay for the goods using
Australian dollars. To access this currency, the
tourist can use an ATM to withdraw Australian
dollars using a credit/debit/travel money card (the
participating bank automatically debits the home
country account in Indonesian rupiah (IDR) using
the spot exchange rate and adds an additional fee).
Alternatively the tourist can go to a bank or foreign
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd
166
08/07/19 04:03 PM
exchange agency and exchange rupiah for dollars. Regardless of the method, when one
currency is exchanged for another, the tourist is participating in the foreign exchange
market.
Businesses engaged in international trade and investment are by necessity major
participants in the foreign exchange market, which has four main purposes. First, payments
received for exports, income received from foreign investments, or income received, for
example, from licensing agreements with foreign companies, may be in foreign currencies.
To use those funds in its home country, the business must convert them to its home
country’s currency.
Second, foreign exchange markets are used to convert currencies when international
businesses must pay a foreign entity for its products or services in the foreign country’s
currency.
Third, international business uses foreign exchange markets to convert to the host
country’s currency when they undertake foreign direct investment. They use it also
for portfolio investment when they have spare cash that they wish to invest for short
terms in money markets. Consider an Australian company that has A$10 million it
wants to invest for three months. The best interest rate it can earn on these funds
in Australia may be 6 per cent. Investing in a South Korean money market account,
however, may earn 12 per cent. Thus, the company may change its A$10 million
into Korean won (KRW) and invest it in South Korea. Note, however, that the rate of
return it earns on this investment depends not only on the Korean interest rate, but
also on the expected changes in the value of the Korean won against the dollar in the
intervening period.
The kind of transaction described immediately above relates to a common form of
speculation known as carry trade. Carry trade involves borrowing in one currency where
the interest rates are low and then using the proceeds to invest in another currency where
the interest rates are high. The speculative element of this trade is that its success is based
upon the belief that there will be no adverse movements in exchange rates (or interest
rates, for that matter) that will make the trade unprofitable. A relationship between interest
rates and exchange rates is discussed in the next section.
Currency speculation is the fourth use made of the foreign exchange market to
convert one currency into another. Currency speculation typically involves the short-term
movement of funds from one currency to another in the hope of profiting from changes
in exchange rates. Consider again our Australian company with A$10 million to invest
for three months. Suppose the company suspects that the Australian dollar is overvalued
against the Japanese yen. That is, the company expects the value of the dollar to depreciate
(fall) against that of the yen. Imagine the current dollar/yen exchange rate is A$1 = ¥120.
The company exchanges its AU$10 million into yen, receiving ¥1.2 billion (AU$10 million ×
120 = ¥1.2 billion). Over the next three months, the value of the dollar depreciates
against the yen until A$1 = ¥100. (There is no guarantee that this depreciation would
occur.) Now the company exchanges its ¥1.2 billion back into dollars and finds that it has
A$12 million. The company has made A$2 million profit on currency speculation in three
months on an initial investment of A$10 million (if its expectations about the exchange
rates are realised). In general, however, speculation by definition is a very risky business.
The company cannot know for sure what will happen to exchange rates. Although a
speculator may profit handsomely if their speculation about future currency movements
turns out to be correct, they can also lose vast amounts of money if it turns out to be
wrong. Currency speculation is something for the foreign exchange specialist rather than
the managers of firms, who need to be focusing more on the strategic and operational
issues of conducting the business.
CHAPTER 4
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd 167
CARRY TRADE
Involves borrowing in one currency
where the interest rates are low and
then using the proceeds to invest in
another currency where the interest
rates are high
CURRENCY SPECULATION
Involves moving funds from one
currency to another over the short
term in the hope of profiting from
changes in exchange rates
FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
167
08/07/19 04:03 PM
ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
GROWING PAINS WITH THE EURO
It seems like experts and interested observers
are always debating the merits of the euro and its
likelihood of survival. Introduced in 1999 as the
common currency to be used across all eurozone
economies, the intention behind its original launch was
to bring united trading power and increased prosperity
to all. These ambitions have not been realised,
however, where growth in the eurozone economy
has slowed in comparison with other economies. For
example, the US economy grew 13 per cent to 26
per cent larger than the eurozone economy between
2000 and 2016. The real GDP levels of the eurozone
economy remained the same between 2001 and 2016.
Many countries have been frustrated with the inability
to control their own interest and exchange rate
mechanisms, and having to answer to Germany’s
heavy-handed role played in controlling the euro policy
agenda. This has resulted in fierce bickering between
countries unable to agree on how best to restructure
and introduce institutions to ensure confidence in
Europe’s future.
It is difficult to compare the challenges within the EU
with those of other nations that have faced similar
problems and survived. But until the growing pains
associated with the euro currency are resolved, it is
difficult to predict its future.
SOURCE: Adapted from J. Stiglitz, ‘The euro could be nearing a crisis: can it be saved?’, The Guardian, 13 June 2018, accessed via www.theguardian.
com/business/2018/jun/13/euro-growth-eurozone-joseph-stiglitz.
Hedging
HEDGING
The process of insuring one’s
business against foreign exchange
risk by using instruments such as
forward exchanges and foreign
exchange swaps
SPOT EXCHANGE RATE
The rate at which a foreign exchange
dealer converts currency on any
particular day
168
PART 2
The second function of the foreign exchange market is to provide insurance against foreign
exchange risk, which is the possibility that unpredicted changes in future exchange rates
will have adverse consequences for the firm. When a company insures itself against foreign
exchange risk, we say that it is engaging in hedging. To explain how the market performs
this function, we need to examine the following foreign exchange rates and transactions:
•
spot exchange rates
•
forward exchange rates
•
foreign exchange swaps.
When two parties agree to exchange currency and execute the deal immediately
(usually within two days), the transaction is referred to as a spot exchange. Exchange
rates governing such ‘on the spot’ trades are referred to as spot exchange rates. The spot
exchange rate is the rate at which a foreign exchange dealer converts one currency into
another currency on a particular day. Thus, when our Indonesian tourist withdraws foreign
currency using a credit/debit/travel money card through an ATM, or goes to a bank to
convert rupiah into Australian dollars, in order to buy souvenirs, the exchange rate used
will be the spot rate for that day.
Spot exchange rates are reported on a real-time basis on many financial websites. Table 4.1
shows the interbank exchange rates (these differ slightly from customer exchange rates) for
a selection of currencies traded in the foreign exchange market as of 2:27 pm Sydney time
on 4 December 2018. An exchange rate can be quoted in two ways—for example, as the
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd
168
08/07/19 04:03 PM
MAJOR RATES
AUD/USD
USD/CAD
USD/CHF
USD/DKK
EUR/USD
GBP/USD
USD/HKD
USD/JPY
USD/NOK
NZD/USD
USD/SEK
USD/SGD
USD/ZAR
BID
ASK
CROSS RATES
BID
ASK
0.7362
1.3185
0.9966
6.5633
1.1368
1.2737
7.8085
113.3040
8.5112
0.6957
9.00112
1.3653
13.6736
0.7363
1.3186
0.9970
6.5640
1.1371
1.2740
7.8090
113.3110
8.5172
0.6959
9.0039
1.3654
13.7036
AUD/AUD
AUD/CAD
AUD/CHF
AUD/DKK
AUD/EUR
AUD/GBP
AUD/HKD
AUD/JPY
AUD/NOK
AUD/NZD
AUD/SEK
AUD/SGD
AUD/ZAR
1.0000
0.9707
0.7337
4.8319
0.6474
0.5779
5.7487
83.4160
6.2661
1.0579
6.6268
1.0052
10.0667
1.0000
0.9708
0.7341
4.8327
0.6477
0.5780
5.7495
83.4273
6.2709
1.0583
6.6293
1.0053
10.0895
TABLE 4.1
Spot exchange rates, 2.27 pm,
Sydney, 4 December 2018
NOTE: Bid (buy) is the rate at which a foreign exchange trader is willing to buy the currency. Ask (offer) is the rate at
which the trader is willing to sell the currency.
SOURCE: Travelex Exchange Rates, accessed via http://internationalpayments.travelex.com.au/exchange-rate, on
4 December 2018.
amount of foreign currency A$1 will buy, or as the cost of Australian dollars to buy one
unit of foreign currency. Thus, A$1 bought US$0.70 on 4 December 2018, or it cost A$1.43
to purchase US$1 (ignoring the difference between the bid (buy) and ask (sell) rates for the
purpose of this exercise).
Spot rates change continually, often on a minute-by-minute basis, although the
magnitude of change over such short periods is usually small. The cross rate between
two currencies is determined by reference to their respective rates quoted in a common
third vehicle currency such as the US dollar. For example, the volume of direct exchange
between the Australian dollar and the Norwegian krone is small relative to their exchange
individually with the US dollar or euro. Consequently, an exchange rate (the cross rate)
between the Australian dollar and the Norwegian krone (AUD/NOK in Table 4.1) can be
calculated by reference to their individual values in US dollars or euros.
When there is a time lag involved in the receipt of a payment, as is the norm
with credit transactions, changes in spot exchange rates can be problematic for an
international business. For example, a New Zealand company imports laptop computers
from Japan. The company agrees to pay the Japanese supplier ¥100 000 in Japanese yen
(JPY) for each laptop computer in 30 days’ time when the shipment arrives. Suppose
when the purchase agreement is reached, the current New Zealand dollar/Japanese yen
spot exchange rate is NZ$1 = JP¥79. At this rate, each computer costs the importer
NZ$1265 (rounded), that is, 1265.82 = 100 000/79. The importer knows they can sell the
computers the day they arrive for NZ$1500 each, which yields a gross profit of NZ$235
(rounded) on each computer ($1500 − $1265). However, the importer will not have the
funds to pay the Japanese supplier until the computers have been sold. If over the next
30 days the dollar unexpectedly depreciates against the yen, say, to NZ$1 = JP¥65, the
importer will still have to pay the Japanese company JP¥100 000 per computer, but
in dollar terms that would be equivalent to NZ$1538 per computer (rounded), which
is more than they can sell the computers for. A depreciation in the value of the dollar
against the yen from NZ$1 = JP¥79 to NZ$1 = JP¥65 would transform a profitable deal
into an unprofitable one.
To insure or hedge against this risk, the New Zealand importer might want to engage in a
forward exchange. A forward exchange occurs when two parties (usually a trader and their
bank) agree to exchange currency at an exchange rate agreed upon today, but to delay the
CHAPTER 4
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd 169
CROSS RATE
The exchange rate between two
currencies calculated by reference
to their respective rates quoted in a
common third currency
FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
169
08/07/19 04:03 PM
FORWARD EXCHANGE RATE
The exchange rate calculated today
based on future expectations for
exchanging currency at some date
in the future
OUTRIGHT FORWARD
When two parties agree today to
exchange currency at an agreed rate
at some specific date in the future.
Sometimes called ‘foreign exchange
forward’
FOREIGN EXCHANGE (FX) SWAP
An agreement to exchange
currencies on a specified date
coupled with a reversal of the
exchange at a later date at agreed
rates
170
PART 2
settlement of the payment until some specific date in the future. The exchange rate agreed
upon by the two parties determines the currency value of the future transaction, and is
referred to as the forward exchange rate. For most major currencies, forward exchange rates
are quoted for 30 days, 90 days and 180 days into the future. In some cases, it is possible
to get forward exchange rates for several years into the future. Returning to our computer
importer example, let us assume that the 30-day forward exchange rate for converting
dollars into yen is NZ$1 = JP¥75. At the time, the importer signs the purchase contract
with the Japanese supplier, the importer also enters into a 30-day forward exchange
transaction with a foreign exchange dealer (usually their bank) to deliver yen at this
30-day rate. The importer is guaranteed that they will have to pay no more than NZ$1333
(rounded) for each computer ($1333 = $100 000/75). This guarantees the importer a
profit of NZ$167 per computer ($1500 − $1333). They insure or hedge themselves against
the possibility that an unanticipated change in the dollar/yen exchange rate will turn a
profitable deal into an unprofitable one.
In this example, the spot exchange rate (NZ$1 = ¥79) and the 30-day forward rate
(NZ$1 = ¥75) differ. Such differences are normal, as they reflect the expectations of the
foreign exchange market about future currency movements. In our example, the fact
that NZ$1 bought more yen with a spot exchange than with a 30-day forward exchange
indicates foreign exchange dealers expected the dollar to depreciate against the yen
in the next 30 days. When this occurs, the dollar is selling at a discount on the 30-day
forward market (i.e. it is worth less than it is on the spot market). Of course, the opposite
can also occur. If the 30-day forward exchange rate was NZ$1 = ¥85, for example, NZ$1
would buy more yen with a forward exchange than with a spot exchange. In such a case,
the dollar is selling at a premium on the 30-day forward market. This reflects the foreign
exchange dealers’ expectations that the dollar will appreciate against the yen over the
next 30 days.
Not all companies hedge their foreign exchange risk using forward exchange contracts,
nor do they hedge each foreign exchange transaction.5 However, both small and large
traders—exporters and importers—typically hedge against currency losses when the home
currency is high (as was the case in Australia in 2013). Very large and diverse companies,
such as commodity producer BHP, may only hedge a small proportion of their revenue
using financial instruments, as operating in many different countries and commodity
markets provides a natural offset or a ‘natural’ hedge. (We will examine natural hedges in
more detail in the last section of this chapter.) Across the entire portfolio, losses and gains
from unexpected changes in the prices of currencies and commodities may offset each
other in part or in full. However, BHP may use forward exchange to hedge just its net
foreign exchange risks, which is not an appropriate strategy for smaller companies with
little or no currency and product diversification.
The option to enter a forward exchange contract is very important to companies
engaged in international business; however, they make up a relatively small proportion
of an increasing global turnover in foreign exchange instruments. The turnovers of spot
exchange and what is described as a foreign exchange (FX) swap (another form of a hedge) are
proportionally much larger (with the latter being the most popular hedging instruments
among financial institutions). Unlike the foreign exchange forward (also referred to as an
outright forward), a foreign exchange swap involves a pair of offsetting transactions. It
contains forward exchange elements but involves two transaction elements, rather than just
one. A foreign exchange (FX) swap is the exchange of two currencies on a specified date
coupled with a reversal of the exchange of the two currencies at a later date at rates agreed
at the time of the contract. For example, the pair of offsetting transactions may include a
spot/forward pairing or a forward/forward pairing. Other instruments include more exotic
forms of hedging including currency swaps, options and futures.
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd
170
08/07/19 04:03 PM
Swaps are transacted between international borrowers and lenders, between banks and
between governments when it is desirable to move out of one currency into another for
a limited period without incurring foreign exchange risk. A common kind of swap is spot
against forward. Consider an Australian company that takes out a foreign currency loan
to fund its domestic operations. At the same time that the company, through its bank,
converts the borrowed foreign funds to Australian dollars on the spot market, with the
agreement of the bank, it buys forward the foreign currency needed to repay the foreign
currency loan when the loan is due. No uncertainty with respect to exchange rate changes
now exists.
Hedging is not without costs. Presumably in the case of a foreign currency loan, over
the period of the loan, it has been put to profitable use. One cost of hedging comprises the
direct fees paid to the financial intermediaries to set up and transact the hedges. Another
cost is any collateral requirement that the bank may demand in setting up the hedge.
A third cost is the opportunity cost of forgone profit. Hedging denies the company the
opportunity to profit from a favourable change in the exchange rate, as was the case with
the industrial manufacturer Embraer from Brazil (see Management Focus: ‘Embraer and the
gyrations of the Brazilian real’). In a sense, these costs could be regarded as the premium for
foreign exchange risk insurance.
MANAGEMENT FOCUS
EMBRAER AND THE GYRATIONS
OF THE BRAZILIAN REAL
For many years, Brazil was a country battered by
persistently high inflation. As a result, the value of its
currency, the real, depreciated steadily against the
US dollar. This changed in the early 2000s, when the
Brazilian government was successful in bringing down
annual inflation rates into the single digits. Lower
inflation, coupled with policies that paved the way for
the expansion of the Brazilian economy, resulted in a
steady appreciation of the real against the US dollar. In
May 2004, 1 real bought US$0.3121; by August 2008,
1 real bought US$0.65, an appreciation of more than
100 per cent.
The appreciation of the real against the dollar
was a mixed bag for Embraer, the world’s largest
manufacturer of regional jets of up to 110 seats and
one of Brazil’s most prominent industrial companies.
Embraer purchases many of the parts that go into its
jets, including the engines and electronics, from US
manufacturers. As the real appreciated against the
dollar, these parts cost less when translated into reals,
which benefited Embraer’s profit margins. However,
the company also prices its aircraft in US dollars, as do
all manufacturers in the global market for commercial
CHAPTER 4
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd 171
jet aircraft. So, as the real appreciated against the
dollar, Embraer’s dollar revenue was compressed when
exchanged back into reals.
To try to deal with the impact of currency appreciation
on its revenue, in the mid-2000s, Embraer started to
hedge against future appreciation of the real by buying
forward contracts (forward contracts give the holder
the right to exchange one currency—in this case,
dollars—for another—in this case, reals—at some point
in the future at a predetermined exchange rate). If the
real had continued to appreciate, this would have been
a great strategy for Embraer because the company
could have locked in the rate at which sales made in
dollars were exchanged back into reals. Unfortunately
for Embraer, as the GFC unfolded in 2008, investors
fled to the dollar, which they viewed as a safe haven,
and the real depreciated against the dollar. Between
August 2008 and November 2008, the value of the
real fell by almost 40 per cent against the dollar. But
for the hedging, this depreciation would have actually
increased Embraer’s revenue in reals. Embraer,
however, had locked itself into a much higher real/
dollar exchange rate, and the company was forced to
FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
171
08/07/19 04:03 PM
take a $121 million loss on what was essentially a bad
currency bet.
Since the shock of 2008, Embraer has cut back on
currency hedging, and most of its dollar sales and
purchases are not hedged. This makes Embraer’s sales
revenue very sensitive to the real/dollar exchange rate.
By 2010, the Brazilian real was once more appreciating
against the US dollar, which pressured Embraer’s
revenue. By 2012, however, the Brazilian economy
was stagnating, while inflation was starting to increase
again. This led to a sustained fall in the value of the
real, which fell from 1 real = US$0.644 in July 2011 to
1 real = US$0.32 by February 2017, a depreciation of
50 per cent. What was bad for the Brazilian currency,
however, was good for Embraer, whose share price
surged to the highest price since February 2008 on
speculation that the decline on the real would lead to a
boost in Embraer’s revenue when expressed in reals.
SOURCES: D. Godoy, ‘Embraer rallies as Brazilian currency weakens’, Bloomberg, 31 May 2013; K. Kroll, ‘Embraer fourth quarter profits plunge 44%
on currency woes’, Cleveland.com, 27 March 2009; ‘A fall from grace: Brazil’s mediocre economy’, The Economist, 8 June 2013; ‘Brazil’s economy: the
deterioration, The Economist, 7 December 2013.
DETERMINATION OF THE EXCHANGE RATE
LO 4.2
If we can understand how exchange rates are determined, we may be able to forecast
exchange rate movements. Because future exchange rate movements influence export and
import opportunities, financing decisions, the profitability of investment and the price
competitiveness of foreign-traded products, this is valuable information for an international
business. Unfortunately, there is no simple explanation. The forces that determine
exchange rates are complex, and no theoretical consensus exists, even among academic
economists who study the phenomenon every day. Consequently, it is beyond the scope of
this book to delve too deeply into these theoretical explanations.
The most general explanation is that exchange rates are determined by the demand
and supply of one currency relative to the demand and supply of another. However, while
differences in relative demand and supply explain the determination of exchange rates, this
explanation does not tell us what factors underlie the decisions to buy and sell a currency.
The state of a country’s economy with respect to its money supply, interest rates, trade
balances and production levels may be expected to influence the decision to buy and sell
its currency. Such fundamental economic factors, however, do not seem to affect exchange
rates, at least in the short run.6 Indeed, one reviewer concluded that economists have found
that the best forecast of the exchange rate in the short run is whatever it happens to be
today.7 Despite disagreement on the single best explanation, economists seem to agree that
three factors have an important impact on the longer-run, future exchange rate movements:
price inflation, interest rates and market psychology.8
Prices and exchange rates
LAW OF ONE PRICE
The principle that in competitive
markets free of transportation costs
and barriers to trade, identical
products sold in different countries
must sell for the same price when
their price is expressed in the same
currency
172
PART 2
To understand how prices are related to exchange rate movements, we first need to
discuss an economic proposition known as the law of one price. We will then discuss
the theory of purchasing power parity (PPP), which links changes in the exchange rate
between two countries’ currencies to changes in the countries’ price levels.
The law of one price
The law of one price states that in competitive markets free of transportation costs and
barriers to trade (such as tariffs), identical products sold in different countries must sell for
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd
172
08/07/19 04:03 PM
the same price when their price is expressed in terms of the same currency. For example,
if the exchange rate between the British pound and the Australian dollar is £1 = A$1.50, a
jacket that retails for A$75 in Sydney should sell for £50 in London (since A$75/1.50 = 50).
Consider what would happen if the jacket cost £40 in London (A$60). At this price, it
would pay a trader to buy jackets in London and sell them in Sydney, an example of
arbitrage, with an initial profit of A$15 on each. However, the process of arbitrage increases
the demand for jackets in London, which would raise their price in London, and would
increase the supply of jackets in Sydney, which would lower their price there, other things
remaining unchanged including the exchange rate staying at £1 = A$1.50. The process
would continue until the prices were equalised and arbitrage is no longer profitable.
The prices might equalise at £45 (A$67.50) in London and A$67.50 in Sydney.
Purchasing power parity (PPP)
If the law of one price were true for all goods and services, an exchange rate based on
purchasing power could be found from any individual set of prices. By comparing the
prices of identical products in different currencies, it would be possible to determine the
‘real’ or purchasing power parity (PPP) exchange rate, assuming markets are free of any
impediments. Thus, if a basket of goods costs A$200 in Australia and the identical basket
cost ¥20 000 in Japan, PPP theory predicts that the dollar/yen exchange rate should be
A$200/¥20 000, or A$0.01 per Japanese yen (i.e. A$1 = ¥100).
The magazine The Economist regularly publishes its own version of the PPP theorem,
which it refers to as the ‘Big Mac index’ or ‘burgernomics’. The Economist has selected
McDonald’s Big Mac as a proxy for a basket of goods because it is produced according to
more or less the same recipe in nearly 120 countries. The Big Mac PPP is the exchange
rate that would have hamburgers costing the same in each country. According to The
Economist, comparing a country’s actual exchange rate with the one predicted by the PPP
theorem based on the relative prices of Big Macs is a test on whether or not a currency
is undervalued. This is not a totally serious exercise, as The Economist admits, but it does
provide us with a useful illustration of the PPP theorem.
A sample of developed and emerging economies selected from the Big Mac index for
July 2018 is shown in Table 4.2. To calculate the index, The Economist converts the price
of a Big Mac in a country into US dollars, the main vehicle currency, at current exchange
rates and divides that by the average price of a Big Mac in the United States. According
to the PPP theorem, the prices should be the same. If they are not, it implies that the
currency is either overvalued against the US dollar or undervalued. The PPP theory argues
that the exchange rate will change if relative prices change. The PPP view of exchange rate
determination is that exchange rate movements tend to offset changes in relative prices
(e.g. due to differences in national inflation rates) so that the ‘real’ exchange rate remains
the same (‘real’ reflects purchasing power.) For example, imagine there is no price inflation
in Australia, while prices in Japan are increasing by 10 per cent a year. At the beginning of
the year, a basket of goods costs A$200 in Australia and ¥20 000 in Japan, so the dollar/
yen exchange rate, according to PPP theory, should be A$1 = ¥100. At the end of the year,
the basket of goods still costs A$200 in Australia, but it costs ¥22 000 in Japan. PPP theory
predicts that the exchange rate should change as a result. The new exchange rate will
be ¥1 = $0.0091 (E$/¥ = A$200/¥22 000 or A$1 = ¥110). Because of 10 per cent price
inflation, the Japanese yen has depreciated by 10 per cent against the Australian dollar. One
dollar will buy 10 per cent more yen at the end of the year than at the beginning.
In essence, PPP theory predicts that a country in which price inflation is running
high should expect to see its currency depreciate against that of countries in which
inflation rates are lower. This is intuitively appealing, but is it true in practice? Extensive
empirical testing of PPP theory has yielded mixed results.9 Although PPP theory seems
CHAPTER 4
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd 173
PURCHASING POWER PARITY (PPP)
An adjustment in gross national
income per capita to reflect
differences in the cost of living
FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
173
08/07/19 04:03 PM
TABLE 4.2
The Big Mac index, selected
countries, July 2018
COUNTRY
United States
Australia
Brazil
United Kingdom
Chile
China
Euro
India
Indonesia
Japan
Mexico
Poland
Russia
South Africa
South Korea
Switzerland
IN LOCAL
CURRENCY
(ROUNDED)
6
6
17
3
2640
21
4
173
31500
390
49
10
130
31
4500
6.50
IN US$
IMPLIED PPP FX
RATE (PX/P$)
5.51
5.51
5.51
5.51
5.51
5.51
5.51
5.51
5.51
5.51
5.51
5.51
5.51
5.51
5.51
5.51
1
1.10
3.07
0.58
479.13
3.72
0.73
31.40
5716.88
70.78
10.23
1.83
23.59
5.63
816.7
1.18
ACTUAL FX
RATE
1
1.34
3.84
0.75
651.73
6.62
0.85
68.83
14360
111.25
15.74
3.69
62.14
13.36
1116.0
0.99
UNDER(–)/OVER(+)
VALUED, %
0
−18
−20
−23
−27
−44
−14
−54
−60
−36
−53
−50
−62
−58
−27
+19
SOURCE: Original data extracted from Big Mac Index, December 2018, The Economist, accessed via https://www.
economist.com/news/2018/07/11/the-big-mac-index on 4 December 2018.
© Ingram Publishing/SuperStock
to yield relatively accurate predictions in the long
run, it does not appear to be a strong predictor of
short-run movements in exchange rates covering
time spans of five years or less.10 Several factors
may explain these results.11 These factors include
the price differentials created by transport
costs, barriers to trade and the market power of
multinational corporations to set prices, control
distribution channels and differentiate product
offerings between nations.12 Other factors include
government intervention in foreign exchange
markets to influence the value of their currencies,
and the impact of investor psychology, which is
discussed later in this chapter.
Interest rates and exchange rates
FISHER EFFECT
The theory that nominal interest
rates (i) in each country equal the
required real rate of interest (r) and
expected rate of inflation (I) over the
time period for which the funds are
to be lent. That is, i = r + I
174
PART 2
Interest rate differentials and inflation expectations are considered to influence exchange
rates. In countries where inflation is expected to be high, interest rates will also be
high because investors want compensation for the decline in the value of their money
over time. This relationship between inflation and the interest rate, formalised by the
economist Irving Fisher in 1930, is referred to as the Fisher Effect (or the Domestic Fisher
Effect, to distinguish it from the International Fisher Effect). The Fisher Effect states that
a country’s nominal interest rate (i) is the sum of the required real rate of interest (r) and
the expected rate of inflation (I) over the period for which the funds are to be lent. The
real interest rate is what an investor or lender expects to yield from their investment after
accounting for any change in the purchasing power of their money due to inflation. More
formally, i = r + I.
For example, if the real rate of interest in a country is 5 per cent and annual inflation is
expected to be 10 per cent, the nominal interest rate will be 15 per cent. As predicted by
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd
174
08/07/19 04:03 PM
To test the Big Mac index, which applies the purchasing
power parity (PPP) theory using the price of a Big Mac
in various markets to determine the equilibrium value
of the foreign currency, The Economist established a
Starbucks index in 2004. Like the Big Mac, a cup of
Starbucks coffee can be found in many foreign markets
and can be seen as a proxy for a basket of goods.
The results of the Starbucks index followed the Big
Mac index in most markets, except in Asia, where the
former indicated that the dollar was at parity with the
Chinese yuan. The Big Mac index suggested that
the yuan was heavily undervalued. Neither of these
consumer items is a good proxy for a basket of goods,
but comparing their relative prices with exchange
rates is an interesting and playful approach to quickly
grasping how under or overvalued the foreign
currency is against the dollar. This obviously does not
take into account whether you think a McDonald’s
Big Mac or a Starbucks cup of coffee is overpriced
© M. Unal Ozmen/Shutterstock
ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
WHAT ABOUT THE STARBUCKS INDEX:
A GOOD IDEA?
or relatively cheap where you live! What would be a
good Australian product, if sold worldwide, that could
replace the Big Mac and Starbucks indices?
the Fisher Effect, a strong relationship seems to exist between inflation rates and interest
rates.13
When investors are free to transfer capital between countries, real interest rates
should be the same in every country. If differences in real interest rates emerge between
countries, arbitrage would soon equalise them. It follows from the Fisher Effect that if the
real interest rate is the same worldwide, any difference in interest rates between countries
reflects differing expectations about inflation rates. Thus, if the expected rate of inflation in
Australia is greater than that in Japan, Australian nominal interest rates will be greater than
Japanese nominal interest rates.
Since we know from PPP theory that there is a link (in theory, at least) between
inflation and exchange rates, and since interest rates reflect expectations about inflation,
it follows that there must also be a link between interest rates and exchange rates. The
country with the higher market (or nominal) interest rate has the higher inflation rate and,
therefore, the currency of that country should fall in value relative to other currencies. This
link is known as the International Fisher Effect. The International Fisher Effect states that
for any two countries, the spot exchange rate should change in an equal amount but in
the opposite direction to the difference in nominal interest rates between the two countries.
If the Australian nominal interest rate is higher than Japan’s, reflecting greater expected
inflation rates, the value of the Australian dollar against the yen should fall by that interest
rate differential in the future. So, if the nominal interest rate in Australia is 10 per cent and
CHAPTER 4
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd 175
INTERNATIONAL FISHER EFFECT
The theory that for any two
countries, the spot exchange rate
should change in an equal amount
but in the opposite direction to the
difference in nominal interest rates
between countries
FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
175
08/07/19 04:03 PM
in Japan it is 6 per cent, we would expect the value of the Australian dollar to depreciate
by 4 per cent against the Japanese yen. In other words, this theory predicts that an interest
rate differential in favour of Australia’s financial assets will be matched by an expected
depreciation of the Australian dollar. Nominal interest rate differentials may be used to
predict exchange rate movements.
Do interest rate differentials help predict future currency movements? The
evidence is mixed. In the long run, there seems to be a relationship between interest
rate differentials and subsequent changes in spot exchange rates, but like PPP the
International Fisher Effect is not a good predictor of short-run changes in spot
exchange rates.14
The International Fisher Effect does remind us, however, that an investment in a foreign
asset requires more than just a comparison of interest rate returns. One needs also to assess
the expected changes in the exchange rate. The return on an investment depends on both
the interest rate differential and the appreciation or depreciation of the exchange rate. The
International Fisher Effect says that the interest rate return on the foreign investment will
be offset by an exchange rate change.
Investor psychology and the bandwagon effect
BANDWAGON EFFECT
When traders move like a herd, all in
the same direction and at the same
time, in response to each other’s
perceived actions
176
PART 2
Various psychological factors play an important role in determining the expectations of
market traders as to likely future exchange rates.15 In turn, expectations have a tendency
to become self-fulfilling prophecies as traders ‘jump on the bandwagon’. For example,
if more and more traders begin to sell a currency and buy another in expectation of a
decline in the value of that currency, then that currency will most likely decline in value
if enough traders jump on the bandwagon. With traders moving as a herd in the same
direction at the same time—the bandwagon effect—the massive selling will force down
the value and traders’ expectations are realised. The decline in value occurs not so much
because of any major shifts in economic fundamentals, but because traders have followed
the actions of others.
According to a number of studies, investor psychology and bandwagon effects play
a major role in determining short-run movements of exchange rates.16 These factors
may explain why the PPP theory and the International Fisher Effect are not particularly
good at explaining short-term movements in exchange rates. Investor psychology can
be influenced by political factors, many of which are only loosely linked to economic
fundamentals such as relative inflation rates. Also, idiosyncratic behaviour by politicians
can both trigger and exacerbate bandwagon effects. Bandwagon effects and speculative
attacks, together with ill-conceived policy decisions played major roles in the collapse
of the Asian currencies during the financial crisis that erupted across South-East Asia in
1997.17
More recent political events that have increased the volatility of global currency market
speculation include the Brexit referendum in the United Kingdom in 2016, where the
country’s decision to split from the EU created an exogenous shock in the market that
sharply impacted the value of the GBP. The election of US President Trump shortly after
the Brexit announcement, a leader who heralded a new, independent and corporate style of
leadership that prioritised domestic fiscal stimulus, resulted in the immediate strengthening
of the US dollar. This was significant given the importance of the US dollar as a reserve
currency in the global economy, and the correlating negative impact on the currencies of
major trading partners.
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd
176
08/07/19 04:03 PM
THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
It has been assumed to this point that the foreign exchange market was the primary
institution for determining exchange rates. Furthermore, it was explained that the decision
to buy or sell currencies in the foreign exchange market may be influenced by factors such
as relative inflation rates and interest rates. Exchange rates, however, are often manipulated
by governments to achieve certain policy goals.
When a country allows the foreign exchange market to be free of any government
intervention to determine the relative value of a currency, we say that the country
is adhering to a freely floating exchange rate system. The world’s four major trading
currencies—the US dollar, the EU euro, the Japanese yen and the British pound—are all free
to float against each other. Australia and New Zealand also allow their exchange rates to
float. In countries where the exchange rates are not determined by the free play of market
forces, other systems or regimes are adopted to govern the exchange rate, such as the ‘daily
fixed’ control of the Chinese renminbi by government authorities. (See Emerging Markets:
‘China’s exchange rate regime’.) These different regimes form part of the international
monetary system in which foreign business operates. Before examining the nature and
functions of the international monetary system, it is useful to understand the different
exchange rate regimes.
LO 4.1
FLOATING EXCHANGE RATE
A system under which the exchange
rate is determined and adjusted
by the market forces of supply and
demand
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY
SYSTEM
The institutional arrangements
countries adopt that govern
exchange rates
EMERGING MARKETS
CHINA’S EXCHANGE RATE REGIME
For years, there have been claims from politicians in
the United States that the Chinese actively manipulate
their currency, the yuan, keeping its value low
against the US dollar and other major currencies in
order to boost Chinese exports. In November 2015, for
example, presidential hopeful Donald Trump claimed
that ‘the wanton manipulation of China’s currency’
was ‘robbing Americans of billions of dollars in capital
and millions of jobs’. But was this claim true? Would it
even be possible for China to manipulate the foreign
exchange markets to artificially depress the value of
its currency? To answer these questions, one needs
to look at the history of exchange rate determination
for China and understand something about how the
international monetary system actually works.
For most of its history, the Chinese yuan was pegged
to the US dollar at a fixed exchange rate. When China
started to open up its economy to foreign trade and
investment in the 1980s, the yuan was devalued
by the Chinese government in order to improve the
competitiveness of Chinese exports. Thus, the official
yuan/USD pegged exchange rate was increased from
CHAPTER 4
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd 177
1.50 yuan per US dollar in 1980 to 8.62 yuan per
US dollar in 1994. With China’s exports growing and
the country running a growing current account trade
surplus, pressure began to increase for China to let its
currency appreciate. In response, between 1997 and
2005, the exchange rate was fixed at 8.27 yuan per
US dollar, which represented a small appreciation. One
could argue that during this period, China’s currency
was indeed undervalued and that this was the result of
government policy.
By the 2000s, China’s growing importance in the global
economy and the rise of its export-led economy led to
calls for the country to re-evaluate its fixed exchange
rate policy. In response, in July 2005, the country
adopted a managed floating exchange rate system.
Under this system, the exchange rate for the yuan was
set with reference to a basket of foreign currencies that
included the US dollar, the euro, the Japanese yen, and
the British pound. The daily exchange rate was allowed
to float within a narrow band of 0.3 per cent around the
central parity. The daily band was extended to 0.5 per
cent in 2007, 1 per cent in 2012 and 2 per cent in 2014.
FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
177
08/07/19 04:03 PM
Over time, this managed-float system allowed for the
appreciation of the Chinese yuan. For example, the
exchange rate changed from 8.27 yuan per US dollar
in mid-2005 to 6.0875 yuan per US dollar on 20 July
2015, representing an appreciation of 26 per cent.
More generally, the effective exchange rate index
of the yuan against a basket of more than 60 other
currencies increased from 86.3 in July 2005 to 123.8
by early 2016, representing an appreciation of 43 per
cent. The yuan appreciated by less than this against
the US dollar primarily because the US dollar has also
been relatively strong and appreciated against many
other currencies over the same time period.
These data suggest that rather than artificially trying
to keep their currency undervalued, since July 2005
the Chinese have allowed the yuan to increase in value
against other currencies, albeit within the constraints
imposed by the managed float. In late 2015 this
commitment was put to the test when a slowdown in
the rate of growth of the Chinese economy led to an
outflow of capital from China, which put downward
pressure on the yuan. China responded by trying
to maintain the value of the yuan, using its foreign
exchange reserves, which are primarily held in US
dollars, to buy yuan on the open market and shore up
its value. Reports suggest that China spent $500 billion
in 2015 to shore up the value of the yuan and more
than $1 trillion in 2016. These actions reduced China’s
foreign exchange reserves to $3.011 trillion by January
2017, the lowest level since 2012. China appears to
be trying to keep the yuan from depreciating below
7 yuan to the US dollar.
One reason for China trying to protect the value of the
yuan against the US dollar: a large number of Chinese
companies have US dollar-denominated debt. If the
yuan falls against the US dollar, the price of serving
that debt goes up when translated into yuan. This could
stress those companies (possibly pushing some into
bankruptcy) and make it more difficult for China to hit
the government’s economic growth targets. Another
reason: China might want to head off charges from
the Trump administration that it continues to keep the
value of its currency artificially low.
SOURCES: T. Hult, ‘The US shouldn’t fret over cheaper yuan’, Time, 14 August 2015; ‘The yuan and the markets’, The Economist, 16 January 2016;
M. Gesiotto, ‘The negative effects of China’s currency manipulation explained’, Washington Times, 13 November 2015; M. Slaughter, ‘The myths of
China’s currency manipulation’, The Wall Street Journal, 8 January 2016; ‘The curious case of China’s currency’, The Economist, 11 August 2015;
L. Wei, ‘China foreign exchange reserves keep dropping’, The Wall Street Journal, 8 January 2017.
Exchange rate regimes in practice
LO 4.3
FIXED EXCHANGE RATE SYSTEM
The exchange rate is pegged and
does not vary with market forces
PEGGED EXCHANGE RATE
The exchange rate is fixed relative
to a reference currency or basket
of currencies, and this exchange
rate is defended by government
intervention in the foreign exchange
market
178
PART 2
Exchange rate regimes or systems range from a pure ‘free float’, where the exchange
rate is determined by the unfettered market forces of demand and supply, to a fixed-peg
system—more generally referred to as a fixed exchange rate system. A pegged exchange
rate is one where the currency value is fixed in terms of some other currency or unit
of money. In the past, currencies were pegged to gold but today many are pegged to
other currencies, such as the US dollar, the euro or a basket of currencies. The almost
pure form of a fixed-pegged system was the gold standard overseen by the British, which
was effectively the international monetary system from 1880 to 1939. The International
Monetary Fund classifies exchange rate regimes according to their degree of flexibility and
the extent to which they limit a nation’s monetary policy independence.18 Leaving aside
the issue of monetary policy independence for the moment, current exchange rate regimes
fit somewhere along a continuum of flexibility (or the converse, a continuum of fixity)
from a fixed-peg system to a free-float system, as shown in Figure 4.2. The exchange rate
regimes at the left-hand end of the spectrum are characterised by purposeful government
intervention, usually via their central banks. The aim is to establish and defend a particular
exchange rate level or path in the face of contrary market forces. At the right-hand end,
the foreign exchange market is free to determine the exchange rate; and away from the
ends, there is a mix of different degrees of government interventions and market forces
that determine the exchange rate.
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd
178
08/07/19 04:03 PM
Fixed peg
Managed peg
‘Hard peg’ range
Managed float
Free float
FIGURE 4.2
Degree of flexibility of exchange
rate regimes
‘Soft peg’ range
Increasing degree of flexibility
Classifying exchange rate regimes is complicated, as there is a difference between de
facto regimes (what countries follow in practice) and de jure regimes (what countries claim
officially to practise). A further complexity is that countries change their regimes as economic
conditions change, such as their stage of economic development, the level of global integration,
and the country’s vulnerability to external economic and financial shocks. For example,
the post-World War II history of Australia’s exchange rate regime changes is as follows: the
Australian pound (before decimalisation in 1966) (later dollar) was fixed or pegged to the
UK pound sterling until December 1971; fixed to the US dollar until September 1974; fixed
to a trade-weighted basket of currencies until November 1976; on a variable peg against the
trade-weighted basket until December 1983, then floated on 12 December 1983.19 Over time,
Australia’s regime has moved to the right across virtually the full continuum in Figure 4.2.
ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
SHOULD COUNTRIES BE FREE TO SET
CURRENCY POLICY?
Exchange rates are critically important in the global
economy. They affect the price of every country’s
imports and exports, companies’ foreign direct
investment and—directly or indirectly—people’s
spending behaviours. In recent years, disagreements
among countries over exchange rates have become
much more widespread. Some government officials
and analysts even suggest that there is a ‘currency war’
among certain countries. The main issue is whether or
not some countries are using exchange rate policies
to undermine free currency markets and whether they
intentionally, in essence, devalue their currency to gain
a trade advantage at the expense of other countries.
A weaker currency makes exports inexpensive (or at
least cheaper) to foreigners, which can lead to higher
exports and job creation in the export sector.
SOURCE: R.M. Nelson, ‘Debates over exchange rates: overview and issues for Congress’, Congressional Research Service, 22 June 2018.
Of 192 countries, 42 per cent operate exchange rate regimes in the intermediate ‘soft
peg’ range and towards the ‘float’ range; nearly 13 per cent operate in the ‘hard peg’ range;
and about 40 per cent operate in the ‘managed float’ to ‘free float’ range.20
Broadly speaking, how do peg systems and floating systems differ? In the ‘hard peg’
and ‘soft peg’ ranges, the main aim is to maintain a predetermined exchange rate against
another currency or basket of currencies. There are many variants of ‘soft pegs’ in this
middle range. Some systems have allowances for fluctuations of the exchange rate in
a band around this peg. Others allow the peg to move incrementally up or down over
time (the ‘crawling peg’). We will discuss the following two points in more detail shortly
but, in brief, to maintain the peg (particularly if it is under threat of depreciation from
CHAPTER 4
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd 179
FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
179
08/07/19 04:03 PM
FOREIGN EXCHANGE RESERVES
The reserves such as foreign
currencies, gold, special credits and
reserve positions with the IMF that
central banks use to intervene in the
foreign exchange market
MANAGED OR ‘DIRTY’ FLOAT
SYSTEM
A system under which a country’s
currency is nominally allowed to
float freely against other currencies,
but in which the government will
intervene if it believes the currency
has deviated too far from its fair
value
market forces), a country will need foreign exchange reserves to defend the peg. Foreign
exchange reserves can comprise key currencies such as the US dollar, yen and euro, gold,
special credits and reserve positions held with the IMF. Second, countries that adopt ‘hard’
and ‘soft’ peg regimes forgo to various degrees independent monetary policy. Countries
operating exchange rate systems in these ranges, ranked in order from ‘hard peg’ to ‘soft
peg’ (from left to right in Figure 4.2), include Hong Kong (SAR) and Saudi Arabia, which are
anchored to the US dollar; Denmark, which is anchored to the euro; China, which uses a
‘monetary aggregate target’; New Zealand, which floats to an ‘inflation targeting framework’;
and Russia, which free floats to an ‘inflation targeting framework’.21
Countries that operate in the floating rate regimes allow the foreign exchange market
to determine the exchange rate. In this range some intervention may occur to manage
short-term economic and financial shocks to the system. The Reserve Bank of New
Zealand has not intervened in the foreign exchange market since the New Zealand dollar
was floated in March 1985. It reserves intervention for cases of ‘extreme disorder’ in the
foreign exchange market.22 When such intervention persists, however, one may question
whether or not the regime is a true float system or a managed or ‘dirty’ float system. The
more derogatory descriptor is often raised by other countries who feel they have been
competitively disadvantaged by a country’s exchange rate policy. The term ‘dirty float’
is applied when it is thought that the goal of the intervention in reality is to maintain a
target peg, and not the often-stated goal of limiting short-term volatility. Countries which
operate in this ‘floating’ range—ranked in order of more interventionist (managed float) to
less interventionist (free float)—include Brazil, Indonesia, Turkey, India, Australia, Poland and
the United States.23 Unless the country is actively involved in managing the float, floating
exchange rate regimes do not have as high a requirement as pegged rate regimes for foreign
reserves, and floating exchange rate regimes afford a country greater monetary policy
autonomy.
Motives and means for managing the foreign exchange rate
Although their exchange rate policies may result in different degrees of flexibility or fixity,
governments or their central banks can use exchange rate changes to achieve a number of
goals.24 Exchange rate policy can be used to control inflation, enhance the international
competitiveness for domestic industries, correct a balance of payments deficit, and limit
the impact on the economy of an external financial crisis. For example, the devaluation of
a currency by 10 per cent is equivalent to a 10 per cent ad valorem tariff on imports and a
10 per cent ad valorem subsidy for exporters.
Near two-thirds of the world’s economies operate a form of fixed or pegged exchange
rate system. How does a country intervene in the foreign exchange market to defend
and maintain its target peg? It does it by manipulating, to the extent that it can, the
demand and supply of its currency in the foreign exchange market. For example, when
Venezuela (a country that anchors its exchange rate to the US dollar) was experiencing
higher inflation rates than its trading partners, the foreign exchange market would be
putting downward pressure on the exchange rate (as predicted by the PPP theory). One
source of such pressure would be the result of less demand for Venezuelan exports at the
current exchange rate. Consequently, there would be less demand for the Venezuelan
bolivar (VEF) in the foreign exchange market. Additional pressure would arise from shortterm capital outflows as investors, expecting a depreciation of the currency, look to invest
in assets denominated in a stronger foreign currency. This action leads to an additional
supply of Venezuelan bolivar in the foreign exchange market at the current exchange
rate. To relieve the combination of these demand and supply pressures, Venezuela’s central
180
PART 2
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd
180
08/07/19 04:03 PM
bank could have entered the foreign exchange market to buy up the extra bolivars being
placed in the foreign exchange market at the current exchange rate. For this purpose, the
central bank would have needed to use its holdings of reserves of foreign currencies and
credits (particularly USD denominations) to exchange for bolivars, buying up the excess
Venezuelan bolivars. Creating the extra demand holds up the price of the currency at or
near the targeted rate or peg.
There is one obvious limit to this method of intervention when there are mounting
depreciation pressures on the currency: the central bank can intervene only to the extent
that it has access to foreign exchange reserves. Unlike the US Federal Reserve, the central
bank of Venezuela cannot print US dollars.
Managing foreign exchange using these measures has been ineffective and beyond
the reach of Venezuela, tragically. Since 2016, the economy has spiralled out of control. In
2018, the black-market exchange rate of the bolivar was devalued to around 100 000 per
USD, down from 960 per USD in 2016 (and 64 USD in 2014). This epic decline of historic
proportions has resulted in Venezuela being the poorest country in Latin America. In a
desperate bid to reverse the woeful state of the country, some have suggested abandoning
the bolivar altogether in favour of the USD. (To learn more about the background
contributing to the downfall of the bolivar, see Another Perspective: ‘Can dollarisation save
Venezuela?’)
ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
CAN DOLLARISATION SAVE VENEZUELA?
The country’s economic decline dates back to the
rule of Hugo Chavez, who took power in 1999.
Chavez significantly raised the royalty rate that
foreign oil companies had to pay to the government.
The oil companies responded by not investing in
Venezuela and looking for oil elsewhere. Chavez
then compounded the problem by pushing out the
professional management of the state-run oil company,
replacing them with his own political appointees. The
result included underinvestment in exploration and
extraction infrastructure and falling oil output. By 2017,
CHAPTER 4
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd 181
© Digital Archive Japan/Alamy Stock Photo
Venezuela is in deep trouble. Although the country
boasts the largest oil reserves on the planet, a fact
that should make it rich, poor governance (declining
oil prices and US economic sanctions) has created
an economic crisis of historic proportions and turned
the country into the poorest nation in Latin America.
The Venezuelan economy contracted by 16.5 per
cent in 2016, and another 12 per cent in 2017, while
unemployment surged to over 26 per cent. Due to food
shortages, some two-thirds of the population have
reported significant weight loss.
oil output had fallen by 50 per cent from its peak in
1998, a major problem for a country where crude oil
makes up about 95 per cent of exports.
Early in his rule, Chavez spent oil revenue liberally
on social programs, including price controls and fuel
subsidies. Initially this helped the poor and boosted
FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
181
08/07/19 04:03 PM
his popularity. However, by 2012 significant strains
were showing in the economy, including declining oil
production and exports, rising unemployment, high
inflation and ballooning government deficits.
Chavez died in 2013 and was succeeded by Nicolas
Maduro. Maduro continued on the trajectory set by
Chavez. Unfortunately for Maduro, oil prices and output
both fell sharply, reducing government revenue. Rather
than abandoning the social programs and subsidies,
Maduro simply expanded the government’s budget
deficit, raising it to a staggering 38 per cent of GDP
by 2017. He financed that deficit by printing money.
Predictably, the result has been hyperinflation. The
inflation rate surged to 250 per cent in 2016 and then
to around 2700 per cent in 2017, the highest in the
world. This made the country’s currency, the bolivar,
virtually worthless, stifling commerce, which depends
on a stable currency.
On the foreign exchange market, the value of the
bolivar collapsed, falling from 64 per US dollar in 2014
to 960 by early 2016 and around 100 000 by early
2018! It should be noted that this reflects the exchange
rate on the black market. The official exchange rate
set by the Venezuelan government, which no one pays
any attention to, is 10 bolivars per US dollar. With the
bolivar viewed as worthless, no one wants to trade with
Venezuela unless they get paid in US dollars. With not
enough US dollars in Venezuela to finance international
transactions, that means a shortage of many goods.
When a country experiences this kind of currency
crisis, the normal response is to call in the International
Monetary Fund (IMF). In return for a loan of funds, the
IMF will often advocate austerity programs to reduce
the government budget deficit, along with high-interest
rates and tight controls over the growth in money
supply to reduce inflation. Other policies advocated
by the IMF include the removal of price controls
and subsidies and the privatisation of state-owned
enterprises. However, all of these actions are anathema
to Maduro, who continues to adhere to a hard-line
socialist ideology and blames foreign and domestic
capitalists for his country’s ills.
Opposition figures in Venezuela have suggested
another solution to the country’s currency problems:
dollarisation. This process would involve the
government abandoning the bolivar and instead
introducing cash denominated in US dollars to keep
commerce moving. In fact, de facto dollarisation
is already underway in Venezuela: increasingly,
merchants are ignoring price controls and pricing
goods in US dollars at their free market value.
Unfortunately, Venezuela’s economic collapse has
been so severe that most Venezuelans earn the
equivalent of only a few US dollars per month, so
this doesn’t help them. For dollarisation to work,
the government would have to purchase about
$10 billion worth of US notes and coins and put
them in circulation.
There are precedents for dollarisation. Ecuador
adopted the US dollar in 2000 in order to overcome
soaring inflation and a collapse in the value of its
currency, the sucre. While the switch was painful—
salaries initially fell by 40 per cent, and savings and
pension accounts were ravaged—wages and prices
stabilised and the economy recovered and started
to grow again. However, Maduro has long vilified the
United States, so it is difficult to see him backing a
similar dollarisation effort for Venezuela.
SOURCES: J. Otis and K. Vyas, ‘The dollar rescued Ecuador: can it save Venezuela?’, The Wall Street Journal, 27 March 2018; M. O’Brian, ‘Venezuela
should be rich, but its government has destroyed its economy’, The Washington Post, 21 January 2015; P. Laya, ‘One dollar now buys 103 000 bolivars
in Venezuela’s black market’, Bloomberg Markets, 1 December 2017.
By the same token, under a situation where there are upward pressures on the currency,
the process of intervention to hold down the exchange rate leads to an accumulation of
foreign exchange reserves. The central bank sells its own currency in exchange for foreign
currencies to maintain the target. For example, China and a number of other South-East
Asian economies have run large trade surpluses with upward pressure on their exchange
rates. Intervention to prevent the exchange rate rising has resulted in the accumulation
of large foreign exchange reserve holdings by these countries. While this latter situation
may appear not to act as a restraint on a central bank in holding the exchange rate at
or near its desired pegged rate indefinitely, there can be significant flow-on effects to
182
PART 2
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd
182
08/07/19 04:03 PM
the country’s money supply and domestic economy from these foreign exchange market
interventions. Changes in the domestic money supply affect prices and interest rates, which
in turn have an adverse effect on domestic economic stability and growth. This presents
the policymakers with a dilemma as to whether the goal it is attempting to achieve via
its exchange rate policy is worth the economic (and political) costs of domestic economic
instability.
Policymakers are frequently confronted with the dilemma of such policy trade-offs. We
can illustrate this dilemma in the context of how a government would go about correcting
a significant international balance of payments deficit. Two potentially conflicting goals are
internal balance and external balance. The goal of internal balance is to keep the economy
at or near full-capacity economic growth with near-full employment while avoiding excess
inflation. The goal of external balance is to maintain the balance of payments at a level
such that it avoids foreign debt positions that are unsustainable in the long run.
Suppose there is a significant change in domestic demand favouring imports (e.g.
consumers prefer quality imported products; businesses purchase more technologically
advanced plant and equipment). The balance of payments moves into deficit. The demand
for foreign currency will rise relative to the demand for the domestic currency in the
foreign market at the current exchange rate. There is pressure on the domestic currency
to depreciate. What can governments do when confronted with an external deficit and
a preference to hold the exchange rate at a targeted pegged level? There are a number of
options:
INTERNAL BALANCE
When the economy is operating
at full capacity with near-full
employment and price stability
EXTERNAL BALANCE
When the international balance
of payments is such that foreign
debt obligations into the future
are sustainable for a country or its
trading partners
1. It could defend the peg using its holdings of foreign exchange reserves at the current
pegged rate, giving it some breathing space in the hope that economic conditions will
change and that there will be some adjustment to import preferences. This option
assumes that it has sufficient foreign exchange reserves.
2. It could reduce the demand for imports by using tariff and non-tariff barriers, and
subsidise exports. In the context of being an open economy, this option may be
limited. There may also be the risk of retaliation from trading partners if such a policy
is perceived as a beggar-thy-neighbour strategy. (As discussed in the previous chapter,
beggar-thy-neighbour policy is a policy that yields economic benefits to the home
country, but only at the expense of making other countries incur economic losses.)
3. It could deflate the domestic economy and domestic demand with contractionary
policies, such as a high-interest rate policy or reduced government expenditures. If
the economy was already experiencing high rates of unemployment and business
confidence was low, this would not be an economically or politically acceptable option.
4. It could allow the currency to depreciate. This is an option of last resort under a fixed
exchange rate system.
Each policy presents difficulties for decision makers. Policy 1 simply delays the
inevitability of currency devaluation if the causes of the deficit are long term and
fundamental (e.g. the country’s products are, for whatever the reason, never going to be
attractive to customers). Policies 2 and 4 would most likely be seen as beggar-thy-neighbour
policies, and the government would be seen as moving the burden of adjustment to its
trading partners, inviting retaliation. Domestic economic and political goals would most
likely be given preference over the impacts on other countries’ economies, ruling out
policy 3. In situations of high unemployment and increasing balance of payments deficits
among a number of countries, a likely outcome, therefore, could be trade wars in the form
of increasing trade protection and competitive devaluations. Such events would greatly
deter international trade and foreign investment. As we will see shortly, this in fact was
CHAPTER 4
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd 183
FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
183
08/07/19 04:03 PM
the context in which the Bretton Woods system was established in the 1940s. One goal
of Bretton Woods was to prevent such trade wars. It was the same motivation behind the
rhetoric of the leaders of the G20 economies during the 2007–09 GFC. They called for
members and emerging market economies to restrain from adopting trade and exchange
rate policies that would restrict foreign trade and investment, which has continued to be an
important issue for subsequent G20 summits.25
Functions of an international monetary system
A question arises as to whether the governments of countries that trade and invest with
each other could come to some agreement or establish some international ‘rules of the
game’ by which the types of dilemmas faced by individual countries (as discussed in the
previous section) can be resolved without significant upset to international trade and
investment. There are three functions that an international monetary system established
by such an agreement needs to provide: adjustment, liquidity creation and confidence
building.26
Adjustment
ADJUSTMENT
The process of restoring external
balance
An international monetary system needs to provide an orderly adjustment mechanism
by which countries can correct internal and external imbalances. As we saw above,
depending on the option chosen, the economic and political costs may be domestic
or international—domestic in terms of the loss of economic stability internally; and
international in terms of the adverse impacts on the economies of other countries, as
well as the loss of the benefits from a reduction in international trade and investment
that results from the growing uncertainty of unstable exchange rates and government
interventions.
Liquidity
INTERNATIONAL LIQUIDITY
The international money supply used
to finance trade and investment
and as reserves by central banks to
achieve exchange rate and balance
of payments policy goals
An international monetary system must also provide sufficient international liquidity.
International trade and investment requires money and a stable international finance
system, the same as is required for a productive domestic economy. As there is no single
global currency created by a global central bank, international liquidity is comprised of
a mix of other countries’ currencies (in the main, the US dollar) and other money assets
such as gold and credits held with the IMF. As we saw above, central banks need to hold
or have access to reserves or liquidity to finance external imbalances, at least in the short
term, before resorting perhaps to less palatable policy options; and they need reserves
to defend a goal of stable exchange rates. The supply of international liquidity, therefore,
depends on the capacity of the international monetary system to keep the exchange
values of these money assets relatively stable—otherwise international traders and investors
will not be willing to use them, and in effect the supply of international liquidity will be
greatly reduced.
Confidence
CONFIDENCE
The belief that the institutions
and relations among countries are
sufficiently robust to sustain the
stability of the system in times of
major imbalances
184
PART 2
The third function of an international monetary system is building confidence. Confidence
in, or the credibility of, a financial system underpins its stability. Central banks and
governments need some assurance that all members to an agreement will abide by the
rules and be consistent with their pledges rather than pursue self-interest when it is
economically or politically convenient. Deficit countries, particularly poorer countries, will
need to be assured that there is a ‘lender-of-last-resort’ facility when the private foreign
capital inflows that are used to finance their deficits slow or stop. Holders of reserve
currencies would need to be confident that the reserve-currency countries will not pursue
policies that sharply alter the value of the currencies that they hold in their reserves.
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd
184
08/07/19 04:03 PM
The rise and fall of the Bretton Woods system
In 1944, near the end of World War II, representatives from 44 countries met at Bretton
Woods, New Hampshire, in the United States, to design a new and enduring international
monetary system that would facilitate postwar trade, investment and economic growth.
Fresh in the minds of the countries’ representatives were the beggar-thy-neighbour
exchange rate devaluations and protectionist policies that governments used to combat
the high unemployment of the 1930s Great Depression, the hyperinflation in Germany
and elsewhere, the trade wars, and the general economic disintegration that occurred
between the two world wars. There was consensus that fixed exchange rates were
desirable. The representatives recognised that the previous international monetary system
based on the gold standard would not avoid a return to competitive devaluations. The
major problem with the gold standard as previously constituted was that no multinational
institution could stop countries from engaging in competitive devaluations. The
representatives agreed that individual countries needed to give up national sovereignty
over exchange rates. Exchange rates would become a matter for international management
under the scrutiny of the International Monetary Fund (IMF). While the architecture of
the international monetary system created under Bretton Woods was a creature of its
time, issues such as the sharing of the burden of the adjustment process, the provision
of international liquidity, the degree of domestic autonomy in policymaking, and the
willingness of participating countries to cooperate and play by the rules still exist today.
We can gain an understanding of the current international monetary system by an
examination of the Bretton Woods system and its demise.27
The agreement reached at Bretton Woods established two multinational institutions:
the IMF and the World Bank (or, more officially, the International Bank of Reconstruction
and Development). Both institutions exist to this day. The task of the IMF would be
to maintain order in the international monetary system by policing adherence to rules
governing exchange rate adjustments. The task of the World Bank, with a much more
long-term perspective, would be to promote general economic development. While the
Bank was set up initially to aid the reconstruction of Europe’s war-torn economies, its task
became one of promoting development in the poorer economies.
The key concept of the Bretton Woods system was for countries to agree to have
fixed but adjustable exchange rates. This system promised discipline, stability and
flexibility. Fixing the exchange rate, it was thought, would reduce the volatility associated
with floating exchange rates (not all economists agree that floating exchange rates are
excessively volatile) and prevent competitive devaluations. A fixed exchange rate system
was also seen as a mechanism for imposing monetary policy discipline on countries and for
controlling inflation.
Being able to adjust the exchange rate under the supervision of the IMF was thought to
be able to provide sufficient flexibility to adjust to a persistent ‘fundamental disequilibrium’
in the balance of payments. As we noted above, the fundamentals of an economy may
change, causing a change in the demand and supply of exports and imports. The economic
conditions for a ‘fundamental disequilibrium’ are such that for the foreseeable future a
nation’s products and its markets are never going to be attractive to traders and investors
at the current exchange rate. A balance of payments deficit will persist and a country
will find it difficult to finance the deficit at the current exchange rate peg. In the case
of a fundamental disequilibrium, a devaluation of the currency (a downwards adjustment
of the peg) could be permitted to restore the external balance. The belief was that the
devaluation would enable governments to sidestep painful domestic policy adjustments
such as deflation of the domestic economy, slowing economic growth and rising
unemployment; and from an international perspective, remove the need to resort to trade
CHAPTER 4
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd 185
FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
185
08/07/19 04:03 PM
IMPOSSIBLE TRINITY ARGUMENT
The argument that it is not possible
to have simultaneously a fixed
exchange rate, a free flow of capital
and an independent monetary policy
186
PART 2
and investment barriers. An ‘approved’ devaluation according to the rules would be an
orderly adjustment to exchange rates that would be transparent and not perceived as a selfserving, beggar-thy-neighbour initiative. Policy cooperation across countries was necessary
to build confidence and stability.
To support the fixed peg in the absence of a fundamental disequilibrium, the IMF
stood ready to supplement the foreign exchange reserves of a member from that member’s
IMF credits and a pool of foreign currencies provided in various quotas by other members.
The temporary official financing of external imbalances through the IMF provided a
smooth adjustment process. It provided access to the necessary foreign exchange and
confidence that imbalances could be corrected without undue disturbances to trade
flows, employment and economic growth. At the time, international private capital flows
were expected to play a limited role in financing external imbalances. Controls would be
imposed to protect the domestic economy from any instability arising from short-term
private capital outflows and inflows.
The Bretton Woods system operated effectively until the late 1960s, when it began to
show signs of strain. Although the institutions remained, the system in effect collapsed
in 1973, as adherence to the ‘rules of the game’ of the ‘fixed but adjustable peg system’
lessened. The international financial environment today is now vastly different to that of
the time of Bretton Woods. As we saw earlier, the vast majority of countries now operate
under a soft peg or floating exchange rate regime. The major currencies fluctuate in
response to the market forces. Private capital flows now play a much more dominant role
than they did in the 1950s and 1960s. As the global economy has grown and financial
markets have become more integrated, private international capital flows have grown.
Countries now tend to use international private capital inflows, rather than ‘official’
central bank and IMF sources, to finance balance of payments imbalances. Controls over
private capital flows, a key element of Bretton Woods, have become ineffective, and many
countries have abandoned them.28
While there is no consensus on the reasons for the demise of Bretton Woods, the
increasing reliance on private foreign capital flows and a combination of issues related
to adjustment, liquidity and confidence undermined the Bretton Woods system. The
rise in capital flows created a major strain on the system. According to economists, it
is not possible for a country to have simultaneously a fixed exchange rate regime, free
cross-border capital flows, and an independent monetary policy dedicated to domestic
macroeconomic policy goals such as low inflation and full employment. This is the
impossible trinity argument. The ‘trilemma’ is that as countries become unwilling or
unable to control international private capital flows, they will have to forgo using monetary
policy to attain domestic economic goals if they wish to maintain a fixed exchange rate.
Monetary policy becomes subservient to the goal of maintaining the peg. Not surprisingly,
governments would give higher priority to domestic economic and political interests than
to the stability of the international monetary system. There was an incentive to flaunt the
rules of the game of the Bretton Woods system. They instead would allow some adjustment
to their exchange rate to assist the attainment of domestic goals. Such unilateral action
is symptomatic of beggar-thy-neighbour policies. As the prevalence of floating exchange
regimes attests, today countries rely more on exchange rate changes to adjust for external
balance problems and target monetary policy at domestic inflation and employment goals.
The rules of the game relating to the official adjustment process also required that both
deficit countries and surplus countries cooperate and take action to correct a fundamental
disequilibrium in the balance of payments. A deficit in one country means there are
surpluses in other countries. By the rules of the game, the deficit countries could devalue
officially and surplus countries should revalue their currencies upwards. Surplus countries,
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd
186
08/07/19 04:03 PM
however, would be loath to place their economy at a competitive disadvantage by revaluing
their currency upwards. Consequently, in practice, the burden of adjustment usually fell
on deficit countries to devalue. As it became evident to the foreign exchange market as
to which country was experiencing exchange rate difficulties, speculative attacks on the
deficit country’s currency would occur. These attacks were facilitated by the mobility
of private foreign capital and tended to increase the size of the devaluation. Speculative
attacks and a disproportionate acceptance of the burden of adjustment undermined
confidence in the capacity of the international monetary system under the Bretton Woods
regime to benefit all member countries. When a currency was under speculative attack,
central banks often did not have access to sufficient foreign exchange reserves, either from
their own reserves or IMF reserves, to defend a targeted exchange rate peg.
A further weakness of the Bretton Woods system was the special role played by the
US dollar. The US dollar had become the de facto global currency and the main source
of international liquidity. However, whenever the US economy and the US balance
of payments experienced significant imbalances, confidence in the stability of the
international monetary system would wane. The imbalances would give rise to speculation
in the foreign exchange market that the US dollar would need to be devalued. A bout
of speculation in 1972 saw the US dollar devalued, virtually destroying, at the time,
confidence in the US dollar as a reserve currency and leading ultimately to the demise of
the Bretton Woods system.
A role for the IMF
The IMF was created in 1945 to support, via short-term loans, a system of fixed exchange
rates with a view to stabilising exchange rates, adjusting balance of payments imbalances,
stabilising the international monetary system and facilitating trade. This followed the
traumatic experiences of the severe economic crises of the 1930s Great Depression,
and the non-cooperation and beggar-thy-neighbour economic policies among the major
trading nations of the time to correct internal and external imbalances. The IMF was
the watchdog of the rules-based Bretton Woods international monetary system, which
included obligations for members to maintain fixed exchange rates and to control private
foreign capital flows.
Following the collapse of the Bretton Woods
system in the 1970s and an increasing reliance
by members on floating exchange rates and on
private capital flows to correct and finance balance
of payments imbalances, the IMF was forced to
find a new reason for existence. Periodic national
and regional financial crises that have arisen post–
Bretton Woods, particularly among developing
and emerging market economies, have demanded
that the IMF’s role move beyond support for
countries to retain a particular exchange rate
system.29 While it always was a core responsibility
of the IMF, the focus now is assisting nations with
balance-of-payment problems to find sufficient
financing on affordable terms to meet their net
international payments. Confronted with the
CHAPTER 4
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd 187
© Alexandros Michailidis/Shutterstock
New role
Christine Lagarde headed the IMF from July 2011 to July 2016.
FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
187
08/07/19 04:03 PM
CURRENCY CRISIS
When a speculative attack on an
exchange rate threatens a sharp
depreciation in the value of the
currency and the capacity of
authorities to defend the value
BANKING CRISIS
When a loss of confidence in the
banking system leads to a run on
banks, as individuals and companies
withdraw their deposits
need to put together financial rescue packages for countries and regions that periodically
have experienced damaging financial crisis, IMF resources now play an important role in
helping countries ‘rebuild their international reserves, stabilise their currencies, continue
paying for imports, and restore conditions for strong economic growth, while undertaking
policies to correct underlying problems’.30
The nature of financial crises to which the IMF has responded varies, but they tend
to contain one or more of the elements of a currency crisis, a banking crisis and a debt
crisis.31 A currency crisis occurs when a speculative attack on an exchange value of a
currency results in a sharp depreciation in the value of the currency. During the Asian
financial crisis of 1997–98, the Thai baht depreciated by more than 30 per cent. Such a
crisis often forces monetary authorities to draw down and often exhaust their foreign
exchange reserves and sharply increase interest rates to defend the prevailing exchange
rate. The IMF arranged a rescue package of US$17.2 billion for Thailand to combat
speculative attacks on the baht. In 2002, the IMF lent Brazil US$30 billion to stabilise
the value of its currency and avoid similar speculative attacks. A banking crisis refers to
a loss of confidence in the banking system that leads to a run on banks, as individuals
and companies withdraw their deposits. This crisis of confidence may arise as financial
institutions begin to experience an increase in non-performing loans and loan defaults and
a deterioration of their capital base.
When President Abdel Fattah al-Sisi came to power
in a 2013 military coup, he promised to fix Egypt’s
mounting economic problems. Three years later,
those problems had only intensified: the country
was struggling with low economic growth; 13 per
cent unemployment; a 12 per cent inflation rate; a
large trade deficit, amounting to 7 per cent of GDP; a
persistent budget deficit of around 12 per cent of GDP;
and public debt that stood at 92 per cent of GDP. In
addition, the tourism trade, a major source of foreign
currency, had collapsed in the wake of concerns about
terrorism, which included an Islamic State-linked
insurgency in the Sinai Peninsula that claimed the
bombing of a Russian passenger jet in 2016; foreign
direct investment, another source of foreign currency,
had also slumped in the wake of Egypt’s economic and
political problems.
One major issue was a lack of foreign currency in the
country, which made it difficult to pay for imports and
resulted in shortages of key commodities. For example,
188
PART 2
© Baloncici/Shutterstock
COUNTRY FOCUS
EGYPT AND THE IMF
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd
188
08/07/19 04:03 PM
Egypt imports one-third of its sugar. By mid-2016, this
commodity was in short supply due to the inability of
Egyptian traders to get the foreign currency required
to pay for imported sugar. Historically, in times of
trouble, the oil-rich Arab states of the Persian Gulf
had loaned foreign currency to Egypt at low-interest
rates, but a collapse in oil prices had left those states
financially strained and loans were not forthcoming. In
an indication of the depth of Egypt’s problems, while
the official exchange rate of the Egyptian pound was
pegged at 9 pounds to the US dollar, the black market
rate had soared to 18 pounds to the US dollar.
In mid-2016, with its foreign exchange reserves being
rapidly depleted, the Egyptian government applied to the
IMF for a loan. The IMF agreed to loan Egypt up to $12
billion, but only if the government undertook a number
of economic reforms. These included liberalising the
exchange rate, letting the Egyptian pound float against
other currencies. The thinking was that the pound would
immediately depreciate against major currencies such
as the US dollar and the euro, making Egyptian exports
cheaper and its imports more expensive. This should help
the country to improve its trade deficit and earn more
foreign currency. At the same time, the IMF required the
Egyptian government to implement an austerity program
that included an immediate end to energy subsidies,
which had kept energy prices artificially low; reforms to
public enterprises to make them more efficient; tighter
monetary policy to rein in inflation; and the imposition of
a value-added tax to raise government revenue.
In November 2016, Egypt let the pound float freely. It
immediately lost 50 per cent of its value against the US
dollar, trading at around 13 pounds to the dollar. The
depreciation continued into the new year, falling to 19
pounds to the dollar by mid-January 2017, and bringing
the official exchange rate and the black market rate
into equality. Egypt also moved rapidly to impose the
value-added tax. In return, the IMF released the first
$2.75 billion of its loan to Egypt. Further tranches of
the loan will be released as Egypt makes progress on
the economic reforms advocated by the IMF.
Only time will tell whether these policies will work. In
addition to a fall in the value of the pound, the immediate
impact included a surge in the annual inflation rate to
around 20 per cent. The IMF envisages the inflation
rate falling to 7 per cent within three years, while
there should be sharp improvements in both the trade
deficit and the budget deficit. However, the planned
austerity measures carry significant political risks for
the Egyptian government. If protests materialise over
short-term hardships, the government might cave in to
political pressure and pull back from the IMF-mandated
reforms. If that happens, the IMF might withhold further
installments under the loan program, and the Egyptian
economy could continue to deteriorate.
SOURCES: H. Mahfouz and P. Schemm, ‘Struggling Egypt devalues currency by almost 50% ahead of IMF loan’, The Washington Post, 3 November 2016;
L. Noueihed and A. Aboulenein, “Egypt on track to receive IMF loan’s second tranche’, Reuters, 18 January 2017; ‘State of denial’, The Economist, 6
August 2016; CIA World Fact Book, Egypt, accessed via www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook February 2017.
Since 2007, banking systems all around the world have been significantly impacted
by the GFC. Referred to by the IMF as the ‘Great Recession’, it has witnessed the largest
number of systemic banking crises ever recorded since the Great Depression, which have
mainly affected advanced economies (including the United Kingdom and the United
States), in contrast to earlier crises that were mainly associated with developing countries.32
Iceland’s and Ireland’s troubled banking systems are calculated to be responsible for among
the top 10 costliest banking crises since the 1970s, with Ireland’s being the costliest
banking crisis since the Great Depression. (Read about Iceland’s crisis in detail in Country
Focus: ‘IMF and Iceland’s economic recovery’.) Banking crises appear to run in cycles and
often coincide with credit cycles, with a cluster of crises preceding the GFC in the 1990s
(the Asian crisis of 1998, Tequila crisis of 1995 and transition economies in 1991). These
were preceded by the Latin American debt crisis in the early 1980s. The IMF has gone
to great efforts to support its member countries throughout the GFC, committing over
US$600 billion in loans and policy assistance to those most affected.33 A foreign debt
crisis is a situation in which a country cannot service its foreign debt obligations of loan
and interest payments, whether private-sector or government debt. Common causes of
CHAPTER 4
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd 189
FOREIGN DEBT CRISIS
When foreign debt, whether privatesector or government debt, has
become so large that the country
cannot service its debt obligations of
loan and interest payments
FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
189
08/07/19 04:03 PM
these crises include high inflation rates, a worsening balance of payments deficit, fiscal
profligacy and excessive borrowing, and asset-price inflation (such as sharp increases in
shares and property).34 In 2010, the IMF in combination with the European Union put
together a rescue package of €110 billion to help reduce Greece’s debt. A second package
of €130 billion was provided to Greece during 2012 when debt was forecast to grow to
190 per cent of GDP. Over the period 1970–2017, an IMF study identified 151 banking
crises, 236 currency crises and 74 sovereign crises.35 Apart from the banking crises in the
developing countries of Guinea-Bissau, Moldova and Ukraine in 2014, the world at large
has experienced a relatively calm period in relation to major debt crisis since the GFC.
While it may have been thought with the collapse of the Bretton Woods system that the
role of the IMF within the international monetary system would diminish, its role and
activities have been reshaped and to some degree strengthened,36 while its influence on
countries’ policies has increased considerably. There are those, however, who are critical of
the expanding role of the IMF, particularly given its present structure.37 We will examine
these criticisms shortly.
In performing its new role, the IMF now gives greater emphasis to three core activities:
surveillance, technical assistance and, as we have already noted, lending.
COUNTRY FOCUS
IMF AND ICELAND’S ECONOMIC
RECOVERY
succession, the local stock market plunged 90 per cent
and unemployment increased nine-fold. The krona,
Iceland’s currency, plunged on foreign exchange
markets, pushing up the price of imports, and inflation
soared to 18 per cent. Iceland appeared to be in free
fall. The economy shrank by almost 7 per cent in 2009
and another 4 per cent in 2010.
To stem the decline, the government secured $10
billion in loans from the IMF and other countries.
The Icelandic government lacked the funds to bail out
the banks, so it decided to let the big three fail. In quick
190
PART 2
© McGraw-Hill
When the GFC hit in 2008, tiny Iceland suffered more
than most. The country’s three biggest banks had been
expanding at a breakneck pace since 2000, when
the government privatised the banking sector. With
a population of 320 000, Iceland was too small for
the banking sector’s ambitions, so the banks started
to expand into other Scandinavian countries and the
United Kingdom. They entered local mortgage markets,
purchased foreign financial institutions and opened
foreign branches—attracting depositors by offering
high-interest rates. This expansion was financed by
debt, much of it structured as short-term loans that had
to be regularly refinanced. By early 2008, the three
banks held debts that amounted to almost six times
the value of the entire economy of Iceland! So long as
they could periodically refinance this debt, it was not
a problem. However, in 2008 global financial markets
imploded following the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers
and the collapse of the US housing market. In the
aftermath, financial markets froze. The Icelandic banks
found that they could not refinance their debt, and they
faced bankruptcy.
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd
190
08/07/19 04:03 PM
The government also stepped in to help local
depositors, seizing the domestic assets of the
Icelandic banks and using the IMF and other loans to
backstop deposit guarantees. Far from implementing
austerity measures to solve the crisis, the Icelandic
government looked for ways to shore up consumer
spending; for example, it provided means-tested
subsidies to reduce the mortgage interest expenses
of borrowers. The idea was to stop domestic
consumer spending from imploding and further
depressing the economy.
With the financial system stabilised, thanks to the
IMF and other foreign loans, what happened next
is an object lesson in the value of having a floating
currency. The fall in the value of the krona helped
boost Iceland’s exports, such as fish and aluminium,
while depressing demand for costly imports, such
as cars. By 2009, the krona was worth half as much
against the US dollar and the euro as it was in 2007
before the crisis. Iceland’s exports surged and
imports slumped. While the high cost of imports did
stoke inflation, booming exports started to pump
money back into the Icelandic economy. In 2011,
the economy grew at a rate of 3.1 per cent. This was
followed by 2.7 per cent growth in 2012 and 4 per
cent growth in 2013, while unemployment fell from a
high of nearly 10 per cent to 4.4 per cent at the end
of 2013.
SOURCES: C. Forelle, ‘In European crisis, Iceland emerges as an island of recovery’, The Wall Street Journal, 19 May 2012, pp. A1, A10; ‘Coming in from
the cold’, The Economist, 16 December 2010; C. Duxbury, ‘Europe gets cold shoulder in Iceland’, The Wall Street Journal, 26 April 2012; ‘Iceland’, The
World Factbook 2013, Washington, DC: Central Intelligence Agency, 2013.
Surveillance
Surveillance involves monitoring and consulting members with regard to the national and
international consequences of their domestic macroeconomic and financial policies. With
the collapse of Bretton Woods, surveillance and policy advice by the IMF now play key
roles in safeguarding the confidence levels and the stability of the international monetary
system. In a globally integrated financial system, there is a recognition that domestic
macroeconomic stabilisation performance and policy can have significant spillover effects
on other countries and the international financial system. Policy cooperation along
with sound domestic financial systems and the macroeconomic stability of domestic
economies of members are considered prerequisites to build confidence and stability in
the international financial system and trading system. Every country that joins the IMF is
required to subject its economic and financial policies to the scrutiny of the IMF and the
international community. To these ends, IMF surveillance includes assessing a country’s
vulnerability to crisis, identifying the strengths, risks and vulnerabilities of its financial
systems, and assisting with formulating appropriate policy responses. Each year the IMF
writes reports on countries’ economic situation and provides policy recommendations.
The IMF also monitors economic and financial developments at the regional and global
levels.38 Multilateral consultations and surveillance are new tools of the IMF (dating
from 2007) that are designed to foster debate and policy actions on issues of systemic
or regional importance. By monitoring, for example, international capital developments,
it looks for early warning signs of vulnerabilities and potential instability in the
international financial system. Inadequate surveillance reduces the effectiveness of the
IMF’s early warning systems, thus limiting its capacity to prevent crises. A notable
failure was the lack of sufficient warning of the 2007–09 GFC because of inadequate
surveillance of the financial institutions and markets of the systemically important
advanced countries.39 The IMF, however, has not been alone in missing the early warning
signs of crises.
CHAPTER 4
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd 191
SURVEILLANCE
The IMF monitors and consults
members with regard to the national
and international consequences of
their domestic macroeconomic and
financial policies
FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
191
08/07/19 04:03 PM
Technical assistance
Technical assistance aims to build the human and institutional capacities of countries to
design and implement sound economic policies. It provides research, advice and training
in areas including the regulation and supervision of financial systems, legal frameworks,
taxation and fiscal, monetary and exchange rate policies.
Lending
CONDITIONALITY
A requirement that countries which
borrow from the IMF commit to
specified economic and financial
policies
As of 31 October 2018, the IMF was committing loans to 36 member countries that were
struggling with economic and currency problems.40 All IMF loans come with conditions
attached. Conditionality is a requirement that countries that borrow from the IMF commit
to specified economic and financial policies. Conditionality enables the IMF to monitor
whether the loan is being used effectively and to safeguard IMF resources. The tailored
program of policies to which a country must commit seeks to take into account the causes
of the crises specific to the country. There are multiple possible causes of financial crises,
domestic and external. Domestic causes include natural disasters, political instability,
excessive money supply, unsustainable government budget deficits and overvalued
exchange rates. External causes include a collapse of export prices, a sudden increase in
import prices, sudden foreign capital outflows, and reduced access to international credit
with rising interest rate costs.41 In general, the IMF insists on a combination of tight
macroeconomic policies, including cuts in public spending, higher interest rates, and
tight monetary policy. It also often pushes for structural and institutional change, such
as the deregulation of sectors formerly protected from domestic and foreign competition,
privatisation of state-owned assets, and better financial reporting from the banking sector.
The IMF’s monitoring role is not without its critics. The criticisms include matters of
conditionality and ‘mission creep’, inappropriate policies, moral hazard and governance.
Conditionality and mission creep
MISSION CREEP
A situation where an organisation
expands its activities beyond its
original mandate
192
PART 2
The IMF loan conditions have been criticised for being too heavy handed and too political.
For example, in the 1997–98 Asian crisis, the IMF loan conditions required South Korea
to open up its banking sector to US and other foreign banks. In Indonesia, it demanded
the breaking up of a clove monopoly, petrol pricing reform and the removal of subsidies
on basic foodstuffs and energy. These requirements gave rise to widespread street protests
and unleashed a chain of events that led eventually to the collapse of the government.
A similar story was played out nearly 15 years later in Europe when the conditions of
austerity and structural change imposed by IMF–EU financial rescue packages generated
widespread political turmoil and upheaval in Greece and Spain. Critics argue that the
IMF, via conditionality, oversteps the mark by attempting virtually to micro-manage
economies.42 This criticism embodies the notion of mission creep. The term mission
creep describes the situation where an organisation expands its activities beyond its
original mandate. With respect to conditionality, the conditions imposed by the IMF have
expanded over time. They have enlarged from those more directly related to balance of
payments and macroeconomic stability (e.g. issues of overvalued exchange rate, growing
government budget expenditures, and inflationary money supply expansions) to include,
in more recent times, requirements for institutional and structural change (e.g. the
privatisation of public enterprises, opening markets to foreign financial firms, breaking
up local monopolies, anti-poverty measures, and the prevention of money-laundering and
terrorist financing).43 To some critics, this expansion transgresses the national sovereignty
and policy autonomy of the loan recipient countries.44
The additional conditions and austerity measures imposed by the IMF became
incentives for countries to shun assistance from the IMF. The reaction of the Asian nations
that were forced to borrow from the IMF during the financial crises of the late 1990s
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd
192
08/07/19 04:03 PM
was to look for ways to reduce their reliance on IMF loans in the future. They did this by
running up large current account surpluses and building up foreign exchange reserves.
In their minds, large reserves would provide insurance against any speculative attack on
their currencies and enable them to withstand any sudden ‘hot money’ capital outflows. In
2000, smarting at the perceived highhandedness of the IMF bailout conditions, all ASEAN
member countries plus China, Japan and Korea began to pool—like an IMF pool, but on a
regional basis—a small fraction of their combined holdings of reserves as pledges (the money
is still held by the individual central banks) under what became known as the Chiang
Mai Initiative (CMI).45 In 2010, in the face of the GFC, a new agreement was reached in
Beijing between South Korea, China, Japan and the 10 members of ASEAN to extend (and
supersede) the Chiang Mai Initiative into the new and improved Chiang Mai Initiative
Multilateralization (CMIM). This agreement aimed to establish a regional financial market
surveillance organisation governed by a single contract, and to build a self-managed foreign
reserve pooling arrangement, which stood at US$240 billion in 2012. However, there are
many critics who argue that the CMIM is too limited and may not be even usable.46
Having learned a lesson about the conditionality of IMF loans during the Asian financial
crisis, the Asian economies began to build surpluses. There are serious shortcomings of
this initiative from the point of view of a stable international monetary system. These
surpluses formed part of the global imbalances, which, as we noted in Chapter 1, became
a fundamental cause of the 2007–09 GFC. Not all countries can run undervalued exchange
rates and have balance-of-payments surpluses. Such action is a beggar-thy-neighbour tactic,
and the danger is that countries that suffer a competitive disadvantage will take unilateral
action that is contrary to the internationally agreed ‘rules of the game’. Another negative
outcome is that developing nations are using their export earnings to accumulate financial
assets, rather than finance the imports of new plant, equipment and technology necessary
to promote economic development.
Further evidence of mission creep is the expanded nature of IMF lending. Critics
argue that the IMF should curtail its lending and require countries to access the private
international capital market. Lending should be limited to providing temporary liquidity
only in extreme cases.47 IMF lending to date has included long-term lending with more of
an economic development focus than a temporary assistance focus. The critics argue that
development loans are more the province of the World Bank and regional development
banks such as the Asian Development Bank and the European Bank of Reconstruction and
Development.
Inappropriate policies
Another criticism of the IMF is that its ‘one-size-fits-all’ approach to macroeconomic policy
is inappropriate to many countries. As we noted above, to different degrees, each financial
crisis may comprise elements of currency, banking and debt crisis. The IMF has tended
to require a traditional mix of fiscal policies (higher taxes and less government spending)
and tighter monetary policy (higher interest rates and less credit availability). These
policies may have been well suited to countries suffering from high inflation, or that had a
temporary liquidity problem, in that they were unable to earn enough foreign currency to
service and repay foreign debts. This was the case in Latin America in the 1980s, but not
the problem in Asia in the 1990s. The problem in Asia was one of insolvency—a privatesector debt crisis with deflationary undertones.48 Critics argued that the traditional mix
of policies actually increased the probability of widespread corporate defaults as a result of
higher interest rates, depressed growth and higher unemployment. The IMF rejected the
criticism, arguing that the central task was to build confidence in the national currencies.
Stabilising price inflation and improving the value of a national currency would reduce
the foreign debt burden and make it easier for companies to service their debt. Seldom is
CHAPTER 4
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd 193
FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
193
08/07/19 04:03 PM
there consensus among economists as to the appropriateness of policies, so criticisms of
IMF prescriptions will persist. In support of the IMF position, in Asia, Latin America and
Central and Eastern Europe, the economies did recover fairly quickly from their respective
crises after IMF intervention.
Moral hazard
MORAL HAZARD
People behave recklessly because
they know they will be saved if
things go wrong
IMF lending for purposes other than the emergency relief of illiquidity is an incentive for
governments and private investors to undertake larger but more risky and unsustainable
borrowings. These, in turn, become a potential source of financial crisis. This is the
problem of moral hazard. Moral hazard arises when people behave recklessly because
they know they will be saved by others (usually the taxpayer) if things go wrong. In the
aftermath of the Asian crisis, critics argued that many Japanese and Western banks were
far too willing to lend large amounts of capital to overleveraged Asian companies during
the boom years of the 1990s. It was argued that the banks should have been forced to
pay the price for their rash lending, even if it meant some banks may have collapsed.49 By
providing support to these countries, the IMF reduced the probability of default and in
effect bailed out the banks whose loans gave rise to the crisis. The bailouts of financial
institutions undertaken by industrialised countries during the 2007–09 GFC and later
in the eurozone with the backing of the IMF have also been criticised because they are
unlikely to constrain reckless risk-taking by ‘too big to fail’ financial institutions. ‘Too big
to fail’ bailouts such as the recapitalisation of financial institutions by governments and
government-subsidised asset guarantees and funding are considered to create significant
moral hazard as they undermine proper incentives and market discipline.50
The counterargument is that widespread debt defaults would result in the failure of
large financial institutions and, unlike the past where impacts were more local or regional,
the impacts are now felt globally. Failures could lead to a meltdown in global financial
markets and serious declines in global equity markets as occurred in 2007–09. This was the
risk the IMF was trying to avoid by stepping in with financial support although policies
may not have been always appropriate.51
Governance
Critics argue that the quotas and voting power of IMF members reflect the world of the
1940s. The industrial states of Europe and the United States are over-represented and
have too much influence in IMF decision making. Fast-growing economies, particularly
in Asia, remain under represented relative to their weight in the world economy. There
are calls for governance reforms that increase the quotas (which determine voting power)
and voice of the new centres of economic growth and wealth (more colloquially described
as ‘chairs and shares’ reform). Without these reforms, the legitimacy and effectiveness
of the IMF to prevent financial crisis will be reduced in the eyes of many countries in
the world economy.52 In 2006, China, South Korea, Mexico and Turkey received quota
increases. In 2008, the IMF governors voted for changes to the quota and voting share
structure for 54 countries to enhance the participation and voice of emerging market and
developing countries. In 2010, the IMF increased all quotas by 100 per cent resulting in
the BRIC countries being among the 10 largest shareholders in the IMF. The next round
of reviews, planned to assess the size and composition of quotas and voting rights, will
take place in 2019.53 Many criticise the slow pace of governance reform particularly the
over-representation of European economies in light of the eurozone crisis. Brazil and China
are among the emerging economies that have contributed significantly to IMF funds,
which have been used by the IMF to assist struggling eurozone countries. There has
subsequently been a push that the countries offering this money should be granted greater
voting rights within the IMF organisation.54
194
PART 2
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd
194
08/07/19 04:03 PM
IMF in the global financial architecture
Seven decades on from its birth, the IMF’s fundamental objective remains one of
maintaining international monetary stability to facilitate the expansion of international
trade and investment. However, the global financial architecture has changed. The rulesbased system of Bretton Woods has been virtually replaced by a ‘non-system’ that allows
national governments to determine their own exchange rate regime and the degree of
control they have over foreign capital flows. This ‘non-system’, however, still provides the
functions of adjustment, liquidity and confidence. Currently, adjustment occurs using
exchange regimes across the full spectrum of flexibility; liquidity is provided by a basically
unregulated international private capital market, with the IMF also providing loans to
cover short-term foreign exchange shortages; and confidence relies on cooperation and the
willingness of national governments to undertake domestic policies and structural reforms
(particularly with respect to strengthening the financial sector) that are ‘acceptable’ in the
sense of forgoing domestic political expediency for the collective international good. It is in
relation to confidence, in particular, that the IMF has a credible and positive role to play.
The IMF does not play alone in this role. Policy debate, surveillance and expertise are
dispersed among numerous bodies, including the G20, the Bank for International Settlements
(BIS) and the Financial Stability Board (FSB). The G20 came into being in 1999, around the
time of the Asian financial crisis. The G20 comprises the seven major industrialised nations—
Britain, Canada, France, Italy, Japan, Germany and the United States—plus Argentina, Australia,
Brazil, China, India, Indonesia, Mexico, Russia, Saudi Arabia, South Africa, South Korea and
Turkey, along with the European Union. Its membership is more representative of the
21st century global economy and financial system than other groups such as the G8.
Established in 1930, the BIS is the world’s oldest international financial organisation.
Based in Basel, Switzerland, the BIS serves as a discussion forum, an advisory body and
a bank to the central banks of nations. In this role, it fosters international monetary and
financial cooperation. Fifty-five central bank institutions currently have rights of voting and
representation at BIS general meetings. The FSB (initially the Financial Stability Forum) was
also convened around the time of the Asian financial crisis, in 1999. Its goal is to promote
international financial stability through information exchange and international cooperation
in financial sector supervision and surveillance. It brings together senior representatives
of national financial authorities (e.g. central banks, supervisory authorities and treasury
departments), international financial institutions, international regulatory and supervisory
groupings, committees of central bank experts and the European Central Bank.
These non-IMF groups, from time to time, have become the focus of policy debate and
policy coordination. They gather key officials together regularly to identify potential threats
to global stability and policy responses. One advantage they have is that their membership
is not as broad and unwieldy as that of the 189-member IMF. They are more flexible and
more likely to agree on responses to systemic risks in the global economy. However, they
have their own shortcomings with respect to legitimacy and capacity. They are, in the
main, forums for discussion and consultative bodies, rather than decision-making bodies.
They rely on domestic governments to implement rule changes and adopt procedures in
their own countries. On the other hand, the IMF already has formal mandates and resources
to back up its deisions to promote international financial stability and restore and monitor
a rules-based system. It has near universal representation that favours multilateralism over
nationalism. These other groups will not supplant the IMF, but in order to retain a central
role in the international financial architecture in the 21st century, the IMF needs to adapt.
These adaptations have commenced. It has begun to strengthen its surveillance function,
facilitate international cooperation among national financial regulators, and rebalance quotas
and representation in its decision-making forums.55
CHAPTER 4
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd 195
TEST PREP
Preparing for a test?
Use LearnSmart to
help you remember
what you’ve learned.
FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
195
08/07/19 04:03 PM
FOCUS ON
MANAGERIAL IMPLICATIONS
Throughout this chapter we have
alluded on several occasions to the
potential impact on international
business of changes in foreign exchange rates. It is
critical that international companies understand the
influence of exchange rates on the profitability of trade
and investment contracts. Changes in exchange rates
bring about changes in the prices of traded goods
and services. Setting the price to remain competitive
and maintain market share in foreign markets is also
complicated by exchange rate changes, as adverse
changes can put at risk apparently profitable deals.
In this section, we look at the impact of exchange
rate changes on international business operations in
more detail, and how companies may manage these
impacts. We begin by looking at the relationship
between exchange rates and the pricing of goods in
foreign markets. We follow with a discussion of the
risks to which business can be exposed as a result of
exchange rate changes and the strategies they may
employ to mitigate these risks.
LO 4.4
EXCHANGE RATES AND PRICE SETTING
With dramatic swings in exchange rates, particularly
in a freely floating exchange rate regime, setting
prices for internationally traded goods is a challenge
for international business management. The extent
to which an international business adjusts prices in
a foreign market as the
EXCHANGE RATE PASS-THROUGH
result of an exchange
The extent to which an international
rate change is called
business adjusts prices in a foreign
market as the result of an exchange exchange rate passrate change
through.
We can illustrate the type of pricing dilemma
confronted by exporters and the pass-through concept
with the numerical examples in Tables 4.3A and 4.3B.
Suppose the ex-factory price of the Australian
produced farm machinery is A$35 000 and the current
exchange rate is A$1.60 = US$1.00. The price in
the US market at this exchange rate is US$21 875,
ignoring all transaction costs and assuming the
manufacturer and all agents through the supply chain
are satisfied that the existing mark-ups at these
prices give acceptable sales and profits. Suppose
196
PART 2
now the Australian dollar appreciates towards parity,
illustrated by moving down the left-hand column of
Tables 4.3A and 4.3B. If the manufacturer passes
through 100 per cent of the impact of the exchange
rate change, as in Table 4.3A, US prices rise. If the
exchange rate went to parity, it would result in a
significant price rise of 60 per cent. If the exchange
rate went to $1.40, the price increase would be
14 per cent. With a price rise in the US, sales would
be expected to fall and market share to decline. The
extent of the fall, and the extent to which the exporter
is willing and able to pass through the exchange
rate change, depends on a number of factors. One
factor is the sensitivity of customers to price changes.
If US customers buy farm machinery for non-price
reasons, such as unique capability, the fall in sales
will not be as great when prices rise. Another factor
is the amount of competition. If other American and
foreign farm machinery manufacturers offer similar
machines, a price rise is likely to see a marked fall
in market share. A third factor is the impact of the
exchange rate change on the costs of production. If
a large proportion of inputs to the production of the
farm machines in Australia are imported, the costs
of imported inputs will decrease as a result of the
appreciation of the Australian dollar. As a result, the
ex-factory price can be lowered and the foreign price
rise can be reduced.
If all the price-sensitivity factors align adversely against
the exporter, the exporter may be forced to accept
lower mark-ups. This is illustrated in Table 4.3B. If
the US market for this type of farm machinery is very
price-sensitive, as illustrated here, the exporter may
be forced to price to what the market determines—in
this case, US$21 875. In other words, the exporter has
no market power to adjust prices upwards and must
take the US dollar price as a given. In this situation,
when the Australian dollar appreciates, the impact
of the exchange rate change is on mark-ups and the
ex-factory price. The pass-through is 0 per cent, as
the motor-vehicle exports are priced to the market
conditions. If the impact of exchange rate appreciation
is such that it causes substantial cuts to ex-factory
prices, a scenario arises that the export venture is no
longer a sound business proposition. Of course, if the
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd
196
08/07/19 04:03 PM
TABLE 4.3A
100 per cent pass-through
EXCHANGE RATE
EX-FACTORY
PRICE IN A$
FOREIGN MARKET
PRICE IN US$
A$1.60 = US$1.00
A$1.40 = US$1.00
A$1.00 = US$1.00
(parity)
A$35 000
A$35 000
A$35 000
US$21 875
US$25 000
US$35 000
TABLE 4.3B
Pricing-to-market (0 per cent pass-through)
EXCHANGE RATE
EX-FACTORY
PRICE IN A$
FOREIGN MARKET
PRICE IN US$
A$1.60 = US$1.00
A$35 000
US$21 875
A$1.40 = US$1.00
A$1.00 = US$1.00
(parity)
A$30 625
A$21 875
US$21 875
US$21 875
exchange rate depreciates, we have a more favourable
mirror image of this scenario from the exporter’s point
of view.
FOREIGN EXCHANGE RISK
Sellers (and buyers) prefer quotes
and invoices in their own currency,
as it means that the other party
bears any foreign exchange rate risk. The choice
of the invoice currency will be part of the price and
contract negotiations between the buyer and seller.
The decision will depend on which party has the
negotiating power. A seller that is competing against
other suppliers for a customer’s signature and wishes
to keep prices stable in the foreign market may choose
to invoice in the buyer’s currency as an inducement.
Invoicing in the buyer’s currency may swing the
deal, but the seller is now exposed to exchange rate
risk. We next discuss what these risks are to sellers
(and buyers), and how to hedge foreign currency
receivables (and payments) to insure against exchange
rate-related losses. These risks are usually divided
into three main categories: transaction exposure,
translation exposure, and economic exposure.
LO 4.5
Transaction exposure is
the extent to which the
income from individual
transactions is affected
by fluctuations in foreign
exchange values. Such exposure includes obligations
for the purchase or sale of goods and services at
agreed prices, paying dividends and the borrowing
or lending of funds in foreign currencies. This is the
TRANSACTION EXPOSURE
The extent to which the income from
individual transactions is affected
by fluctuations in foreign exchange
values
CHAPTER 4
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd 197
money lost or gained due to an adverse or favourable
movement in exchange rates between the time when a
deal was signed and when the payment is due.
Translation exposure is
TRANSLATION EXPOSURE
The extent to which the reported
the impact of currency
consolidated results and balance
exchange rate changes
sheets of a corporation are affected
on the reported financial by fluctuations in foreign exchange
statements of a company. values
Translation exposure
is concerned with the present measurement of
past events. It is sometimes described as ‘balance
sheet’ exposure. Translation is a change in monetary
expression, rather than involving a physical conversion
of one currency for another. It does not involve an
actual cash flow. Changes in exchange rates impact
the earnings, assets and liabilities of an international
firm when they are translated and reported in the local
currency. The resulting accounting gains or losses are
said to be unrealised—that is, they are ‘paper’ gains
and losses, but they are still important.
Consider an Australian company with a subsidiary
in Thailand. If the value of the Thai baht depreciates
significantly against the Australian dollar, this would
substantially reduce the dollar value of the Thai
subsidiary’s equity. In turn, this would reduce the total
dollar value of the company’s equity reported in its
consolidated balance sheet. The decrease in value
of equity would raise the apparent leverage of the
company (its debt ratio), which could increase the
company’s cost of borrowing and potentially limit its
access to the capital market. Similarly, if the value of
the baht depreciates rapidly against that of the dollar
over a year, this will reduce the dollar value of the baht
profit made by the Thai subsidiary, resulting in negative
translation exposure.
Economic exposure
ECONOMIC EXPOSURE
The extent to which a company’s
is the extent to which
future international earning power
a company’s future
is affected by changes in exchange
international earning
rates
power is affected
by changes in exchange rates. There is not only a
conversion effect, as with transaction exposure, but
also a price-competitive effect. Hence, economic
exposure is concerned more with the long-run effect
of changes in exchange rates on prices, sales and
costs, and future operating cash flows. This is distinct
from transaction exposure, which is concerned with
the effect of exchange rate changes on individual
transactions, most of which involve commitments
already in place and are short-term affairs that will be
FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
197
08/07/19 04:03 PM
executed within a few weeks or months. Transaction
exposure may be considered a subset of economic
exposure.
In the longer term, a wide and sustained swing in the
value of a currency affects the international pricecompetitiveness of exporters and those domestic
companies competing against imports. A sustained
loss of price-competitiveness may require a company
to take long-term solutions such as relocating its
production facilities to another country, particularly to a
country that comprises a very large share of its export
market.
REDUCING RISK EXPOSURES
Reducing transaction and translation exposures A
number of strategies can help companies to minimise
their transaction and translation exposures. These
strategies primarily protect short-term cash flows from
adverse changes in exchange rates. Earlier in this
chapter, we discussed two of these strategies: entering
into forward exchange rate contracts, and buying
swaps. In addition to using these financial instruments,
firms’ transaction and translation exposures may be
reduced by ‘natural’
hedges. A natural
NATURAL HEDGE
Hedging opportunities that arise
hedge arises out of the
from the way in which a business
structure of business
operates
operations that create
offsets between foreign
currency receipts and payments. Restructuring
business operations to create these offsets may reduce
or eliminate transaction and translation exposures.
The net exposures remaining after natural hedges
may then be addressed by using financial instruments
as forward and swap contracts. One such natural
hedge is through leading and lagging payables and
receivables—that is, paying suppliers and collecting
payment from customers early or late depending on
expected exchange rate movements. A lead strategy
involves attempting to
LEAD STRATEGY
collect foreign currency
An attempt to collect foreign
currency receivables early when
receivables (payments
a foreign currency is expected
from customers) early
to depreciate and to pay foreign
when a foreign currency
currency payables before they are
is expected to depreciate,
due when a currency is expected to
and paying foreign
appreciate
currency payables
(payments to suppliers) before they are due when a
currency is expected to appreciate. A lag strategy
involves delaying collection of foreign currency
198
PART 2
LAG STRATEGY
receivables if that
An attempt to delay collection of
currency is expected to
foreign currency receivables if that
appreciate and delaying
currency is expected to appreciate
payables if the currency
and to delay payables if that
is expected to depreciate. currency is expected to depreciate
Leading and lagging
involves accelerating payments from weak currency
to strong currency countries and delaying inflows
from strong currency to weak currency countries. Lead
and lag strategies can be difficult to implement, however.
The company must be in a position to exercise some
control over payment terms. Small companies do not
usually have this kind of bargaining power, particularly
when they are dealing with important customers who are
in a position to dictate payment terms.
Currency diversification and matching are natural
hedges. Large multinational companies such as BHP
operating in many different countries have their
receipts, payments, assets and liabilities denominated
in many different currencies. Diversification acts
to reduce overall foreign exchange exposures. An
appreciation of one currency means the depreciation
of another, so, in the mix of currencies, gains may
offset losses. A natural hedge occurs when there is a
match of the currency denomination of receipts and
payments.56 For example, if an Australian manufacturer
exports a finished product to the United States and
imports major component parts from the United
States, foreign exchange exposure from these trades
is limited. The income stream from exports ‘naturally’
hedges the risk associated with the US dollar import
payment.
Establishing foreign currency bank accounts to make
payments and receive income in the foreign currency
of the country with which a company trades is another
mechanism for limiting exposure. This is not an
option for a company that requires foreign earnings
to maintain a sufficient cash flow for the business at
home. Natural hedging can also arise through the
conditions negotiated in contracts. The inclusion of
automatic price escalation clauses relating to exchange
rate changes and the determination of the invoicing
currency can reduce the risk for one of the parties
to the transaction. Whether or not a company can
use contract conditions as a hedge depends on their
bargaining power in the contract negotiations. For
many smaller international businesses, natural hedging
may not be viable because of their limited regional
diversity of operations, cash flow demands and
negotiating power.
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd
198
08/07/19 04:03 PM
Reducing economic exposure Reducing economic
exposure requires strategic choices that go beyond the
realm of financial management. It requires restructuring
operations and involves decisions on the location of
production, sourcing of supplies and the diversification
of markets. The key to reducing economic exposure is
to distribute the firm’s productive assets and sources
of supplies to various locations so that the company’s
long-term financial wellbeing is not severely affected by
adverse changes in particular exchange rates. In theory,
by locating production in different regions that use
different currencies, the firm can adjust capacity utilisation
so that it produces or sources more of its product in the
region where the currency values are most favourable.
OTHER STEPS FOR MANAGING
FOREIGN EXCHANGE RISK
The international company needs to develop a
mechanism for ensuring it maintains an appropriate
mix of strategies for minimising its foreign exchange
exposure. Although there is no universal agreement
as to the components of this mechanism, a number
of common themes stand out. First, central control of
exposure is needed to protect resources efficiently
and ensure that each sub-unit adopts the correct mix
of strategies. Many companies have set up in-house
foreign exchange centres. Although such centres may
not be able to execute all foreign exchange deals—
particularly in large, complex multinationals where
myriad transactions may be pursued simultaneously—
they should at least set guidelines for the company’s
subsidiaries to follow.
exposure, which may have more profound long-term
implications. Companies need to develop strategies
for dealing with economic exposure such as moving
production to multiple country locations to maximise
flexibility, price competitiveness and the ability to
respond rapidly to major currency fluctations.
Third, the need to forecast future exchange rate
movements cannot be overstated, though this is a
tricky business. There is no model that comes close
to perfectly predicting future movements in foreign
exchange rates. The best that can be said is that in the
short run, forward exchange rates provide the best
predictors of exchange rate movements, and in the
long run, fundamental economic factors—particularly
relative inflation rates—should be watched because
they influence exchange rate movements.
Fourth, companies need to establish good reporting
systems so the central finance function (or the inhouse foreign exchange centre) can regularly monitor
the company’s exposure positions. Such reporting
systems should enable the company to identify any
exposed accounts, the exposed position by currency
of each account, and the time periods covered. Foreign
exchange software solutions play an important role in
providing management with the ability to easily track
and monitor their currency exposure across all facets
of the organisation. Developments in technology have
enabled companies to streamline their data-collection
processes, produce real-time foreign exchange
exposure reports, improve forecasting in foreign
exchange movements, and hence manage exposure
risks more effectively and efficiently.
Second, companies should distinguish between, on the
one hand, transaction and translation exposure and, on
the other, economic exposure. Many companies seem
to focus on reducing their transaction and translation
exposure and pay scant attention to economic
CHAPTER 4
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd 199
FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
199
08/07/19 04:03 PM
KEY TERMS
184
166
165
176
188
167
192
184
169
164
188
167
197
164
196
183
adjustment
Algorithmic Trading (AT)
arbitrage
bandwagon effect
banking crisis
carry trade
conditionality
confidence
cross rate
cryptocurrencies
currency crisis
currency speculation
economic exposure
exchange rate
exchange rate pass-through
external balance
174
178
177
189
163
180
166
170
170
168
186
183
175
184
177
198
Fisher Effect
fixed exchange rate system
floating exchange rate
foreign debt crisis
foreign exchange market
foreign exchange reserves
foreign exchange risk
foreign exchange (FX) swap
forward exchange rate
hedging
impossible trinity argument
internal balance
International Fisher Effect
international liquidity
international monetary system
lag strategy
172
198
180
192
194
198
170
178
173
168
191
197
197
166
law of one price
lead strategy
managed or ‘dirty’ float system
mission creep
moral hazard
natural hedge
outright forward
pegged exchange rate
purchasing power parity (PPP)
spot exchange rate
surveillance
transaction exposure
translation exposure
vehicle currency
SUMMARY
This chapter explained how foreign exchange markets work, the forces that determine exchange rates, and the attempts
to construct a stable international monetary system. It examined the implications for international business of changes in
exchange rates and international monetary instability, and the strategies that management may employ to address such
factors. The chapter made the following points:
1. Two key functions of the foreign exchange market are
to convert the currency of one country into the currency
of another, and to provide insurance against foreign
exchange risk. Foreign exchange risk can be reduced by
using financial instruments such as forward exchange and
foreign exchange swaps.
2. The laws of one price and purchasing power parity (PPP)
theory predict that the exchange rate will change if
relative prices change. These predictions tend to be more
accurate in the long term than the short term.
3. Nominal interest rates reflect expectations about inflation.
The International Fisher Effect predicts that, for any
two countries, the spot exchange rate should change
in an equal amount but in the opposite direction to the
difference in nominal interest rates.
4. Monetary authorities intervene to varying degrees in the
foreign exchange market to achieve internal and external
balance goals. The target of the intervention is usually the
level or volatility of the exchange rate. Intervention will result
in the accumulation or depletion of the foreign exchange
reserves that are available to the monetary authority.
5. Current exchange rate regimes range over a continuum
of flexibility (or fixity) between the extremes of fixed and
floating exchange rates. The world’s four major trading
currencies—the US dollar, the EU euro, the Japanese
yen and the British pound—are all free to float against
each other. Australia and New Zealand also allow their
200
PART 2
currencies to float. China pegs its exchange rate daily but
allows it to fluctuate within a band around the peg.
6. The challenge for domestic governments and the
international monetary system is to reconcile the goals
of internal balance and external balance of national
economies. To reconcile the potential conflict between
these goals and maintain international monetary stability,
an international monetary system must provide all nations
with a mechanism for the adjustment of external imbalances
without severely damaging the internal balance, a source of
international liquidity to assist adjustment, and a means of
building their confidence in the system.
7. In order to attain international monetary stability, the
Bretton Woods system, overseen by the IMF, established
essentially a fixed exchange rate system with the
value of each currency pegged to the value of the US
dollar. Discrete exchange rate variations were allowed
only in times of external imbalances of ‘fundamental
disequilibrium’. The IMF provided short-term loans to
correct temporary imbalances.
8. The Bretton Woods system collapsed in 1973 primarily
due to speculative attacks on currencies fostered by
the asymmetrical adjustment mechanism and to a
loss of confidence in the US dollar, the main source of
international liquidity. Under its rules, the Bretton Woods
system was unsuccessful in its attempt to reconcile
internal and external balance goals.
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd
200
08/07/19 04:03 PM
9. Although the Bretton Woods system has collapsed
and the role of the IMF as an international manager of
exchange rates has diminished, a series of regional and
global financial crises has given the IMF the opportunity
to reshape and strengthen its role. This new role, which is
not without its critics, is performed through the functions
of surveillance, lending and technical assistance.
10. Domestic political realities often mean that domestic
policy goals will get preference over the goal of
international monetary stability. To minimise beggarthy-neighbour policies, international cooperation is
essential for international monetary stability. The IMF
can become a credible forum for facilitating international
cooperation by strengthening and broadening the scope
of its surveillance activities and rebalancing the quotas
and voice in its decision making to reflect the changing
structure of the global economy.
CHAPTER 4
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd 201
11. A changing exchange rate may force an international
business to adjust prices. The business needs to decide
how much of the exchange rate change to pass through
to the foreign market. There is a need to balance the
impact on profits with the retention of market share.
12. Fluctuating exchange rates expose an international
business to three types of foreign exchange risk:
transaction exposure, translation exposure and economic
exposure. Ways of managing transaction and translation
exposures include buying forward, using foreign
exchange, and natural hedges, such as leading and
lagging payables and receivables. Reducing a company’s
economic exposure requires longer-term strategic
choices about the sources of supplies and the location of
production plants.
FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
201
08/07/19 04:03 PM
INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS
GRADUATE ATTRIBUTES (IBGAs):
LEARNING AND ASSESSMENT TASKS
IBGA1: DISCIPLINE KNOWLEDGE AND SKILLS
1. Explain why many countries choose to operate a managed
float system.
2. Compare and contrast the circumstances under which it
is better to set prices for international trade in either the
home-country or the host-country currency.
IBGA2: CRITICAL ANALYSIS
3. CASE ANALYSIS Read the following Closing Case and
answer the questions that follow.
IBGA3: PROBLEM SOLVING
4. Your firm manufactures light bulbs. In mid-June, you
receive an order for 10 000 light bulbs from Japan.
Payment of ¥400 000 is due in mid-December. You
expect the yen to rise from its present rate of A$1 = ¥100
to A$1 = ¥70 by December. You can borrow yen at 6 per
cent a year. Explain what you should do.
5. Two countries, South Africa and Australia, each produce a
similar basket of goods and services. Suppose the price of
this basket in Australia was A$2000 and the price (in rand)
in South Africa is R12 000. Calculate the following.
a. According to PPP theory, what should be the dollar/
rand spot exchange rate?
b. Suppose over the next 12 months the price of the
basket is expected to rise to A$2200 in Australia and
to R15 000 in South Africa. What should be the oneyear forward dollar/rand exchange rate?
c. Given your answers to a and b, and given that the
current interest rate in Australia is 5 per cent per
annum, what would you expect the current interest rate
to be in South Africa?
IBGA5: COMMUNICATION
6. Search the website of the Reserve Bank of Australia (RBA)
for historical data on exchange rates. Construct a graph
that compares changes in the AUD/USD exchange rate
to the Trade Weighted Index (TWI) over the past three
years. The TWI is essentially an exchange rate against
a trade-weighted basket of currencies, rather than a
single currency, and includes the currencies of Australia’s
principal trading partners. These weights reflect the
202
PART 2
composition of Australia’s two-way merchandise trade
and are provided on the RBA website. Accompanying
the graph, write a brief 250-word analysis about any
observable differences in the pattern of the two exchange
rate measures and probable causes of these differences.
7. Prior to 2009, Iceland was one of the richest countries
in the world on a per capita basis. However, the GFC of
the late 2000s wreaked economic and political havoc
on the country. In 2008, the krona collapsed, as did the
country’s three largest banks, which were subsequently
nationalised. The economy declined by 10 per cent.
Political protest saw the long-serving, business-friendly
national government defeated in the elections held in
early 2009, and the country was forced to secure help
from the IMF. The IMF designed a reform plan as part of a
US$6 billion loan package, funded jointly by the IMF and
Iceland’s Nordic neighbours. The IMF claims that it no
longer pushes countries to make fundamental changes—
so-called structural adjustments—to their economies.
Over the last decade, Turkey has also been a recipient of
IMF loans, conditional on adopting a package of reforms.
Turkey is a different economy to Iceland. Prepare a
presentation to your class that outlines and compares the
key elements of the IMF packages to Iceland and Turkey.
Explain the reasons for differences in the packages.
Assess whether or not structural adjustment was part of
the packages. Useful websites include the IMF (www.imf.
org/external/country/index.htm) and the financial press
(e.g. The Economist at www.economist.com/).
IBGA7: GLOBAL PERSPECTIVE
8. Explain the concept of contagion in the context of financial
crises; for example, the 1997 Asian financial crisis or the
2007–09 GFC.
9. The IMF notes: ‘There is no domestic solution to global
problems’. In light of the global cooperation forged during
the 2007–09 GFC, the G20 initiated a ‘mutual assessment
process’. This process essentially involves assessing the
multilateral compatibility of national economic policies
and the aggregate impact of such policies on achieving
global economic outcomes. Search the IMF website (www.
imf.org) for more details of this process. Illustrate using
examples from the past—dating back to the pre-Bretton
Woods days to more recent times, the actions of national
governments that proved to be unable to solve global
problems.
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd
202
08/07/19 04:03 PM
CLOSING CASE
THE FLUCTUATING VALUE OF
THE YUAN GIVES CHINESE
BUSINESS A LESSON IN FOREIGN
EXCHANGE RISK
Between 2015 and early 2018, the Chinese currency,
the yuan, fluctuated significantly in value against the
US dollar, giving Chinese businesses an object lesson
in the importance of managing for foreign exchange
risk.
From August 2015 to December 2016, the value of
the yuan depreciated by 12 per cent from 6.2 yuan
to the US dollar to 6.95 yuan. This depreciation was
triggered by a slowdown in the Chinese economy,
which led to an outflow of capital from China. Even
though the Chinese government spent heavily trying
to prop up the value of the yuan, using $1.5 trillion
of dollar-denominated foreign exchange reserves to
purchase yuan, it could not halt the decline in the
value of the yuan against the dollar.
While the depreciation in the yuan boosted exports,
it also resulted in an unanticipated increase in the
yuan price of key imports, which raised costs for a
number of Chinese companies. In 2015, about 980
listed Chinese companies reported combined foreign
exchange losses of 48.7 billion yuan, almost 13 times
higher than in 2014, according to data compiled by
Bloomberg. Hardest hit were Chinese airlines, many
of which imported aviation fuel that was paid for in
dollars. As the cost of fuel in terms of yuan went up,
their profits slumped. In total, the Chinese airline
sector registered foreign exchange losses of 17.9
billion yuan in 2015, compared with 951.7 million a
year earlier. The big three state-owned airlines—China
Southern Airlines, China Eastern Airlines and Air
China—suffered 15.85 billion yuan in foreign-exchange
currency losses in 2015.
In 2017, conditions reversed. Between January 2017
and April 2018 the yuan appreciated in value by 10
CHAPTER 4
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd 203
per cent against the US dollar, increasing from 6.95
yuan to the dollar to 6.27 yuan. The appreciation
was due to a number of factors, including a return to
stronger growth in China and the election of Donald
Trump in the United States. The latter event seems
to have reduced the confidence that foreign investors
had in the United States and resulted in an outflow of
capital as investors sought to diversify their holdings
of foreign assets and currency. The dollar also fell
after members of the Trump administration made
statements suggesting that they were happy to see it
decline, since that boosted US exports.
The appreciation in the value of the yuan against the
dollar from January 2017 onwards reduced the yuan
costs for Chinese companies that imported goods
priced in dollars, such as aviation fuel. Thus Air China
noted in its 2017 annual report that a 1 per cent gain
in the yuan against the greenback could boost its net
profits by about 280 million yuan, primarily due to
reductions in the cost of aviation fuel.
On the other hand, the appreciation of the yuan
raised the dollar price of Chinese exports. Many
exporters saw their profits squeezed as a result. In
early February 2018, Guangdong Goworld, a supplier
to Apple, said in a stock exchange filing that it
had suffered an estimated foreign exchange loss of
45 million yuan (US$7.2 million) in January 2018 owing
to a stronger yuan. The January figure alone was equal
to 94 per cent of its foreign exchange losses for the
first three quarters of 2017. It also translated into 34
per cent of its net profits in the first nine months of
2017. The Shenzhen-listed company manufactures
and sells printed circuit boards, liquid crystal
displays (LCDs) and ultrasonic electronic measuring
FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
203
08/07/19 04:03 PM
instruments to developed markets including the
United States, Europe, Australia and Japan.
In another example, a spokesperson for Zhejiang
NHU, a producer of vitamins, said that even as the
vitamin export market experienced a boom in 2017,
the company suffered millions of yuan in foreign
exchange losses. The basic problem was that the
company negotiated dollar prices for its vitamins in
2016, but by the end of 2017, each dollar of sales was
yielding less revenue when translated back into yuan
(thanks to the appreciation of the yuan). To deal with
this problem, the company set up a team to discuss
the issue and employed means such as hedging and
forward exchange transactions to try to minimise
foreign exchange risks.
SOURCES: M. Zhang and D. Ren, ‘It has dealt us a heavy blow’, South China Morning Post, 7 April 2018; X. Yu, ‘Chinese companies foreign exchange
losses soared last year’, South China Morning Post, 6 April 2016; ‘Exporters feel the bite of a stronger yuan’, Global Times, 2 April 2018.
CLOSING CASE DISCUSSION QUESTIONS
a. What could Zhejieng NHU have done to mitigate its foreign exchange losses?
b. What were the reasons for the yuan appreciating between January 2017 and April 2018?
c. What triggered the fall of the yuan between 2015 and 2016?
d. What is the easiest way for SMEs to hedge against foreign exchange risks?
204
PART 2
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd
204
08/07/19 04:03 PM
ENDNOTES
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.
12.
13.
14.
15.
16.
17.
18.
19.
20.
21.
22.
23.
Bank for International Settlements, Triennial Central Bank Survey of Foreign
Exchange Turnover in April 2016, accessed via www.bis.org/publ/rpfx16fx.
pdf on 3 December 2018.
Ibid., Table 6.
www.investopedia.com/articles/forex/053115/basics-forex-algorithmictrading.asp
A detailed description of the economics of foreign exchange markets
can be found in P.R. Krugman, M. Obstfeld and M. Melitz, International
Economics: Theory and Policy, New York: Prentice Hall, 2011.
Austrade, ‘Export pricing and quotations’, accessed via www.austrade.gov.
au/Australian/Export/Guide-to-exporting/Export-pricing on 10 December
2018.
G. Hopper, ‘What determines the exchange rate: economic factors or
market sentiment?’, Business Review, September/October 1997.
Ibid.
For a comprehensive review, see M. Taylor, ‘The economics of exchange
rates’, Journal of Economic Literature, 33 (1995), pp. 13–47.
Economists have been investigating this issue for a considerable time. See
H.J. Edison, J.E. Gagnon and W.R. Melick, ‘Understanding the empirical
literature on purchasing power parity’, Journal of International Money
and Finance, 16 (February 1997), pp. 1–18; J.R. Edison, ‘MultiCountry
evidence on the behavior of purchasing power parity under the current
float’, Journal of International Money and Finance, 16 (February 1997), pp.
19–36; K. Rogoff, ‘The purchasing power parity puzzle’, Journal of Economic
Literature, 34 (1996), pp. 64–78; D.R. Rapach and M.E. Wohar, ‘Testing the
monetary model of exchange rate determination: New evidence from a
century of data’, Journal of International Economics, December 2002, pp.
35–95; and M.P. Taylor, ‘Purchasing power parity’, Review of International
Economics, August 2003, pp. 436–56.
M. Obstfeld and K. Rogoff, ‘The six major puzzles in international
economics’, National Bureau of Economic Research working paper no.
7777, July 2000.
Ibid.
See M. Devereux and C. Engel, ‘Monetary policy in the open economy
revisited: price setting and exchange rate flexibility’, National Bureau
of Economic Research working paper no. 7665, April 2000. See also P.
Krugman, ‘Pricing to market when the exchange rate changes’, in S. Arndt
and J. Richardson (eds), Real Financial Economics, Cambridge, MA: MIT
Press, 1987.
For a summary of the evidence, see the survey by M.P. Taylor, ‘The
economics of exchange rates’, op. cit.
R.E. Cumby and M. Obstfeld, ‘A note on exchange rate expectations and
nominal interest differentials: a test of the Fisher Hypothesis’, Journal
of Finance, June 1981, pp. 697–703; and L. Coppock and M. Poitras,
‘Evaluating the Fisher Effect in long-term cross country averages’,
International Review of Economics and Finance, 9 (2000), pp. 181–203.
Taylor, ‘The economics of exchange rates’, op. cit.; see also R.K. Lyons, The
Microstructure Approach to Exchange Rates, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press,
2002.
See H.L. Allen and M.P. Taylor, ‘Charts, noise, and fundamentals in the
foreign exchange market’, Economic Journal, 100 (1990), pp. 49–59; and
T. Ito, ‘Foreign exchange rate expectations: micro survey data’, American
Economic Review, 80 (1990), pp. 434–49.
G. Stevens, The Asian Crisis: A Retrospective, Address to the Anika
Foundation Luncheon, Reserve Bank of Australia, 18 July 2007.
International Monetary Fund, ‘De facto classification of exchange rate
regimes and monetary policy framework’, July 2006, accessed via www.imf.
org/external/np/mfd/er/2006/eng/0706.htm on 10 December 2018.
The Reserve Bank of Australia, ‘The exchange rate and the Reserve Bank’s
role in the foreign exchange market’, January 2018, accessed via www.rba.
gov.au/mkt-operations/ex-rate-rba-role-fx-mkt.html on 10 December 2018.
International Monetary Fund, Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements
and Exchange Restrictions 2017, accessed via www.imf.org/~/media/Files/
Publications/AREAER/areaer-2017-overview.ashx on 5 December 2018.
Ibid.
N. Bjorksten and A. Brook, ‘Exchange rate strategies for small open
developed economies such as New Zealand’, Bulletin, Reserve Bank of New
Zealand, 65(1), p. 23.
International Monetary Fund, Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements
and Exchange Restrictions 2017, op. cit.
CHAPTER 4
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd 205
24. R. Mareno, Motives for Intervention, Bank for International Settlements, BIS
Papers no. 24, May 2005, accessed via www.bis.org/publ/bppdf/bispap24b.
pdf on 10 December 2018.
25. Group of Twenty, Declaration: Summit on Financial Markets and the World
Economy, Washington, 15 November 2008.
26. See R. Gilpin, Global Political Economy: Understanding the International
Economic Order, Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2001, pp. 242–50;
G. Meier, The International Environment of Business: Competition and
Governance in the Global Economy, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1998,
pp. 427–30.
27. For a more detailed account of the demise of Bretton Woods, see R.
Solomon, The International Monetary System 1945–1981, New York:
Harper & Row, 1982.
28. P.R. Krugman and M. Obstfeld, International Economics, op. cit, Ch 15;
B. Eichengreen, Globalizing Capital: A History of the International Monetary
System, Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1996.
29. For an excellent overview of the changing role of the IMF prior to the Global
Financial Crisis of 2007, see M. Parkinson and A. McKissack, ‘The IMF
and the challenge of relevance in the international financial architecture’,
Economic Roundup, Australian Government, The Treasury, Winter 2003.
30. International Monetary Fund, Factsheet: IMF Lending, March 2018,
accessed via www.imf.org/external/np/exr/facts/howlend.htm on 8
December 2018.
31. L. Laeven and F. Valencia, Systemic Banking Crises Database: An Update,
International Monetary Fund (IMF) Working Paper 12/163, 1 June 2012,
accessed via www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2012/wp12163.pdf on
10 December 2018.
32. Ibid.
33. International Monetary Fund, Factsheet: How the IMF Promotes Global
Economic Stability, accessed via www.imf.org/external/np/exr/facts/
changing.htm on 10 December 2018.
34. International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook, 1998.
35. L. Laeven and F. Valencia, IMF Working Paper: Systemic Banking Crisis
Revisited, accessed via www.imf.org/~/media/Files/Publications/WP/2018/
wp18206.ashx on 5 December 2018.
36. R. Altman, ‘The great crash, 2008: a geopolitical setback for the West’,
Foreign Affairs, 88(1) (January/February 2009); M. Goldstein, ‘A grand
bargain for the London G20 summit: insurance and obeying the rules’,
VoxEU.org, February 2009, accessed via https://voxeu.org/article/grandbargain-london-g20-summit on 10 December 2018.
37. M. Feldstein, ‘Refocusing the IMF’, Foreign Affairs, 77(2) (March/April 1998).
38. International Monetary Fund, Factsheet: How the IMF Promotes Global
Economic Stability, March 2018, accessed via https://www.imf.org/en/
About/Factsheets/Sheets/2016/07/27/15/22/How-the-IMF-PromotesGlobal-Economic-Stability on 10 December 2018.
39. Parkinson and McKissack, ‘The IMF and the challenge of relevance in the
international financial architecture’ (2003), op. cit.; International Monetary
Fund, Initial Lessons of the Crisis for the Global Architecture and the IMF,
Strategy, Policy and Review Departments, 18 February 2009, accessed via
www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2009/021809.pdf on 10 December 2018.
40. International Monetary Fund, IMF Lending Arrangements as of
October 2018, accessed via www.imf.org/external/np/fin/tad/extarr11.
aspx?memberKey1=ZZZZ&date1key=2020-02-28 on 5 December 2018.
41. International Monetary Fund, Factsheet: IMF Lending, March 2018.
Available https://www.imf.org/en/About/Factsheets/IMF-Lending, accessed
10 December 2018.
42. J. Sachs, ‘Power unto itself’, Financial Times, 9 December 1997, p. 11; M.
Feldstein, ‘Refocusing the IMF’, Foreign Affairs, 77(2) (March/April 1998).
43. S. Babb and A. Buira, Mission Creep, Mission Push and Discretion in
Sociological Perspective: The Case of IMF Conditionality, Geneva, 8–9
March 2004, accessed via www.g24.org/wp-content/uploads/2016/01/
Mission-Creep-Mission-Push-and-Discretion-in-Sociological-Perspective.
pdf on 10 December 2018.
44. Feldstein, ‘Refocusing the IMF’ (1998), op. cit.
45. ‘Reshaping the IMF’, The Economist, 22 April 2006, p. 83.
46. The Asian Century Institute, Chiang Mai Initiative: An Asian IMF?, 5 April
2017, accessed via http://asiancenturyinstitute.com/economy/248-chiangmai-initiative-an-asian-imf on 10 December 2018.
47. D. Dodge, ‘The evolving international monetary order and the need for an
evolving IMF’, Bank of Canada Review, Spring 2006.
48. Feldstein, ‘Refocusing the IMF’ (1998), op. cit.; Sachs, ‘Power unto itself’
(1997), op. cit., p. 11.
49. M. Wolf, ‘Same old IMF medicine’, Financial Times, 9 December 1997, p. 12.
FOREIGN EXCHANGE AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY SYSTEM
205
08/07/19 04:03 PM
50. S. Claessens, C. Pazarbasioglu, L. Laeven, M. Dobler, F. Valancia, O.
Nedelescu and K. Seal, Crisis Management and Resolutions: Early Lessons
from the Financial Crisis, IMF, March 2011, accessed via www.imf.org/
external/pubs/ft/sdn/2011/sdn1105.pdf on 10 December 2018.
51. Ibid.
52. J. Williamson, ‘Reforming the IMF’, VoxEU.org, February 2009, accessed via
https://piie.com/commentary/op-eds/reforming-imf on 10 December 2018.
53. International Monetary Fund, Factsheet: IMF Quotas, April 2018, accessed
via www.imf.org/en/About/Factsheets/Sheets/2016/07/14/12/21/
IMF-Quotas on 6 December 2018.
54. L. Wroughton, ‘IMF vote reform bogged down by delays, deadlock’,
Reuters, 8 October 2012, accessed via www.reuters.com/
206
PART 2
article/2012/10/08/us-imf-governance-idUSBRE8970B120121008 on
10 December 2018.
55. International Monetary Fund, Initial Lessons of the Crisis for the Global
Architecture and the IMF, Strategy, Policy and Review Departments,
18 February 2009, accessed via https://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/
eng/2009/021809.pdf on 10 December 2018.
56. For examples of the use of matching see H. Kamil, How Do Exchange Rate
Regimes Affect Firms’ Incentives to Hedge Currency Risk? Micro Evidence
for Latin America, IMF Working Paper WP/12/69, March 2012, accessed
via www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2012/wp1269.pdf on 10 December
2018.
CROSS-BORDER LINKAGES: TRADE, INVESTMENT AND EXCHANGE
hiL23674_ch04_159-206.indd
206
08/07/19 04:03 PM
3
© Cherkas/Shutterstock
COUNTRY DIFFERENCES
CHAPTER 5
DIFFERENCES IN CULTURE
CHAPTER 6
POLITICAL AND LEGAL ENVIRONMENTS
CHAPTER 7
ECONOMIC ENVIRONMENT
CHAPTER 8
ETHICS AND CORPORATE RESPONSIBILITY
CHAPTER 9
COUNTRY MARKET RESEARCH
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd 207
08/06/19 07:50 PM
© Rawpixel.com/Shutterstock
CHAPTER 5
DIFFERENCES IN CULTURE
208
PART 3
COUNTRY DIFFERENCES
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd
208
08/06/19 07:50 PM
INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS GRADUATE
ATTRIBUTES (IBGAs)
This chapter’s content, learning resources and case studies provide you with the
opportunity to develop a number of International Business Graduate Attributes (IBGAs),
including the following:
IBGA1
IBGA2
IBGA3
IBGA5
IBGA6
Discipline Knowledge and Skills
Critical Analysis
Problem Solving
Communication
Social Interaction
LEARNING OBJECTIVES (LOs)
5.1
5.2
5.3
5.4
5.5
Know what is meant by the culture of a society.
Identify the forces that lead to differences in culture.
Identify the business and economic implications of differences
in culture.
Understand how differences in culture influence the conduct
of business.
Develop an appreciation for the economic and business
implications of cultural change.
CHAPTER 5
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd 209
DIFFERENCES IN CULTURE
209
08/06/19 07:50 PM
OPENING CASE
EVOLVING CULTURE AT PANASONIC
Founded by Ko–nosuke Matsushita in 1918, the
consumer electronics giant Panasonic has grown from
manufacturing light bulbs in Matsushita’s home in Osaka
with three employees to a global giant with 250 000
employees and more than $70 billion in sales in 2018.
With a founding philosophy of placing customer and
employee needs first, Panasonic was at the forefront
of Japan’s rise to the status of major economic power
during the 1970s and 1980s (before 2009, Panasonic was
known as Matsushita). Like many other longstanding
Japanese businesses, Panasonic was regarded as a bastion
of traditional Japanese values based on strong group
identification, reciprocal obligations and loyalty to the
company. Several commentators attributed Panasonic’s
success, and that of the Japanese economy, to the
existence of Confucian values in the workplace. At
Panasonic, employees were taken care of by the company
from ‘the cradle to the grave’. Panasonic provided them
with a wide range of benefits including cheap housing,
guaranteed lifetime employment, seniority-based pay
systems and generous retirement bonuses. In return,
Panasonic expected, and got, loyalty and hard work from
its employees. To Japan’s postwar generation, struggling
to recover from the humiliation of defeat, it seemed
like a fair bargain. The employees worked hard for the
greater good of Panasonic, and Panasonic reciprocated by
bestowing ‘blessings’ on employees.
However, culture does not stay constant. According to
some observers, the generation born after 1964 lack the
same commitment to traditional Japanese values as their
parents. They grew up in a world that was richer, where
Western ideas were beginning to make themselves felt
and where the possibilities seemed greater. They did not
want to be tied to a company for life, to be a ‘salaryman’.
These trends came to the fore in the 1990s when the
Japanese economy entered a prolonged economic slump.
As the decade progressed, one Japanese company after
another was forced to change its traditional ways of doing
business. Slowly at first, troubled companies started to
lay off older workers, effectively abandoning lifetime
employment guarantees. As younger people saw this
happening, they concluded that loyalty to a company
210
PART 3
might not be reciprocated, effectively undermining one of
the central bargains made in postwar Japan.
Panasonic was one of the last companies to turn its back
on Japanese traditions, but in 1998, after years of poor
performance, it began to modify traditional practices.
The principal agents of change were a group of managers
who had extensive experience in Panasonic’s overseas
operations, and included Kunio Nakamura, who became
the company’s chief executive in 2000.
First, Panasonic changed the pay scheme for its 11 000
managers. In the past, the traditional twice-a-year
bonuses were based almost entirely on seniority, but
now Panasonic said they would be based on performance.
In 1999, Panasonic announced this process would be
made transparent: managers would be shown their
performance rankings and how these fed into pay
bonuses. As elementary as this might sound in the
West, for Panasonic it represented the beginning of a
revolution in human resource practices.
About the same time, Panasonic took aim at the lifetime
employment system and the associated perks. Under
the new system, recruits were given the choice of three
employment options. First, they could sign on to the
traditional option. Under this, they were eligible to live
in subsidised company housing, go free to companyorganised social events and buy subsidised services such
as banking from group companies. They also still would
receive a retirement bonus equal to two years’ salary.
Under the second scheme, employees could forgo the
guaranteed retirement bonus in exchange for a higher
starting salary and keep perks such as cheap company
housing. Under the third scheme, they would lose both
the retirement bonus and the subsidised services, but
they would start at an even higher salary. In its first two
years of operation, only 3 per cent of recruits chose the
third option—suggesting that there is still a hankering for
the traditional paternalistic relationship—but 41 per cent
took the second option.
In other ways Panasonic’s designs are grander still. As the
company has moved into new industries such as software
engineering and network communications technology,
COUNTRY DIFFERENCES
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd
210
08/06/19 07:50 PM
it has begun to sing the praises of democratisation of
employees and it has sought to encourage individuality,
initiative taking and risk seeking among its younger
employees. But while such changes may be easy to
articulate, they are hard to implement. For all of its
talk, Panasonic has been slow to dismantle its lifetime
employment commitment to those hired under the
traditional system. This was underlined in early 2001
when, in response to continued poor performance,
Panasonic announced it would close 30 factories in Japan,
cut 13 000 jobs (including 1000 management jobs) and sell
a ‘huge amount of assets’ over the next three years. While
this seemed to indicate a final break with the lifetime
employment system—it represented the first layoffs in the
company’s history—the company also said unnecessary
management staff would not be fired but instead
transferred to higher growth areas such as health care.
With so many of the company’s managers a product of
the old way of doing things, a sceptic might question the
company’s ability to turn its intentions into reality. As
growth has slowed, Panasonic has had to cut back on its
hiring, but its continued commitment to longstanding
employees means that the average age of its workforce is
rising. In the 1960s it was around 25; by the early 2000s
it was 35, a trend that might counteract Panasonic’s
attempts to revolutionise the workplace, for surely those
who benefited from the old system will not give way
easily to the new. Still, by the mid-2000s it was clear that
Panasonic was making progress. After significant losses
in 2002, the company broke even in 2003 and started to
make profits again in 2004. New growth drivers—such as
sales of DVD equipment—helped, but so did the cultural
and organisational changes that enabled the company
to better exploit these new opportunities. The company
continued to make solid profits until 2009, when, like
most enterprises, it was hit by the global recession.
Panasonic’s response to this showed how much the
company had changed. The company quickly announced
that it would close 27 plants and lay off 15 000
employees, half of them in Japan, signalling, perhaps, the
demise of its lifetime employment commitments that the
founder made. Marking its 100th anniversary Panasonic
will need to continue to innovate, adapt to changing
competition and evolve its organisational culture to
continue to succeed in the dynamic global marketplace.
SOURCES: ‘Putting the bounce back into Matsushita’, The Economist, 22 May 1999, pp. 67–8; ‘In search of the new Japanese dream’, The Economist, 19 February
2000, pp. 59–60; P. Landers, ‘Matsushita to restructure in bid to boost thin profits’, The Wall Street Journal, 1 December 2000, p. A13; M. Tanikawa, ‘A pillar of
Japan Inc. finally turns around; work in progress’, International Herald Tribune, 28 August 2004, pp. 17–18; ‘Panasonic will slash jobs, shut 27 plants’, Los Angeles
Times, 5 February 2009, p. C3; Panasonic history accessed via www.panasonic-electric-works.com/en/100th-anniversary/timeline.htm on 14 October 2018;
Forbes, www.forbes.com/companies/panasonic/#50ef318e5774, accessed on 14 October 2018.
INTRODUCTION
International business is different from domestic business because countries are different.
In this chapter, we explore how differences and similarities in culture across countries can
affect international business. Several themes run through this chapter.
The first theme is that business success in a variety of countries requires cross-cultural
literacy. By cross-cultural literacy, we mean an understanding of how cultural differences
across and within nations can affect the way business is practised. In these days of global
communications, rapid transportation and worldwide markets, it is easy to forget just how
different various cultures really are. Underneath the veneer of modernism, deep cultural
differences often remain. Westerners in general are quick to conclude that because people
from other parts of the world also wear jeans, listen to Western popular music, eat at
McDonald’s and drink Coca-Cola, they also accept the basic tenets of Western culture.
However, this is not true. For example, increasingly, the Chinese are embracing the material
products of modern society. Anyone who has visited China cannot fail to be struck by
how modern many Chinese cities seem, with their skyscrapers, department stores and
CHAPTER 5
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd 211
CROSS-CULTURAL LITERACY
An understanding of how cultural
differences across and within
nations can affect the way business
is practised
DIFFERENCES IN CULTURE
211
08/06/19 07:50 PM
© Glow Images
freeways. Yet beneath the veneer of Western modernism,
longstanding cultural traditions rooted in a 2000-year-old
ideology continue to have an important influence on the
way business is transacted in China. In China, guanxi—
relationships backed by reciprocal obligations—are central to
getting business done, and firms that lack sufficient guanxi
may find themselves at a disadvantage. In this chapter, we
argue that it is important for foreign businesses to gain an
understanding of the culture that prevails in those countries
where they do business.
Another theme developed in this chapter is that a
relationship may exist between culture and the cost of
doing business in a country or region. Different cultural
attributes may increase or lower the costs of doing business.
Japan’s modernity and the appearance of Western
For example, some observers have argued that cultural
modernism do not translate into cultural similarity.
factors lowered the costs of doing business in Japan and
helped to explain Japan’s rapid economic ascent during the 1960s, 1970s and 1980s.1
However, as highlighted by the opening case, cultures change over time. This brings us to
another theme that we explore in this chapter. Culture is not static. It can and does evolve,
although the rate at which it can change is the subject of some dispute. In Australia and
New Zealand, significant changes in culture have occurred during the past 60 years, partly
due to the influx of new migrants and advances in technology.
WHAT IS CULTURE?
LO 5.1
CULTURE
A system of values and norms that
are shared among a group of people
and that when taken together
constitute a design for living
Scholars have never been able to agree on a simple definition of culture. In the 1870s,
the anthropologist Edward Tylor defined culture as ‘that complex whole which includes
knowledge, belief, art, morals, law, custom, and other capabilities acquired by man as a
member of society’.2 Since then, hundreds of other definitions have been offered. Geert
Hofstede, an expert on cross-cultural differences and management, defined culture as ‘the
collective programming of the mind which distinguishes the members of one human
group from another . . . Culture, in this sense, includes systems of values; and values
are among the building blocks of culture’.3 Another definition of culture comes from
sociologists Zvi Namenwirth and Robert Weber, who see culture as a system of ideas and
argue that these ideas constitute a design for living.4
Ed Schein (2010) defines the culture of a group as:
. . . a pattern of shared basic assumptions learned by a group as it solved its problems
of external adaptation and internal integration, which has worked well enough to be
considered valid and, therefore, to be taught to new members as the correct way to
perceive, think, and feel in relation to those problems.5
VALUES
Abstract ideas about what a group
believes to be good, right and
desirable
NORMS
The social rules and guidelines that
prescribe appropriate behaviour in
particular situations
212
PART 3
This definition does not capture the size or location of the social unit. As Schein points
out, within countries, minorities, religions and other social groups have cultures—macrocultures.
Also, Schein identified the potential for large MNCs such as Unilever to have a corporate
culture, in spite of the presence of a multitude of subcultures within the organisation.
Here we follow Hofstede, Schein and Namenwirth and Weber, by viewing culture as a
system of values and norms that are shared among a group of people, and that when taken
together constitute a design for living. By values we mean abstract ideas about what a
group believes to be good, right and desirable. Put differently, values are shared assumptions
about how things ought to be.6 By norms we mean the social rules and guidelines that
COUNTRY DIFFERENCES
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd
212
08/06/19 07:50 PM
prescribe appropriate behaviour in particular situations. We use the term ‘society’ to refer
to a group of people who share a common set of values and norms. While a society may be
equivalent to a country, some countries harbour several societies (i.e. they support multiple
cultures), and some societies embrace more than one country.
SOCIETY
A group of people who share a
common set of values and norms
Values and norms
Values form the bedrock of a culture. They provide the context within which a society’s
norms are established and justified. They may include a society’s attitudes towards
such concepts as individual freedom, democracy, truth, justice, honesty, loyalty, social
obligations, collective responsibility, the role of women, love, sex, marriage, and so on.
Values are not just abstract concepts; they are invested with considerable emotional
significance. People argue, fight and even die over values such as freedom. Values are also
often reflected in the political and economic systems of a society.
Norms are the social rules that govern people’s actions towards one another. Norms can
be subdivided further into two main categories: the routine conventions of everyday life,
and other norms that are seen as central to the functioning of a society and to its social life.
The routine conventions of everyday life
Generally, these are social conventions concerning things such as the appropriate dress
code in a particular situation, good social manners, eating with the correct utensils,
neighbourly behaviour and the like. However, violation of these norms is not considered
to be a serious matter. People who violate them may be thought of as eccentric or illmannered, but they are not usually considered to be evil or bad. In many countries,
foreigners may initially be excused for violating some of these norms.
Attitude towards time
People are keenly aware of the passage of time in Australia, the United States and
Northern European cultures such as Germany and Britain. Businesspeople are very
conscious about scheduling their time and are quickly irritated when their time is wasted
because a business associate is late for a meeting or they are kept waiting. They talk
about time as though it were money, as something that can be spent, saved, wasted and
lost.7 Alternatively, in Arab, Latin, Mediterranean and many Asian cultures, time has a
more elastic character. Keeping to a schedule is viewed as less important than finishing
an interaction with people. For example, an Australian or New Zealand businessperson
might feel insulted if he or she is kept waiting for 30 minutes outside the office of a Latin
American executive before a meeting, but the executive may simply be completing an
interaction with an associate and view the information gathered from this encounter as
more important than sticking to a rigid schedule. The Latin American executive intends
no disrespect, but due to different perspectives about the importance of time, the
Australian may see things differently. Similarly, Saudi attitudes to time have been shaped
by their nomadic Bedouin heritage, in which precise time played no real role and arriving
somewhere ‘tomorrow’ might mean next week. Like Latin Americans, many Saudis are
unlikely to understand the general Western obsession with precise time and schedules, and
Australians and New Zealanders need to adjust their expectations accordingly. However,
it is not uncommon to find that businesspeople of cultures where precise timing is less
important will accommodate the needs of business partners who view ‘time as money’.
Rituals and symbols
Rituals and symbols are the most visible manifestations of a culture and constitute the
outward expression of deeper values. For example, upon meeting a foreign business
executive, a Japanese executive will hold his or her business card in both hands and bow
CHAPTER 5
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd 213
DIFFERENCES IN CULTURE
213
08/06/19 07:50 PM
© Dave and Les Jacobs/Blend Images LLC
while presenting the card to the foreigner.8 This ritual
behaviour is loaded with deep cultural symbolism. The
card specifies the rank of the Japanese executive, which
is a very important piece of information in a hierarchical
society such as Japan. (Japanese businesspeople often have
business cards with Japanese printed on one side and
English on the other.) The bow is a sign of respect, and
the deeper the angle of the bow, the greater the reverence
one person shows for the other. The person receiving the
card is expected to examine it carefully, which is a way
of returning respect and acknowledging the card giver’s
position in the hierarchy. The foreigner is also expected
to bow when taking the card, and to return the greeting
by presenting the Japanese executive with his or her own
card, similarly bowing in the process. Failure to bow and to
read the given card, and to casually pocket it, violates this
ritual and is considered rude.
There are other norms that are seen as central to the
functioning of a society and to its social life. They have
much greater significance than the routine conventions of
In a number of Asian countries there are deep-seated
everyday life discussed above. Accordingly, violating these
rituals associated with exchanging business cards and it is
norms can bring serious retribution. These norms include
important to follow these rituals. It is a mark of respect to
your business partners.
such factors as indictments against theft, adultery, incest
and cannibalism. In many societies, certain norms have
been enacted into law. Thus, all advanced societies have laws against theft, incest and
cannibalism. However, there are also many differences between cultures. In Australia, for
example, drinking alcohol is widely accepted, whereas in Saudi Arabia the consumption of
alcohol is viewed as violating an important social norm and is punishable by imprisonment
(as some Western citizens working in Saudi Arabia have discovered).
ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
ONLINE VIEW OF OTHER CULTURES
Visit the English versions of major foreign newspapers
online to get a sense of their cultural values, social
structure and markets. Look at the ads and business
names. Check out the classifieds. See
www.onlinenewspapers.com.
Culture, society and the nation-state
We have defined a society as a group of people who share a common set of values and
norms; that is, people who are bound together by a common culture. There is not a strict
one-to-one correspondence between a society and a nation-state. Nation-states are political
creations. They may contain a single culture or several cultures. While the French nation
can be thought of as the political embodiment of French culture, the nation of Canada
has at least three cultures—an Anglo culture, a French-speaking ‘Quebecois’ culture and a
Native American culture. In Australia, Indigenous people are an extremely diverse group
214
PART 3
COUNTRY DIFFERENCES
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd
214
08/06/19 07:50 PM
consisting of more than 500 distinct groups or ‘nations’: in the past, there were hundreds
of languages and dialects and a multitude of distinct cultures.9 Many African nations have
important cultural differences between tribal groups, as witnessed in the early 1990s
when Rwanda dissolved into a bloody civil war between two tribes, the Tutsi and the
Hutu. Like Africa, India is composed of many distinct cultural groups.
During the first Gulf War (which began in 1990) Iraq was seen as a homogenous Arab
nation. However, we have learned that several different societies exist within Iraq, each
with its own culture and history. The Kurds in the north do not view themselves as Arabs
and have their own distinct history and traditions. There are two Arab societies: the Shiites
in the south, and the Sunnis who populate the middle of the country and who ruled Iraq
under the regime of Saddam Hussein. (‘Shiite’ and ‘Sunni’ refer to different sects within the
religion of Islam.) Among the southern Sunnis is another distinct society of 500 000 Marsh
Arabs who live at the confluence of the Tigris and Euphrates Rivers, pursuing a way of life
that dates back 5000 years.10
At the other end of the scale are cultures that embrace a number of nations. Several
scholars argue that we can speak of an Islamic society or culture shared by citizens residing
in different nations in the Middle East, in Asia and in Africa.
To complicate things further, it is also possible to talk about culture at different levels.
It is common to talk about ‘Australian society’ and ‘Australian culture’, but there are several
societies within Australia—each with its own culture. Within Australia one can talk about
Indigenous culture, Chinese culture, Italian culture, Indian culture and Greek culture. In
Aotearoa (New Zealand), the relationship between culture and country is often ambiguous
in Māori and non-Māori culture, each of which consists of several societies. One cannot
always characterise a country as having a single homogenous culture; and even when one
can, in a country such as Japan, one must also often recognise that the national culture is a
mosaic of subcultures.
The determinants of culture
AOTEAROA
Māori name for New Zealand
LO 5.2
The values and norms of a culture do not emerge fully formed. They are the evolutionary
product of a number of factors, including the prevailing political and economic
philosophies; the social structure of a society; and the dominant religion, language and
education (see Fig. 5.1). In addition, the political and economic philosophies influence
FIGURE 5.1
The determinants of culture
Religion
Social
structure
Political
philosophy
Cultural
norms and
value
systems
Economic
philosophy
Language
Education
CHAPTER 5
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd 215
DIFFERENCES IN CULTURE
215
08/06/19 07:50 PM
the value systems of a society. For example, the values found in Communist North Korea
towards freedom, justice and individual achievement are clearly different from the values
found in Australia, precisely because the two societies operate according to different
political and economic philosophies. Below we discuss the influence of social structure,
religion, language and education. The chain of causation runs both ways. While factors
such as social structure and religion clearly influence the values and norms of a society,
the values and norms of a society can influence social structure and religion.
SOCIAL STRUCTURE
SOCIAL STRUCTURE
The basic social organisation
of a society
A society’s social structure refers to its basic social organisation. Although social structure
consists of many different aspects, two dimensions are particularly important when
explaining differences between cultures. The first is the degree to which the basic unit of
social organisation is the individual, as opposed to the group. In general, Western societies
tend to emphasise the primacy of the individual, whereas in many Asian societies the
focus is on the group. The second dimension is the degree to which a society is stratified
into classes or castes. Some societies are characterised by a relatively high degree of social
stratification and relatively low mobility between strata (e.g. Indian society); other societies
are characterised by a low degree of social stratification and high mobility between strata
(e.g. the Australian, New Zealand and American societies).
Individuals and groups
LO 5.3
GROUP
An association of two or more
individuals who have a shared
sense of identity and who interact
with each other in structured ways
on the basis of a common set of
expectations about each other’s
behaviour
A group is an association of two or more individuals who have a shared sense of identity
and who interact with each other in structured ways on the basis of a common set of
expectations about each other’s behaviour.11 Human social life is group life. Individuals are
involved in families, work groups, social groups, recreational groups, and so on. However,
while groups are found in all societies, societies differ according to the degree to which
the group is viewed as the primary means of social organisation.12 In some societies,
individual attributes and achievements are viewed as being more important than group
membership; in others, the reverse is true.
The individual
In many Western societies, the individual is the basic building block of social organisation.
This is reflected not just in the political and economic organisation of society, but also in
the way people perceive themselves and relate to each other in social and business settings.
Researchers such as Harry Triandis suggested that individualistic societies can be
subdivided into two subgroups—namely, horizontal and vertical individualism. Horizontally
individualistic countries include Australia and the Scandinavian countries such as Sweden and
Denmark where the emphasis is on independence of action and equality with others. (It is also
important to note that within Australia and New Zealand, the Aboriginal and Māori people
respectively tend to be group-oriented societies.) However, most wealthy Western countries,
such as the United States and the United Kingdom, tend to be vertically individualistic
countries where independence of action and standing out from others is emphasised.13
The emphasis on individual performance in many Western societies has both beneficial
and harmful aspects. In Australia and the United States, the emphasis on individual
performance finds expression in an admiration of rugged individualism and entrepreneurship.
One benefit of this is the high level of entrepreneurial activity in Western societies.
Individualism also finds expression in a high degree of managerial mobility between
companies, and this is not always a good thing. Although moving from company to
216
PART 3
COUNTRY DIFFERENCES
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd
216
08/06/19 07:50 PM
company may be good for individual managers who are trying to build impressive resumés,
it is not necessarily a good thing for companies. The lack of loyalty and commitment
to an individual company, and the tendency to move on for a better offer, can result in
managers who have good general skills but lack the knowledge, experience and network
of interpersonal contacts that come from years of working within the same company. An
effective manager draws on company-specific experience, knowledge and a network of
contacts to find solutions to current problems, and Australian companies may suffer if their
managers lack these attributes. One positive aspect of high-managerial mobility is that
executives are exposed to different ways of doing business. The ability to compare business
practices helps executives to identify how good practices and techniques developed in one
company might be profitably applied to other companies.
The emphasis on individualism may also make it difficult to build teams within an
organisation to perform collective tasks. Individuals are always competing with each other
on the basis of individual performance, so it may be difficult for them to cooperate. The
emphasis on individualism in Australia and the United States, while helping to create a
dynamic, entrepreneurial economy, may raise the costs of doing business due to its adverse
impact on managerial stability and cooperation.
The group
In contrast to the Western emphasis on the individual, the group is the primary unit of
social organisation in many other societies. For example, in Japan, the social status of an
individual is determined as much by the standing of the group to which he or she belongs
as by his or her individual performance.14
In traditional Japanese society, the group was the family or village to which an
individual belonged. Today, the group has frequently come to be associated with the work
team or business organisation to which an individual belongs. In a now-classic study of
Japanese society, Chie Nakane noted how this orientation expresses itself in everyday life:
When a Japanese faces the outside (confronts another person) and affixes some position
to himself socially he is inclined to give precedence to institution over kind of occupation.
Rather than saying, ‘I am a typesetter’ or ‘I am a filing clerk’, he is likely to say, ‘I am from
B Publishing Group’ or ‘I belong to S company’.15
Nakane goes on to observe that the primacy of the group to which an individual
belongs often evolves into a deeply emotional attachment in which identification with
the group becomes all-important in one’s life. One central value of Japanese culture is
the importance attached to group membership. This may have beneficial implications for
business organisations. Strong identification with the group is urged to create pressures
for mutual self-help and collective action. If the worth of an individual is closely linked
to the achievements of the group (e.g. the company), as Nakane maintains is the case
in Japan, this creates a strong incentive for individual members of the group to work
together for the common good. Some argue that the success of Japanese enterprises in
the global economy has been based partly on their ability to achieve close cooperation
between individuals within a company and between companies. This has found expression
in the widespread diffusion of self-managing work teams within Japanese organisations,
the close cooperation among different functions within Japanese companies (e.g. among
manufacturing, marketing and R&D) and the cooperation between a company and its
suppliers on issues such as design, quality control and inventory reduction.16 In all these
cases, cooperation is driven by the need to improve the performance of the group (i.e. the
business organisation).
The primacy of the value of group identification also discourages managers and workers
from moving from company to company. Lifetime employment in a particular company was
CHAPTER 5
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd 217
DIFFERENCES IN CULTURE
217
08/06/19 07:50 PM
long the norm in certain sectors of the Japanese economy.17 Over the years, managers and
workers build up knowledge, experience and a network of interpersonal business contacts.
All these things can help managers perform their jobs more effectively and achieve
cooperation with others.
Social stratification
LO 5.2
SOCIAL STRATA
The hierarchical categories within a
society, defined on the basis of such
elements as family background,
income and occupation
All societies are stratified on a hierarchical basis into social categories—that is, into
social strata. These strata are typically defined on the basis of characteristics such as family
background, occupation and income. Individuals are born into a particular stratum. They
become a member of the social category to which their parents belong. Individuals born
into a stratum towards the top of the social hierarchy tend to have better life chances than
those born into a stratum towards the bottom of the hierarchy. They are likely to have
better education, health, standard of living and work opportunities. Although all societies
are stratified to some degree, they differ in two related ways. First, they differ from each
other with regard to the degree of mobility between social strata; second, they differ with
regard to the significance attached to social strata in business contexts. Overall, social
stratification is based on four basic principles:18
•
social stratification is a trait of society, not a reflection of individual differences
•
social stratification carries over to the next generation
•
social stratification is generally universal but variable; for example, it is entrenched in
rural India and to a lesser extent in urban areas
•
social stratification does not just involve inequality, it is also embedded in religious beliefs.
Social mobility
SOCIAL MOBILITY
The extent to which individuals can
move out of the strata into which
they are born
CASTE SYSTEM
A closed system of stratification in
which social position is determined
by the family into which a person is
born, and change out of that strata
is usually not possible during a
person’s lifetime
CLASS SYSTEM
A less rigid social stratification
system, in which mobility is
possible depending on a person’s
achievements or even just luck
218
PART 3
The term social mobility refers to the extent to which individuals can move out of the
strata into which they are born. Social mobility varies significantly from society to society.
The most rigid system of stratification is a caste system. A caste system is a closed system
of stratification in which social position is hereditary—that is, determined by the family
into which a person is born—and change in that position is usually not possible during an
individual’s lifetime. Often a caste position carries with it a specific occupation. Members
of one caste might be shoemakers, members of another might be butchers and so on.
These occupations are embedded in the caste and passed down through the family to
succeeding generations. Although the number of societies with caste systems diminished
rapidly during the 20th century, one partial example still remains: India has four main
castes and several thousand sub-castes. Even though the caste system was officially
abolished in 1949 (two years after India became independent) and made unlawful in
1976,19 it is still a force in Indian society where occupation and marital opportunities are
still partly related to caste.
A class system is a less rigid form of social stratification in which social mobility is
possible. It is a form of open stratification in which the position a person has by birth can
be changed through his or her own achievements or luck. Individuals born into a class at
the bottom of the hierarchy can work their way up; conversely, individuals born into a class
at the top of the hierarchy can slip down.
While many societies have class systems, social mobility within a class system varies
from society to society. For example, some sociologists have argued that Britain has a more
rigid class structure than certain other Western societies, such as the United States20 and
Australia. Historically, British society was divided into three main classes: the upper class,
COUNTRY DIFFERENCES
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd
218
08/06/19 07:50 PM
COUNTRY FOCUS
BREAKING INDIA’S CASTE SYSTEM
AND GENDER DISCRIMINATION
India’s ancient caste system, which places people
into different categories based on birth and has long
been an impediment to social mobility, is starting to
fade among the educated urban middle class who
make up the majority of employees in the high-tech
economy. However, the same is not true in rural India
where 70 per cent of the population still resides. There,
caste and gender discrimination remain a pervasive
influence. In 1950, the national constitution reserved
22.5 per cent of jobs for people from the lower castes,
or Dalits (also known as ‘untouchables’), and for tribal
people. In 1990, an additional 27 per cent of jobs were
set aside for those known as ‘other backward castes’.
Some Indian states set higher quotas, including Tamil
Nadu, which reserves 69 per cent of government jobs
for lower castes and other needy groups. Despite
these longstanding policies and some spectacularly
successful rags to riches stories, such as that of
Kalpana Saroj, discrimination remains. Kalpana Saroj
is a Dalit who heads Kamani Tubes and several other
companies. She overcame discrimination, abject
poverty, abuse and death threats to become the head
of companies worth more than $200 million and is a
multi-millionaire in her own right.
Unfortunately, anecdotal and hard evidence suggests
that the caste system and discrimination against
women still play an important role in daily life in India.
For example, a young female engineer at Infosys who
grew up in a small rural village and is a Dalit recounts
how she never entered the house of a Brahmin, India’s
elite priestly caste, even though half of her village
were Brahmins. When a Dalit was hired to cook at the
© Mint/Contributor/Getty Images
Modern India is a country of contrasts, steeped in
history and traditions. It is the largest democracy in the
world. In recent years India’s information technology
sector has become one of the most vibrant worldwide,
with companies such as Infosys and Wipro Ltd
emerging as powerful global players.
Through her perseverance and entrepreneurial spirit,
Kalpana Saroj is one of only a few Dalits/women to have
succeeded as a CEO in India.
school in her native village, Brahmins withdrew their
children from the school. The engineer herself is the
beneficiary of a charitable training system that Infosys
launched in 2006. Her caste is among the poorest in
India, with some 91 per cent making less than $100 a
month, compared to 65 per cent of Brahmins. To try to
correct this historic inequality, politicians have talked
for years about extending the employment quota
system to private enterprises. The government has told
private companies to hire more Dalits and members
of tribal communities and has warned that strong
measures will be taken if companies do not comply.
Private employers are resisting government attempts
to impose quotas, arguing with some justification that
people who are guaranteed a job by a quota system
are unlikely to work very hard. At the same time,
progressive employers realise that they need to do
something to correct the inequalities and that, unless
India taps into the lower castes and women, it may not
be able to find the employees required to staff rapidly
growing high-technology organisations.
SOURCES: ‘With reservations: business and caste in India’, The Economist, 6 October 2007, pp. 81–3; Eric Bellman, ‘Reversal of fortune isolates
India’s Brahmins’, The Wall Street Journal, 24 December 2007, p. 4; Rajini Vaidyanathan, ‘From child bride to millionaire in India’, www.bbc.co.uk/news/
world-asia-india-18186908, accessed on 24 July 2012; ‘Meet Kalpana Saroj, Dalit entrepreneur who broke corporate hegemony’, The Indian Express,
5 February 2019, accessed via https://indianexpress.com/article/business/meet-kalpana-saroj-dalit-entrepreneur-who-broke-corporate-hegemony/ on
20 October 2018; www.kalpanasaroj.com/aboutus.aspx.
CHAPTER 5
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd 219
DIFFERENCES IN CULTURE
219
08/06/19 07:50 PM
© Rodrigo A Torres/Glow Images
which was made up of individuals whose families for generations had wealth, prestige
and, occasionally, power; the middle class, whose members were involved in professional,
managerial and clerical occupations; and the working class, whose members earned their
living from manual occupations. The middle class was further subdivided into the uppermiddle class, whose members were involved in important managerial occupations and
the prestigious professions (e.g. lawyers, accountants, doctors), and the lower-middle class,
whose members were involved in clerical work (e.g. bank tellers) and the less prestigious
professions (e.g. schoolteachers).
Historically, the British class system exhibited significant divergence between the life
chances of members of different classes. The upper and upper-middle classes typically
sent their children to a select group of private schools (known as public schools in
Britain), where they would not mix with lower-class children, and where they picked up
many of the speech accents and social norms that distinguished them as being from the
higher strata of society. These same schools also had close ties with the most prestigious
universities, such as Oxford and Cambridge. Until fairly recently, Oxford and Cambridge
guaranteed a certain number of places for the graduates of these schools. Having been
to a prestigious university, the offspring of the upper and upper-middle classes then had
an excellent chance of being offered a prestigious job in companies, banks, brokerage
companies and law firms run by members of the upper and upper-middle classes.
In contrast, the members of the British working and lower-middle classes typically went
to state-funded schools. The majority left school at 16, and those who went on to higher
education found it difficult to get accepted into the best universities. When they did,
they found that their lower-class accent and lack of appropriate social skills marked them
as being from a lower social stratum, which made it difficult for them to access the most
prestigious jobs. Thus, the class system in Britain perpetuated itself from generation to
generation, and social mobility was limited.
Although upward mobility was possible, it could not normally be achieved in one
generation. While an individual from a working-class background may have established
an income level of the upper-middle class, he or she may not have been accepted by
others of that class due to different accent and background. However, by sending his
or her offspring to the ‘right kind of school’, the individual could ensure that his or her
children were accepted.
According to many commentators, modern British society is now rapidly leaving this
class structure behind and moving towards a classless society. However, sociologists
continue to dispute this finding and present evidence that this is not the case. For example,
a study reported that in the mid-1990s, state-funded schools in the London suburb of
Islington, which has a population of 175 000, had only
79 candidates for university, while one prestigious private
school alone, Eton, sent more than that number to Oxford
and Cambridge.21 This, according to the study’s authors,
implies that ‘money still begets money’. They argue that
a good school means a good university, a good university
means a good job, and merit has only a limited chance of
elbowing its way into this tight little circle.
The class system in Australia, New Zealand and the
United States is less extreme than in Britain, and mobility is
greater. Like Britain, Australia, New Zealand and the United
States have their own upper, middle and working classes.
However, class membership is determined to a much greater
degree by individual economic achievements, as opposed
Until the late 1970s, social mobility in China was very limited. to background and schooling. Thus, an individual can, by
220
PART 3
COUNTRY DIFFERENCES
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd
220
08/06/19 07:50 PM
his or her own economic achievement, move smoothly from the working class to the upper
class within a lifetime. Successful individuals from humble origins may be highly respected in
Australian and American society. There are many examples of people from humble beginnings
rising to prominence in these societies; for example, Australia’s 24th prime minister, Paul
Keating, came from a working-class background, starting work as a pay clerk.22 New Zealand’s
prime minister in 1990 and later director-general of the World Trade Organization, The Right
Hon. Michael Kenneth Moore, started work as a labourer and a painter.23
Another society where class divisions have historically been of some importance has
been China, where there has been a longstanding difference between the life chances of
the rural peasantry and urban dwellers. Ironically, this historic division was strengthened
during the high point of Communist rule because of a rigid system of household
registration that restricted most Chinese to the place of their birth for their lifetime. Bound
to collective farming, peasants were cut off from many urban privileges—compulsory
education, quality schools, health care, public housing, varieties of foodstuffs, to name
only a few—and they largely lived in poverty. Social mobility was thus very limited. This
system crumbled following reforms of the late 1970s and early 1980s and, as a consequence,
migrant peasant labourers have flooded into China’s cities looking for work. Sociologists
now hypothesise that a new class system is emerging in China based less on the rural–
urban divide and more on urban occupation.24
Significance
From a business perspective, the stratification of a society is significant if it affects the
operation of business organisations. In American society, the high degree of social mobility
and the extreme emphasis on individualism limit the impact of class background on business
operations. The same is true in Japan, where most of the population perceives itself to be
middle class. In a country such as Great Britain, however, the relative lack of class mobility
and the differences between classes have resulted in the emergence of class consciousness.
Class consciousness refers to a condition where people tend to perceive themselves in terms
of their class background, and this shapes their relationships with members of other classes.
This perception has been played out in British society in the traditional hostility
between upper-middle-class managers and their working-class employees. Mutual
antagonism and lack of respect historically made it difficult to achieve cooperation between
management and labour in many British companies and resulted in a relatively high level
of industrial disputes. However, the last two decades have seen a dramatic reduction in
industrial disputes,25 which bolsters the arguments of those who claim that the country is
moving towards a classless society. (The level of industrial disputes in the United Kingdom
is now lower than in the United States.) Alternatively, as noted above, class consciousness
may be re-emerging in urban China, and it may ultimately prove to be significant there.
An antagonistic relationship between management and labour classes, and the resulting
lack of cooperation and high level of industrial disruption, tends to raise the costs of
production in countries characterised by significant class divisions. In turn, this can make
it more difficult for companies based in such countries to establish a competitive advantage
in the global economy.
LO 5.3
CLASS CONSCIOUSNESS
A condition where people tend to
perceive themselves in terms of their
class background, shaping how they
relate with members of other classes
LO 5.2
RELIGIOUS AND ETHICAL SYSTEMS
Religion may be defined as a system of shared beliefs and rituals that are concerned
with the realm of the sacred.26 Ethical systems refer to sets of moral principles or values
that are used to guide and shape behaviour. Most of the world’s ethical systems are
the product of religions. Thus, we can talk about Christian ethics and Islamic ethics.
However, there is a major exception to the principle that ethical systems are grounded
CHAPTER 5
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd 221
RELIGION
A system of shared beliefs and
rituals that are concerned with the
realm of the sacred
ETHICAL SYSTEMS
A set of moral principles, or values, that
are used to guide and shape behaviour
DIFFERENCES IN CULTURE
221
08/06/19 07:50 PM
in religion—Confucianism. Confucian ethics influence behaviour and shape culture in parts
of Asia, but it is not considered a religion.
The relationship between religion, ethics and society is subtle and complex. Among
the thousands of religions in the world today, four dominate in terms of numbers of
adherents: Christianity with 2.2 billion adherents, Islam with around 1.3 billion adherents,
Hinduism with 875 million adherents (primarily in India) and Buddhism with 385 million
adherents.27 Although many other religions have an important influence in certain parts
of the modern world (e.g. Judaism, which has 15 million adherents), their numbers pale in
comparison with the dominant religions (see Map 5.1). (However, as the precursor of both
Christianity and Islam, Judaism has an indirect influence that goes beyond its numbers.)
We will review these four religions, along with Confucianism, focusing on their business
implications. Some scholars have argued that the most important business implications of
religion centre on the extent to which different religions shape attitudes towards work
and entrepreneurship, and the degree to which religious ethics affect the costs of doing
business in a country.
It is hazardous to make sweeping generalisations about the nature of the relationships
between religion and ethical systems and business practice. Some scholars argue that there is
a relationship between religious and ethical systems and business practice in a society, but in
a world where nations with Catholic, Protestant, Muslim, Hindu and Buddhist majorities all
show evidence of entrepreneurial activity and sustainable economic growth, it is important
to view the proposed relationships critically. The proposed relationships may exist, but their
impact and influence is probably small compared to the impact of economic policy.
Christianity
LO 5.2
Christianity is the most widely practised religion in the world. Approximately 30 per cent
of the world’s people identify themselves as Christians. The vast majority of Christians
live in Europe and the Americas, although their numbers are rapidly growing in Africa.
Christianity grew out of Judaism. Like Judaism, it is a monotheistic religion. (Monotheism
is the belief in one god.) A religious division in the 11th century led to the establishment
of two major Christian organisations—the Roman Catholic Church and the Orthodox
Church. Today, the Roman Catholic Church accounts for more than half of all Christians,
most of whom are found in southern Europe and Latin America. The Orthodox Church,
while less influential, is still of major importance in several countries (e.g. Greece and
Russia). In the 16th century, the Reformation led to a further split with Rome; the
result was Protestantism. The nonconformist nature of Protestantism has facilitated
the emergence of numerous denominations under the Protestant umbrella (e.g. Baptist,
Methodist, Calvinist).
Economic implications of Christianity: The Protestant work ethic
LO 5.3
222
PART 3
Several sociologists have argued that of the main branches of Christianity—Catholic,
Orthodox and Protestant—Protestantism has the most important economic implications.
In 1904, a German sociologist, Max Weber, made a connection between Protestant ethics
and ‘the spirit of capitalism’ that has since become famous.28 Weber noted that capitalism
emerged in Western Europe, where business leaders and owners of capital, as well as the
higher grades of skilled labour, and even more the higher technically and commercially
trained personnel of modern enterprises, are overwhelmingly Protestant.29
Weber theorised that there was a relationship between Protestantism and the
emergence of modern capitalism. He argued that Protestant ethics emphasise the
importance of hard work and wealth creation (for the glory of God) and frugality
COUNTRY DIFFERENCES
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd
222
08/06/19 07:50 PM
(abstinence from worldly pleasures). According to Weber, this kind of value system
was needed to facilitate the development of capitalism. Protestants worked hard and
systematically to accumulate wealth. However, their ascetic beliefs suggested that rather
than consuming this wealth by indulging in worldly pleasures, they should invest it
in the expansion of capitalist enterprises. Thus, the combination of hard work and the
accumulation of capital, which could be used to finance investment and expansion, paved
the way for the development of capitalism in Western Europe and subsequently in the
United States. In contrast, Weber argued that the Catholic promise of salvation in the next
world, rather than this world, did not foster the same kind of work ethic.
Protestantism may also have encouraged capitalism’s development in another way.
By breaking away from the hierarchical domination of religious and social life that
characterised the Catholic Church for much of its history, Protestantism gave individuals
significantly more freedom to develop their own relationship with God. The right to
freedom of form of worship was central to the nonconformist nature of early Protestantism.
This emphasis on individual religious freedom may have paved the way for the subsequent
emphasis on individual economic and political freedoms and the development of
individualism as an economic and political philosophy.
Islam
LO 5.2
With more than 1.3 billion adherents, Islam is the second-largest of the world’s major
religions. Islam dates back to AD 610 when the Prophet Muhammad began spreading
the word, although the Muslim calendar begins in AD 622 when, to escape growing
opposition, Muhammad left Mecca for the oasis settlement of Yathrib, later known as
Medina. Adherents of Islam are referred to as Muslims. Muslims constitute a majority in
more than 35 countries and inhabit a nearly contiguous stretch of land from the northwest
coast of Africa, through the Middle East, to China and Malaysia.
Islam has roots in both Judaism and Christianity (Islam views Jesus Christ as one
of God’s prophets). Like Christianity and Judaism, Islam is a monotheistic religion. The
central principle of Islam is that there is but the one true omnipotent God. Islam requires
unconditional acceptance of the uniqueness, power and authority of God and the
understanding that the objective of life is to fulfil the dictates of his will in the hope of
admission to paradise. According to Islam, worldly gain and temporal power are an illusion.
Those who pursue riches on earth may gain them, but those who forgo worldly ambitions
to seek the favour of God may gain the greater treasure—entry into paradise. Other major
principles of Islam include honouring and respecting parents, respecting the rights of
others, being generous but not a squanderer, avoiding killing except for justifiable causes,
not committing adultery, dealing justly and equitably with others, being of pure heart and
mind, safeguarding the possessions of orphans, and being humble and unpretentious.30
Obvious parallels exist with many of the central principles of both Judaism and Christianity.
Islam is an all-embracing way of life governing the totality of a Muslim’s being.31 As
God’s surrogate in this world, a Muslim is not a totally free agent but is circumscribed by
religious principles—by a code of conduct for interpersonal relations—in social and economic
activities. Religion is paramount in all areas of life. The Muslim lives in a social structure
that is shaped by Islamic values and norms of moral conduct. The ritual nature of everyday
life in a Muslim country is striking to a Western visitor. Among other things, orthodox
Muslim ritual requires prayer five times a day (business meetings may be put on hold while
Muslim participants engage in their daily prayer ritual), requires that women should dress
in a certain manner and forbids the consumption of pork and alcohol.
CHAPTER 5
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd 223
DIFFERENCES IN CULTURE
223
08/06/19 07:50 PM
ARC
ARCTIC
CTIC
OCEAN
OCE
EAN
ARCTIC
OCEAN
J
J
J
Predominant Religions
J
J
M
J
M
ATLAN
A
NTIC
ATLANTIC
OCE
O
EAN
N
OCEAN
Christianity (C)*
Roman Catholic
Protestant
M
C
H
Eastern churches
HM
H
M
Mixed sects
Islam (M)
Sunni
PACIFIC
ACIFIC
OCEAN
OC
CEAN
Shi’a
Buddhism (B)
Hinayanistic
C
M
Hinduism (H)
M
H
C
C
C
M
C
PAC
CIFIC
C
PACIFIC
OC
CEAN
N
OCEAN
C
IND
DIAN
INDIAN
EAN
EAN
N
OCEAN
C
J
H
Lamaistic
M
B
Mormon (LDS)
J
Judaism (J)
Sikhism
Animism (tribal)
Chinese complex
(Confucianism, Taoism, and
Buddhism)
Korean complex
(Buddhism, Confucianism,
Christianity, and Chondogyo)
Japanese complex
(Shinto and Buddhism)
Vietnamese complex
(Buddhism, Taoism,
Confucianism, and Cao Dai)
Unpopulated regions
* Capital letters indicate the presence of
locally important minority adherents of
nonpredominant faiths.
0
Scale: 1 to 190,080,000
0
1000
1000
2000
2000 Miles
3000 Kilometers
MAP 5.1
Predominant world religions
Source: ‘Map 14’, in J. L. Allen and C. J. Sutton, Student Atlas of World Politics, 10th ed. New York, NY: McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., 2013.
ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
RELIGIOUS FUNDAMENTALISM
The past three decades have witnessed the growth of
religious fundamentalism. While some may associate
religious fundamentalism with a social movement
often referred to as Islamic fundamentalism,32 religious
extremism is not confined to Islam. For example, we
have witnessed extreme Christian, Hindu and Buddhist
movements such as the attacks directed against the
224
PART 3
Rohingya Muslims in Myanmar by so-called Buddhists,
who hijacked the peace-loving religion to justify their
violence.
In the West, Islamic fundamentalism is associated
with violence—with militants, terrorists and violent
upheavals, such as the activities of Islamic State (IS) in
COUNTRY DIFFERENCES
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd
224
08/06/19 07:50 PM
recent years, the 11 September 2001 attacks on the
World Trade Center and the Pentagon in the United
States, the 2002 and 2005 Bali bombings, the London
attacks, the Nice attack in France and various terror
attacks in Sri Lanka. However, this association is
misleading. Islamic fundamentalism is perpetrated by
a small minority of radical ‘fundamentalists’ who like
other extremists have hijacked religion to further their
own political and violent ends. The vast majority of
Muslims point out that Islam teaches peace, justice and
tolerance, not violence and intolerance, and that Islam
explicitly repudiates the violence that radical minority
groups such as the Taliban and IS followers practise.
According to the well-known former Pakistani cricketer
and prime minister Imran Khan, many Muslims are
embarrassed by these extreme views and the practices
of extremists.33 Indeed, many Muslims have been killed
by these groups, sometimes in a very brutal manner.
SOURCES: R. Ovendale review of ‘Islam in Revolution: Fundamentalism in the Arab World Second Edition’ by R. Hrair Dekmejian, Digest of Middle East
Studies, 4(4), pp. 32–34; Enough Rope, with Andrew Denton, Episode 13, ABC TV, 13 October 2008, accessed via www.abc.net.au/tv/enoughrope/
transcripts/s2389924.htm; E. Dias, ‘Top Catholic Official in Myanmar Speaks Out on Treatment of Rohingya Muslims and the Risks of a Military Coup’,
Time, 13 September 2017, accessed via http://time.com/4939946/myanmar-rohingya-muslims-pope-francis-envoy on 28 October 2018.
Islamic fundamentalists demand a rigid commitment to traditional religious beliefs
and rituals. The result has been a marked increase in the use of symbolic gestures that
confirm Islamic values. In areas where fundamentalism is strong, women have resumed
wearing floor-length, long-sleeved dresses and covering their hair; religious studies have
increased in universities; the publication of religious tracts has increased; and the number
of public religious orations has risen.34 The sentiments of some fundamentalist groups are
increasingly anti-Western: rightly or wrongly, Western influence is blamed for a range of
social ills and many fundamentalists’ actions are directed against Western governments,
cultural symbols, businesses and even individuals.
In several Muslim countries, fundamentalists have gained political power and have used
this to try to make Islamic law (as set down in the Koran, the holy book of Islam) the law of
the land. There are grounds for this in Islam. Islam is not just a religion: it is also the source
of law, a guide to statecraft and an arbiter of social behaviour. Muslims believe that every
human endeavour is within the purview of the faith—and this includes political activity—
because the only purpose of any activity is to do God’s will.35 Muslim fundamentalists
have been most successful in Iran, where a fundamentalist party has held power since 1979,
but they have also had an influence in many other countries, such as Algeria, Afghanistan
(where the Taliban established an extreme fundamentalist state until it was removed by the
US-led coalition in 2002), Egypt, Pakistan, the Sudan and Saudi Arabia.
Economic implications of Islam
The Koran establishes some explicit economic principles, many of which are pro–free
enterprise.36 The Koran speaks approvingly of free enterprise and of earning legitimate
profit through trade and commerce. (The Prophet Muhammad was once a merchant.) The
protection of the right to private property is also embedded within Islam, although Islam
asserts that all property is a favour from God, who created and so owns everything. Those
who hold property are regarded as trustees, rather than as owners in the Western sense
of the word. As trustees they are entitled to receive profits from the property but are
admonished to use it in a righteous, socially beneficial and prudent manner. This reflects
Islam’s concern with social justice. Islam is critical of those who earn profit through the
exploitation of others. In the Islamic view of the world, humans are part of a collective in
which the wealthy and successful have obligations to help the disadvantaged. Put simply,
in Muslim countries, it is fine to earn a profit, so long as that profit is justly earned and
CHAPTER 5
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd 225
LO 5.3
DIFFERENCES IN CULTURE
225
08/06/19 07:50 PM
not based on the exploitation of others for one’s own advantage. It also helps if those
making profits undertake charitable acts to help the poor. Furthermore, Islam stresses the
importance of living up to contractual obligations, of keeping one’s word and of abstaining
from deception.
Given the Islamic proclivity to favour market-based systems, Muslim countries are
likely to be receptive to international businesses as long as those businesses behave in a
manner that is consistent with Islamic ethics. For example, consider the Chapter 5 Closing
Case; the managers of Cognition Consulting will have to be very mindful of the strong
influence that Islam has within the business culture of country markets such as Dubai and
the United Arab Emirates.
The economic principle of Islam prohibits the payment or receipt of interest, which is
considered usury. This is not just a matter of theology; in several Islamic states, it is also
becoming a matter of law, as Emerging Markets: ‘Islamic banking in Malaysia’ illustrates.
The rise of Islamic banking
RIBA
Arabic for ‘interest’ and/or ‘usury’
226
PART 3
Financial experts from Islamic countries have argued that the Islamic banking system
shielded them from the Global Financial Crisis. What is Islamic banking? How is it different
from conventional banking?
Islamic banking has a similar role to conventional banking, except that Islamic banking
activity must comply with the principles of the Islamic rulings (Shari’ah), specifically Islamic
rules on transactions known as Fiqh al-Muamalat.
The Koran clearly condemns interest, which is called riba in Arabic, as exploitative and
unjust. For many years, banks operating in Islamic countries conveniently ignored this
condemnation, but starting about 30 years ago with the establishment of an Islamic bank
in Egypt, Islamic banks started to open in predominantly Muslim countries. There are more
than 200 Islamic financial institutions worldwide, and it is expected that assets managed
by these institutions will grow to around US$4 trillion by 2020. Even conventional banks
are entering the market—both Citigroup and HSBC, two of the world’s largest financial
institutions, now offer Islamic financial services. While only Iran and the Sudan enforce
Islamic banking conventions, in an increasing number of countries customers can choose
between conventional banks and Islamic banks, such as in Malaysia and Pakistan.
Conventional banks make a profit on the spread between the interest rate they have
to pay to depositors and the higher interest rate they charge borrowers. Because Islamic
banks cannot pay or charge interest, they must find a different way of making money.
Islamic banks have experimented with two different banking methods—the mudarabah
and the murabaha.
A mudarabah contract is similar to a profit-sharing scheme. Under mudarabah, when an
Islamic bank lends money to a business, rather than charging that business interest on the
loan, it takes a share in the profits that are derived from the investment. Similarly, when a
business (or individual) deposits money at an Islamic bank in a savings account, the deposit
is treated as an equity investment in whatever activity the bank uses the capital for. Thus,
the depositor receives a share in the profit from the bank’s investment (as opposed to
interest payments) according to an agreed-on ratio. Some Muslims claim this is a more
efficient and ethical system than the Western banking system, since it encourages both
long-term savings and long-term investment. However, some believe that a mudarabah
system is less efficient than a conventional Western banking system.
The second Islamic banking method, the murabaha contract, is the most widely used
among the world’s Islamic banks, primarily because it is the easiest to implement. In a
murabaha contract, when a company wishes to purchase something using a loan—let’s say a
piece of equipment that costs $1000—the company tells the bank after having negotiated
the price with the equipment manufacturer. The bank then buys the equipment for $1000,
COUNTRY DIFFERENCES
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd
226
08/06/19 07:50 PM
EMERGING MARKETS
ISLAMIC BANKING IN MALAYSIA
© Patrick Foto/Shutterstock
In 1993 Malaysia became the first country to offer a
dual banking system with the introduction of the
Islamic Banking Scheme, allowing existing banks and
other financial institutions to offer Islamic banking
services. Nowadays, in multicultural Malaysia, Islamic
banking is widely used by both Muslims and nonMuslims. In 2002 Malaysia
pioneered the issuance of
SUKUK
Islamic bonds, called sukuk.
A type of Islamic bond
In the West, many US and
British banks are setting up subsidiaries to offer Islamic
banking, while Australian banks are also considering
offering these services.
Malaysia pioneered a dual banking system with the
introduction of an Islamic Banking Scheme.
SOURCES: ‘Forced devotion’, The Economist, 17 February 2001, pp. 76–7; ‘Islamic banking marches on’, The Banker, 1 February 2000; F. Bokhari,
‘Bankers fear introduction of Islamic system will prompt big withdrawals’, Financial Times, 6 March 2001, p. 4; ‘Islamic banking booms in Pakistan’,
Agence France Presse, January 2005; D. Oakley, ‘BLME grows despite crunch’, Financial Times, 8 September 2008; and R. Brant, ‘Is Islamic finance
the answer?’, BBC News, accessed via http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/business/8025410.stm on 12 June 2009; AMEinfo.com, ‘Value of assets managed by
global Islamic banks expected to touch Dhs14.6 trillion by 2020’, accessed via www.ameinfo.com/233174.html on 25 July 2012; The Economist online,
Islamic Finance, 10 April 2012; E.M.R. Abdullah, ‘Development of Islamic banking in Malaysia’, KLRCA News Letter, accessed via www.ridzalaw.com.my/
downloads/2011-klrca_newsletter.pdf; Institute of Islamic Banking and Insurance, accessed via www.islamic-banking.com/what_is_ibanking.aspx on 10
March 2015; Daria Solovieva, ‘Get ready for corporate sukuk boom after sovereign rush’, accessed via www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2015-01-05/
get-ready-for-company-boom-after-sovereign-rush-islamic-finance on 15 March 2015.
and the borrower buys it back from the bank at some later date for, say, $1100, a price
that includes a $100 mark-up for the bank. A cynic might point out that such a mark-up is
functionally equivalent to an interest payment, and it is the similarity between this method
and conventional banking that makes it so much easier to adopt.
Hinduism
LO 5.2
Hinduism has approximately 875 million adherents, most of them on the Indian
subcontinent. Hinduism began in the Indus Valley in India more than 4000 years ago,
making it the world’s oldest major religion. Unlike Christianity and Islam, its founding is
not linked to a particular person. Nor does it have an officially sanctioned sacred book
such as the Bible or the Koran. Hindus believe that a moral force in society, called dharma,
requires the acceptance of certain responsibilities. Hindus believe in reincarnation, or
rebirth into a different body, after death. Hindus also believe in karma, the spiritual
progression of each person’s soul. A person’s karma is affected by the way he or she lives.
The moral state of an individual’s karma determines the challenges he or she will face in
CHAPTER 5
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd 227
DIFFERENCES IN CULTURE
227
08/06/19 07:50 PM
the next life. By perfecting the soul in each new life, Hindus believe that an individual
can eventually achieve nirvana, a state of complete spiritual perfection that renders
reincarnation no longer necessary. Many Hindus believe that the way to achieve nirvana
is to lead a severe ascetic lifestyle of material and physical self-denial, devoting life to a
spiritual rather than material quest.
One of the interesting aspects of Hindu culture is the reverence for the cow, which
Hindus see as a gift of the gods to the human race. The sacred status of the cow created
some unique problems for McDonald’s when it entered India in the 1990s, since devout
Hindus do not eat beef (and many are also vegetarians). McDonald’s dealt with that
challenge by adapting the original menu to create an Indian version of its Big Mac—the
‘Maharaja Mac’—created from mutton. Other additions to the menu also conform to local
sensibilities—such as the ‘McAloo Tikki Burger’, which is made from chicken. All foods are
strictly segregated into vegetarian and non-vegetarian lines to conform with preferences in
a country where many Hindus are vegetarian.37
© Christopher Kerrigan/McGraw-Hill
ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
ADAPTING TO SUIT THE LOCAL PALATE
In Hong Kong, McDonald’s serves Rice Fan-tastic,
substituting rice patties for buns.
Food is an integral part of many cultures. Hindus in
India do not eat the meat of the sacred cow. Muslims
and Jews do not eat pork. McDonald’s responded to
these cultural food dilemmas by adapting the menu
to suit the local palate and other local sensibilities.
In India, McDonald’s foods are strictly segregated
into vegetarian and non-vegetarian lines to conform
with preferences in a country where many Hindus are
vegetarian. In predominantly Islamic countries such
as Malaysia and Indonesia, foods are halal compliant.
In Israel, around 50 of the McDonald’s restaurants are
kosher in keeping with Jewish traditions. In Sri Lanka,
where people have a taste for fiery hot chilli, locals can
enjoy a ‘Seeni Sambol’ burger (with a filling of onions
fried with chillies) or Curry N Rice.
SOURCES: ‘About us’, McDonald’s, www.mcdonalds.co.il/About_McDonalds, accessed on 2 March 2015; McDonald’s India, www.mcdonaldsindia.com/
menu.html, accessed on 31 July 2012; McDonald’s delivery, www.mcdelivery.lk/lk/browse/menu.html, accessed on 29 October 2018.
Economic implications of Hinduism
LO 5.3
228
PART 3
Devout Hindus perceive the pursuit of material wellbeing as making the attainment of
nirvana more difficult.
Mahatma Gandhi, the famous Indian nationalist and spiritual leader, was certainly
the embodiment of Hindu asceticism. It has been argued that the values of Hindu
asceticism and self-reliance that Gandhi advocated had a negative impact on the economic
development of post-independence India.38 But one must be careful not to read too much
COUNTRY DIFFERENCES
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd
228
08/06/19 07:50 PM
into this argument. Modern India is a very dynamic, entrepreneurial society, and millions
of hardworking entrepreneurs form the economic backbone of the country’s rapidly
growing economy.
Historically, Hinduism also supported India’s caste system. The concept of mobility
between castes within an individual’s lifetime makes no sense to traditional Hindus. Hindus
see mobility between castes as something that is achieved through spiritual progression
and reincarnation. An individual can be reborn into a higher caste in his or her next life
if he or she achieves spiritual development in this life. In so far as the caste system limits
individuals’ opportunities to adopt positions of responsibility and influence in society,
the economic consequences of this religious belief are somewhat negative. For example,
within a business organisation, the most able individuals may find their route to the higher
levels of the organisation blocked simply because they come from a lower caste. By the
same token, individuals may get promoted to higher positions within a company as much
because of their caste background as because of their ability.
Buddhism
LO 5.2
Economic implications of Buddhism
The emphasis on wealth creation that is embedded in Protestantism is not found in
Buddhism. However, Buddhism does not discourage ethical business practices, only the
five forms of trades that are to be avoided: trading in arms, in living beings, flesh (breeding
of animals for slaughter), intoxicating drinks and poisons.39 In addition, countries where
Mahayana Buddhism is practised have been strongly influenced by local deities, ancestor
worship and Confucian ethics, providing a more conducive environment for business. For
example, at the Baolian Temple in the city of Xuzhou in southern China there is high
patronage by local businesspeople praying for wealth and prosperity.
CHAPTER 5
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd 229
© Rumintha Wickramasekera
Buddhism is not a religion in the strict sense. Buddhism was founded in India in the
6th century BC by Siddhartha Gautama, an Indian prince who renounced his wealth to
pursue an ascetic lifestyle and spiritual perfection. Siddhartha achieved nirvana but decided
to spend the remainder of his life to teach his followers how
they too could achieve this state of spiritual enlightenment.
Siddhartha became known as the Buddha (which means ‘the
awakened one’). Today, Buddhism has around 500 million
followers. There are two main Buddhist sects, Theravada and
Mahayana. Theravada Buddhism is practised predominantly
in Sri Lanka, Cambodia, Thailand, Laos and Myanmar, while
Mahayana Buddhism is practised in China, Taiwan, Korea and
Japan.
According to Buddhism, suffering originates in people’s
desires for pleasure. Cessation of suffering can be achieved
by following a path for transformation. The Buddha offered
the Noble Eight-fold Path as a route for transformation. This
emphasises right seeing, thinking, speech, action, living,
effort, mindfulness and meditation. Unlike Hinduism,
Buddhism does not support the caste system. Nor does
Buddhism advocate the kind of extreme ascetic behaviour
The Baolian Temple in Southern China is indicative of a
that is encouraged by Hinduism. Nevertheless, like Hindus,
fusion of beliefs.
Buddhists stress the afterlife and spiritual achievement
rather than involvement in this world.
LO 5.3
DIFFERENCES IN CULTURE
229
08/06/19 07:50 PM
Confucianism
LO 5.2
Confucianism was founded in the 5th century BC by K’ung-Fu-tzu, more generally
known in Western countries as Confucius. Until the 1949 Communist revolution,
Confucianism was the official ethical system of China for more than 2000 years. While
observance of Confucian ethics has been weakened in China since 1949, more than
400 million people still follow the teachings of Confucius (in conjunction with local
beliefs and/or Buddhism),40 principally in China, Korea and Japan. Confucianism teaches
the importance of attaining personal salvation through right action. Although not a
religion, Confucian ideology has become deeply embedded in the culture of these
countries over the centuries and, through that, has an impact on the lives of many
millions more. Confucianism is built around a comprehensive ethical code that sets down
guidelines for relationships with others. High moral and ethical conduct and loyalty to
others are central to Confucianism. Unlike religions, Confucianism is not concerned with
the supernatural and has little to say about the concept of a supreme being or an afterlife.
Economic implications of Confucianism
LO 5.3
230
PART 3
Some scholars maintain that Confucianism may have economic implications as profound
as those Max Weber argued were to be found in Protestantism, although they are of
a different nature.41 Their basic thesis is that the influence of Confucian ethics on the
cultures of China, Japan, South Korea and Taiwan, by lowering the costs of doing business
in those countries, may help to explain their economic success. In this regard, three values
central to the Confucian system of ethics are of particular interest: loyalty, reciprocal
obligations and honesty in dealings with others.
In Confucian thought, loyalty to one’s superiors is regarded as a sacred duty—an absolute
obligation. In modern organisations based on Confucian cultures, the loyalty that binds
employees to the heads of their organisation can reduce the conflict between management
and labour that we find in more class-conscious societies. Cooperation between
management and labour can be achieved at a lower cost in a culture where the virtue of
loyalty is emphasised in the value system.
However, in a Confucian culture, loyalty to one’s superiors, such as a worker’s loyalty
to management, is not blind loyalty. The concept of reciprocal obligations is important.
Confucian ethics stress that superiors are obliged to reward the loyalty of their subordinates
by bestowing blessings on them. If these ‘blessings’ are not forthcoming, then neither will
be the loyalty. This Confucian ethic is central to the Chinese concept of guanxi, which
refers to relationship networks supported by reciprocal obligations (which we discuss in
the Management Focus: ‘DMG Entertainment’).42 Guanxi means ‘relationships’, although
in business settings it can be better understood as ‘connections’. Today, Chinese will often
cultivate a guanxiwang, or ‘relationship network’, for help. Reciprocal obligations are the glue
that holds such networks together. If those obligations are not met—if favours done are not
paid back or reciprocated—the reputation of the transgressor is tarnished and the person will
be less able to draw on his or her guanxiwang for help in the future. Thus, the implicit threat
of social sanctions is often sufficient to ensure that favours are repaid, obligations are met and
relationships are honoured. In a society that lacks a rule-based legal tradition, and thus legal
ways of redressing wrongs such as violations of business agreements, guanxi is an important
mechanism for building long-term business relationships and getting business done in China.
A third concept found in Confucian ethics is the importance attached to honesty.
Confucian thinkers emphasise that, although dishonest behaviour may yield short-term
benefits for the transgressor, dishonesty does not pay in the long run. The importance
attached to honesty has major economic implications. When companies can trust each
other not to break contractual obligations, the costs of doing business are lowered as
expensive lawyers are not needed to resolve contract disputes. In a Confucian society,
COUNTRY DIFFERENCES
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd
230
08/06/19 07:50 PM
people may be less hesitant to commit substantial resources to cooperative ventures than
in a society where honesty is less pervasive. When companies adhere to Confucian ethics,
they can trust each other not to violate the terms of cooperative agreements. Thus, the
costs of achieving cooperation between companies may be lower in societies such as Japan
relative to societies where trust is less pervasive.
For example, it has been argued that the close ties between the automobile companies
and their component parts suppliers in Japan are facilitated by a combination of trust
and reciprocal obligations. These close ties allow the auto companies and their suppliers
to work together on a range of issues, including inventory reduction, quality control and
design. The competitive advantage of Japanese auto companies such as Toyota may in part
be explained by such factors.43 Similarly, as we will see in the Management Focus, the
combination of trust and reciprocal obligations is central to the workings and persistence of
guanxi networks in China. Someone seeking and receiving help through a guanxi network
is then obligated to return the favour and faces social sanctions if that obligation is not
reciprocated when it is called upon. If the person does not return the favour, his or her
reputation will be tarnished and he or she will be unable to draw on the resources of the
network in the future. It is claimed that these relationship-based networks can be more
important in helping to enforce agreements between businesses than the Chinese legal
system. Some claim that guanxi networks are a substitute for the legal system.44
SUPERSTITIONS
LO 5.2
Like religion, superstitions play an important role in the daily life of people as well as
impacting on how business is conducted. The 5000-year-old Chinese culture is rich in
traditions and superstitions. Numbers play a particularly important role for the Chinese,
with their faith in lucky numbers influencing daily life, from choosing a car number plate,
to a phone number, house or apartment number.45
MANAGEMENT FOCUS
DMG ENTERTAINMENT
In 1993, New Yorker Dan Mintz moved to China as a
freelance film director with no contacts, no advertising
experience and no Mandarin skills. By 2015, DMG,
the company he subsequently founded in China
in 2003, had emerged as one of China’s fastestgrowing advertising and entertainment agencies,
with a multicultural staff of 800 and offices in Beijing,
Shanghai, Changchun, Hangzhou, Chengdu and Los
Angeles. DMG’s clients include Budweiser, Unilever,
Sony, Nabisco, Audi, Volkswagen, Nike, Google, China
Mobile and dozens of other Chinese brands. In recent
years DMG facilitated multimillion-dollar co-productions
between China and Hollywood such as Iron Man 3
and Valiant Entertainment’s suit of superheroes to be
showcased in China and beyond. Mintz attributes his
success to understanding the Chinese culture and in
part to what the Chinese call guanxi.
Guanxi literally means relationships, although in
business settings it can be better understood as
connections. Guanxi has its roots in the Confucian
philosophy of valuing social hierarchy and reciprocal
obligations. Confucian ideology has a 2000-yearold history in China. It stresses the importance of
relationships, both within the family and between
master and servant. Confucian ideology teaches that
CHAPTER 5
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd 231
DIFFERENCES IN CULTURE
231
08/06/19 07:50 PM
people are not created equal. In Confucian thought,
loyalty and obligations to one’s superiors (or to family)
are regarded as a sacred duty, but at the same time,
this loyalty has its price. Social superiors are obligated
to reward the loyalty of their social inferiors by
bestowing ‘blessings’ upon them; thus, the obligations
are reciprocal. Chinese people will often cultivate a
guanxiwang, or ‘relationship network’, for help. There
is a tacit acknowledgment that if you have the right
guanxi, legal rules can be broken, or at least bent.
Mintz, who is now fluent in Mandarin, cultivated his
guanxiwang by going into business with two young
Chinese associates who had connections, Bing Wu
and Peter Xiao. Wu, who works on the production side
of the business, was a former national gymnastics
champion, which translates into prestige and access
to business and government officials. Xiao comes
from a military family with major political connections.
Together, these three have been able to open doors
that long-established Western advertising agencies
could not. They have done it in large part by leveraging
the contacts of Wu and Xiao and by backing up their
connections with what the Chinese call shi li, the ability
to do good work.
A case in point was DMG’s campaign for Volkswagen,
which helped the German company become ubiquitous
in China. The ads used traditional Chinese characters,
which had been banned by Chairman Mao during the
cultural revolution in favour of simplified versions. To
get permission to use the characters in film and print
ads—a first in modern China—the trio had to draw on
high-level government contacts in Beijing. They won
over officials by arguing that the old characters should
be thought of not as ‘characters’ but as art. Later, they
shot TV spots for the ad on Shanghai’s famous Bund,
a congested boulevard that runs along the waterfront
of the old city. Drawing again on government contacts,
they were able to shut down the Bund to make the
shoot. Steven Spielberg had been able to close down
only a portion of the street when he filmed Empire
of the Sun there in 1986. DMG has also filmed inside
Beijing’s Forbidden City, even though it is against the
law to do so. Using his contacts, Mintz persuaded
the government to lift the law for 24 hours. As Mintz
has noted, ‘We don’t stop when we come across
regulations. There are restrictions everywhere you
go. You have to know how to get around them and get
things done’.
While it began as an advertising agency in 1993, the
company started distributing non-Chinese movies
in the Chinese market in the late 2000s as well as
producing Chinese films, the first being The Founding
of a Republic in 2009. This is a movie that marked the
60th anniversary of the People’s Republic of China.
The company was split up in 2014. Today, DMG is a
Chinese-based production and distribution company.
The China component of DMG (renamed Yingin)
retained the marketing, Chinese film distribution and
other local activities. Later the company was listed on
the Shenzhen Stock Exchange with co-founder Xiao
appointed as chairman. However, Mintz could not hold
an executive position in the company due to Chinese
laws and returned to the United States to run DMG’s
privately held unit based from Los Angeles.
While strong connections and enjoying guanxi in China
are important in facilitating business activities, there is
a limit to what foreigners and Chinese nationals alike
can achieve via guanxi. Businesspeople operating in
China must be mindful of these limitations.
SOURCES: J. Bryan, ‘The Mintz dynasty’, Fast Company, April 2006, pp. 56–62; M. Graser, ‘Featured player’, Variety, 18 October 2004, p. 6; C. Coonan,
‘DMG’s Dan Mintz: Hollywood’s man in China’, Variety, 5 June 2013, accessed 7 March 2014; S. Montlake, ‘Hollywood’s Mr China: Dan Mintz, DMG’,
Forbes, accessed via www.forbes.com/sites/simonmontlake/2012/08/29/hollywoods-mr-china-dan-mintz-dmg/3 on 12 March 2015; ‘DMG and Valiant
to Bring Largest Independent Superhero Universe to Movie Theaters Worldwide’, DMG, 9 March 2015, accessed via www.dmg-entertainment.com/
dmg-valiant-bring-largest-independent-superhero-universe-movie-theaters-worldwide on 14 March 2015; P. Brzeski, ‘DMG Entertainment’s Chinese
Affiliate Crashes on Shenzhen Stock Exchange’, The Hollywood reporter, 20 August 2018, accessed via www.hollywoodreporter.com/news/dmgentertainments-chinese-affiliate-crashes-shenzhen-stock-exchange-1135580 on 28 October 2018.
It is no coincidence that the Beijing Olympics started at 8pm on 8 August 2008
(8/8/08). The number eight is considered lucky or associated with wealth. (‘Eight’ in
Chinese is pronounced in a similar manner to the word for making money, ba.)
Other lucky numbers include six and nine; six is associated with things going smoothly
or happiness, and nine conveys everlasting or long life. The meanings behind other numbers
include: one—guaranteed; two—easy; three—life. In general, these numbers are considered
good, and it is not surprising to find that some Chinese will value or pay a premium for items
232
PART 3
COUNTRY DIFFERENCES
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd
232
08/06/19 07:50 PM
containing lucky numbers. For example, a Hong Kong tycoon paid HK$13 million (AU$2.16
million) for a number ‘9’ for his car number plate,46 and a £50 bank note with the serial
number AA01 000888 sold for over £800.47
In contrast, the number four is generally avoided. ‘Four’ sounds similar to the Chinese
and Korean words for ‘death’ and is thus considered inauspicious.
Superstitions are not confined to the Chinese; many cultures have these beliefs. Think
of the number 13 in Australia and many Western countries—lucky for some, unlucky for
others. To be successful, international businesses must become familiar with local beliefs
and customs and endeavour to accommodate them. For example, Swiss watchmakers
accommodate the belief in parts of Asia that the number four is unlucky by numbering a
limited edition of five watches for that market 0, 1, 2, 3 and 5.48
LANGUAGE
LO 5.2
One obvious way in which countries differ is language. By language, we mean both the
spoken and the unspoken means of communication. Language is one of the defining
characteristics of a culture.
Spoken language
Language does far more than just enable people to communicate with one
another. The nature of a language also structures the way we perceive the
world. The language of a society can direct the attention of its members to
certain features of the world rather than others. The classic illustration of
this phenomenon is that whereas the English language has just one word for
snow, the language of the Inuit (Eskimos) lacks a general term for it. Instead,
because distinguishing different forms of snow is so important in the lives of
the Inuit, they have several words that describe different types of snow (e.g.
powder snow, falling snow, wet snow, drifting snow).49
Because language shapes the way people perceive the world, it also
helps to define culture. Countries with more than one language often
have more than one culture. Canada has an English-speaking culture and
a French-speaking culture. Tensions between the two can run quite high,
with a substantial proportion of the French-speaking minority demanding
independence from a Canada ‘dominated by English speakers’. The same
phenomenon can be observed in many other countries. Belgium is divided
into Flemish and French speakers, and tensions between the two groups exist;
in Spain, a Basque-speaking minority with its own distinctive culture has been
agitating for independence from the Spanish-speaking majority for decades; on
the Mediterranean island of Cyprus, the culturally diverse Greek and Turkishspeaking populations of the island engaged in open conflict in the 1970s, and
the island is now partitioned into two. While it does not necessarily follow
that language differences create differences in culture and, therefore, separatist
The fourth and thirteenth floors are missing
pressures (witness the harmony in Switzerland, where four languages are
from this hotel in Taiwan as patrons
spoken), there certainly seems to be a tendency in this direction.50
consider them to be inauspicious numbers.
Chinese (Mandarin) is the mother tongue of the largest number of people,
followed by English and Hindi, which is spoken in India. However, the most widely spoken
language in the world is English, followed by French, Spanish and Chinese (i.e. many people
LINGUA FRANCA
speak English as a second language). English is the lingua franca of international business.
A language widely used by
When Japanese and German businesspeople get together to do business, it is almost certain
non-native speakers
that they will communicate in English. Although English is widely used, learning the local
CHAPTER 5
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd 233
DIFFERENCES IN CULTURE
233
08/06/19 07:50 PM
© Rumintha Wickramasekera
LO 5.3
© ILYA AKINSHIN/Shutterstock
language yields considerable advantages. Most people prefer to converse
in their own language, and being able to speak the local language
can build rapport, which may be very important for a business deal.
International businesses that do not understand the local language can
make major blunders through improper translation. For example, the
Sunbeam Corporation used the English words for its ‘Mist-Stick’ mistproducing hair curling iron when it entered the German market, only
to discover after an expensive advertising campaign that mist means
‘excrement’ in German. General Motors was troubled by the lack of
enthusiasm among Puerto Rican dealers for its new Chevrolet Nova.
When literally translated into Spanish, nova means ‘star’. However, when
spoken it sounds like ‘no va’, which in Spanish means ‘it doesn’t go’.
General Motors changed the name of the car to Caribe.51
United States
It’s fine
Germany
Lunatic
Greece, Turkey
An obscene symbol for a
bodily orifice
Unspoken language
Unspoken language refers to non-verbal communication. We all
communicate with each other by a host of non-verbal cues. The
Japan
Money, especially change
raising of eyebrows, for example, is a sign of recognition in many
cultures, while a smile is a sign of joy. Many non-verbal cues, however,
FIGURE 5.2
are culturally bound. A failure to understand the non-verbal cues of
Kinesics: gestures are not universal. This common gesture has
different meanings internationally.
another culture can lead to a communication failure. For example, as
highlighted in Figure 5.2, making a circle with the thumb and the forefinger is a friendly
gesture in the United States, but it is a vulgar sexual invitation in Greece and Turkey,
and means ‘lunatic’ in Germany, ‘zero’ or ‘worthless’ in France, and ‘money’ or ‘change’
in Japan.52 Similarly, while most Americans and Europeans use the thumbs-up gesture to
LO 5.2
indicate that ‘it’s all right’, in Greece the gesture is obscene.
France
Zero, or worthless
Conducting research across cultural borders is difficult
for many reasons. First, there are the more obvious
issues connected to travel and building collaborative
relationships in other countries, both of which are
time-consuming and always full of surprises. One of
the most difficult issues, though, is how to be certain
that the concept about which you want to communicate
has a similar meaning when it crosses a cultural border.
This challenge is more than one of word translation; it
is concept translation, which researchers term concept
equivalence. Take the concept of bribery. Does it have
the same meaning in the middle of Sydney, Auckland or
Manhattan as it does in an underdeveloped, centralised
economy such as North Korea? What do you think?
234
PART 3
© Ingram Publishing
ANOTHER PERSPECTIVE
STICKY PROBLEMS IN CULTURE RESEARCH
COUNTRY DIFFERENCES
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd
234
08/06/19 07:50 PM
Another aspect of non-verbal communication is personal space, which is the comfortable
amount of distance between you and someone you are talking with. In Australia and the
United States, the customary distance apart adopted by parties in a business discussion
is around two metres. In Latin America, it is around a metre to a metre and a half.
Consequently, many Australians and North Americans unconsciously feel that Latin
Americans are invading their personal space and can be seen backing away from them
during a conversation. Indeed, Australians and Americans may feel that Latin Americans are
being aggressive and pushy. In turn, Latin Americans may interpret such backing away as
aloofness. The result can be a regrettable lack of rapport between two businesspeople from
different cultures.
EDUCATION
LO 5.3
Formal education plays a key role in a society. Formal education is the medium through
which individuals learn many of the language, conceptual and mathematical skills that
are indispensable in a modern society. Formal education also supplements the family’s
role in socialising the young into the values and norms of a society. Values and norms
are taught both directly and indirectly. Schools generally teach basic facts about the
social and political nature of a society. They also focus on the fundamental obligations of
citizenship. In addition, cultural norms are taught indirectly at school. Respect for others,
obedience to authority, honesty, neatness, being on time and so on are all part of the
‘hidden curriculum’ of schools. The use of a grading system also teaches children the value
of personal achievement and competition.53
From an international business perspective, one important aspect of education is its role
as a determinant of national competitive advantage.54 The availability of a pool of skilled
and educated workers seems to be a major determinant of the likely economic success of
a country. In analysing the competitive success of Japan since 1945, for example, Michael
Porter notes that after the war, Japan had almost nothing except for a pool of skilled and
educated human resources:
With a long tradition of respect for education that borders on reverence, Japan possessed
a large pool of literate, educated, and increasingly skilled human resources . . . Japan has
benefited from a large pool of trained engineers.
. . . A first-rate primary and secondary education system in Japan operates based on high
standards and emphasises maths and science. Primary and secondary education is highly
competitive . . . Japanese education provides most students all over Japan with a sound
education for later education and training.55
Porter’s point is that Japan’s excellent education system is an important factor
explaining the country’s postwar economic success. Not only is a good education system
a determinant of national competitive advantage, but it is also an important factor guiding
the location choices of international businesses. The recent trend to outsource information
technology jobs to India, for example, is partly due to the presence of significant numbers
of trained engineers in India, which in turn is a result of the Indian education system.
By the same token, it would make little sense to base production facilities that require
highly skilled labour in a country where the education system was so poor that a skilled
labour pool was not available, no matter how attractive the country might seem on other
dimensions. It might make sense to base production operations that require only unskilled
labour in such a country.
CHAPTER 5
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd 235
DIFFERENCES IN CULTURE
235
08/06/19 07:50 PM
The general education level of a country is also a good index of the kind of products
that might sell in a country and of the type of promotional material that should be used.
For example, a country where more than 70 per cent of the population is illiterate is
unlikely to be a good market for popular books. Promotional material containing written
descriptions of mass-marketed products is unlikely to have an effect in a country where
almost three-quarters of the population cannot read. It is far better to use pictorial
promotions in such circumstances.
CULTURE AND THE WORKPLACE
LO 5.4
Of considerable importance for an international business with operations in different
countries is how a society’s culture affects the values found in the workplace. Management
processes and practices may need to vary according to culturally determined workrelated values. For example, if the cultures of Australia and China result in different workrelated values, an international business with operations in both countries should vary its
management process and practices to account for these differences.
Many researchers have focused on how cultures differ and the impact these differences
have on business. Probably two of the most famous theories were proposed by Edward Hall
and Mildred Hall,56 and by Geert Hofstede.57
Cultural context
LOW-CONTEXT CULTURE
A culture in which the speaker’s
message is conveyed explicitly by
the spoken words
TABLE 5.1 Low- and high-context
cultures
SOURCE: E. Tuleja, ‘An overview of
culture: ethnocentrism’, Intercultural
Communication for Business, Mason, Ohio:
South-Western Cengage Learning, 2009.
Hall and Hall highlighted the cultural differences between countries by using the
concept of context, where context equates to cues and other information present in a
situation such as tone of voice and gestures. They divided the extremes of context into
high and low context with a range in between (see Table 5.1). Most of the individualistic
Western countries such as Australia, New Zealand, the United States, Canada and most of
Western Europe tend to be low-context cultures (see Fig. 5.3). In these countries, explicit
communication is preferred. Most countries in Asia, the Middle East, Latin America
LOW-CONTEXT CULTURES
HIGH-CONTEXT CULTURES
Focus more on completing tasks than on
maintaining relationships
Maintain good relationships and the tasks will
be completed
Use objective data
Subjective elements can be included
Employees expect detailed information
Employees expect superiors to handle details
In general people are addressed informally, with
notable exceptions such as in Germany
People are addressed formally
Executives tend to be given private office spaces
Executives share open office space
Employee’s position/status gives power and
influence
Meetings stick closely to a set agenda
Low context
High context
FIGURE 5.3
Low- and high-context cultures
SOURCE: Constructed by author based
on E. Tuleja, ‘An overview of culture:
ethnocentrism’, Intercultural Communication
for Business, Mason, Ohio: South-Western
Cengage Learning, 2009, pp. 13–16.
236
PART 3
an
rm
Ge
US
n
via
ina
nd
Sca
ian lian nd
n sh
k
a
nad ustra
tish lia
i
eal
Bri Ita Span Gree Arab inese rean nese
A
Z
w
Ch Ko Japa
e
N
an
a
dC
COUNTRY DIFFERENCES
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd
236
08/06/19 07:50 PM
and Africa have high-context cultures. In these countries, people refrain from explicitly
expressing feelings and thoughts, and important information is embedded in the context.58
What does this mean for undertaking business internationally? Australians, Americans
and New Zealanders (low-context cultural background) tend to focus more on completing
tasks than on maintaining relationships, whereas people from high-context cultures (such as
Japanese, Chinese and Koreans) focus on forging and maintaining good relationships to facilitate
the completion of tasks. (In Chapter 10 we will discuss the importance of forging long-term
relationships in ensuring the long-term survival of companies and in reducing business costs.)
In Germany and Switzerland, meetings start promptly, but not in Saudi Arabia or
Mexico, where meetings often begin with lengthy socialising to establish rapport. Be
careful how you say things: Australians, Americans and Western Europeans tend to speak
plainly and in a straightforward manner, but Chinese, Japanese, Koreans, Arabs, Indians and
some Latin Americans are indirect and rely on body language and context to make their
point. And be careful what you say. American and Australian managers describe business
in financial terms (or objective data), whereas in China and Japan subjective elements can
be included in business discussions. A good rule of thumb: pay attention to cues and don’t
assume that your customs are observed everywhere.59
It is good business practice to adapt to your clients’ needs. For example, the general
manager of Jingzhi Co., a manufacturer of quality kitchen cabinets and wardrobes in the
Chinese town of Ronggui,60 has adapted to the needs of his (low-context) Western clients.
They have moved away from the traditional Chinese way of doing business, building
relationships first and business later. ‘In the past we used to take time concluding business
deals, including entertaining our Western business partners. We realised this hospitality
seemed to annoy them. They were in China for a limited time and were keen to conclude
as many deals as possible—“time is money”. Now we accommodate their needs by providing
information prior to their arrival, including on our website. We no longer insist on
socialising or hosting banquets for them.’
One of the most detailed studies of how culture relates to values in the workplace was
undertaken by Geert Hofstede.61 As part of his job as a psychologist working for IBM, Hofstede
collected data on employee attitudes and values for more than 100 000 individuals from 1967 to
1973. These data enabled him to compare dimensions of culture across 40 countries. Hofstede
isolated four dimensions that he claimed summarised different cultures—power distance,
uncertainty avoidance, individualism versus collectivism and masculinity versus femininity.
Hofstede’s power distance dimension focused on how a society deals with the fact that
people are unequal in physical and intellectual capabilities. According to Hofstede, highpower distance cultures were found in countries that let inequalities grow over time into
inequalities of power and wealth. Low-power distance cultures were found in societies that
tried to play down such inequalities as much as possible.
The individualism versus collectivism dimension focused on the relationship between
the individual and his or her fellows. In individualistic societies, the ties between
individuals were loose and individual achievement and freedom were highly valued. In
societies where collectivism was emphasised, the ties between individuals were tight. In
such societies, people were born into collectives, such as extended families, and everyone
was supposed to look after the interest of his or her collective.
Hofstede’s uncertainty avoidance dimension measured the extent to which different
cultures socialised their members into accepting ambiguous situations and tolerating
uncertainty. Members of high uncertainty avoidance cultures placed a premium on job
security, career patterns, retirement benefits, and so on. They also had a strong need
for rules and regulations; the manager was expected to issue clear instructions, and
subordinates’ initiatives were tightly controlled. Lower uncertainty avoidance cultures were
characterised by a greater readiness to take risks and less emotional resistance to change.
CHAPTER 5
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd 237
HIGH-CONTEXT CULTURE
A culture in which the context of a
discussion is as important as the
actual words spoken
POWER DISTANCE
Extent to how much a society
allows inequalities of physical and
intellectual capabilities between
people to grow into inequalities of
power and wealth
INDIVIDUALISM VERSUS
COLLECTIVISM
Extent to which a society teaches
individuals either to prize personal
achievement or conversely to look
after the interests of their collective
first and foremost
UNCERTAINTY AVOIDANCE
Extent to which cultures socialise
members to accept ambiguous
situations and to tolerate uncertainty
DIFFERENCES IN CULTURE
237
08/06/19 07:50 PM
MASCULINITY VERSUS FEMININITY
Extent to which a society
differentiates and emphasises
traditional gender and work roles;
a masculine characterisation
means there is more differentiation,
whereas a feminine level means
there is less
Hofstede’s masculinity versus femininity dimension looked at the relationship between
gender and work roles. In masculine cultures, sex roles were sharply differentiated and
traditional ‘masculine values’, such as achievement and the effective exercise of power,
determined cultural ideals. In feminine cultures, sex roles were less sharply distinguished,
and little differentiation was made between men and women in the same job.
Hofstede created an index score for each of these four dimensions that ranged from
0 to 100 and scored high for high individualism, high-power distance, high uncertainty
avoidance and high masculinity. He averaged the score for all employees from a given
country. Table 5.2 summarises these data for 14 selected countries. Western nations such as
Australia, the United States, New Zealand and Britain score high on the individualism scale
and low on the power distance scale. At the other extreme are a group of Latin American
and Asian countries that emphasise collectivism over individualism and score high on the
power distance scale. Table 5.2 also reveals that Japan’s culture has strong uncertainty
avoidance and high masculinity. This characterisation fits the standard stereotype of Japan
as a country that is male dominant and where uncertainty avoidance exhibits itself in the
institution of lifetime employment. Sweden stands out as a country that has both low
uncertainty avoidance and low masculinity (high emphasis on ‘feminine’ values).
TABLE 5.2 Work-related values for selected countries
COUNTRY
Australia
POWER
DISTANCE
UNCERTAINTY
AVOIDANCE
INDIVIDUALISM
MASCULINITY
LONG-TERM
ORIENTATION
36
51
90
61
31
Brazil
69
76
38
49
65
China
80
30
20
66
118
Germany
35
65
67
66
31
Great Britain
35
35
89
66
25
India
77
40
48
56
61
Japan
54
92
46
95
80
New Zealand
22
49
79
58
30
Nigeria
80
55
30
60
16
Russia
93
95
39
36
–
Singapore
74
8
20
48
48
Sweden
31
29
71
5
33
Thailand
64
64
20
35
56
United States
40
46
91
62
29
SOURCES: G. Hofstede, ‘The business of international business is culture’, International Business Review, 3(1) (1994);
data for Singapore and New Zealand derived from T.C. Garrett, D.H. Buisson and C.M. Yap, ‘National culture and R&D
and marketing integration mechanisms in new product development: a cross-cultural study between Singapore and
New Zealand’, Industrial Marketing Management, 35 (2006), pp. 293–307; G. Hofstede, G.J. Hofstede and M. Minkov,
Cultures and Organizations: Software for the Mind, 3rd ed, New York, NY: McGraw-Hill Professional Publishing (2010).
Hofstede’s results are interesting for what they tell us in a very general way about
differences between cultures. Many of Hofstede’s findings are consistent with standard
Western stereotypes about cultural differences. For example, many people believe
Australians are more individualistic and egalitarian than the Japanese (Australians have a
lower power distance), who in turn are more individualistic and egalitarian than Brazilians
or Indians. Similarly, many might agree that Japanese place a higher emphasis on masculine
values than the Nordic countries of Denmark and Sweden.
However, one should be careful about reading too much into Hofstede’s research. It has
been criticised on a number of points.62 First, Hofstede assumes there is a one-to-one
238
PART 3
COUNTRY DIFFERENCES
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd
238
08/06/19 07:50 PM
correspondence between culture and the nation-state but, as we saw earlier, many
countries have more than one culture. Hofstede’s results do not capture this distinction.
Second, the research may have been culturally bound. The research team was composed of
Europeans and Americans. The questions they asked of IBM employees and their analysis of
the answers may have been shaped by their own cultural biases and concerns. So, it is not
surprising that Hofstede’s results confirm Western stereotypes, because it was Westerners
who undertook the research.
Third, Hofstede’s informants worked not only within a single industry, the computer
industry, but also within one company, IBM. At the time, IBM was renowned for its own
strong corporate culture and employee selection procedures, making it possible that the
employees’ values were different in important respects from the values of the cultures from
which those employees came. Also, certain social classes (such as unskilled manual workers)
were excluded from Hofstede’s sample.
Still, just as it should not be accepted without question, Hofstede’s work should not be
dismissed either. It represents a good starting point for managers trying to figure out how
cultures differ and what that might mean for management practices. Also, several other
scholars have found strong evidence that differences in culture affect values and practices
in the workplace, and Hofstede’s basic results have been replicated using more diverse
samples of individuals in different settings.63 In addition, Hofstede’s work has evolved over
time with the addition of further dimensions.64
Hofstede subsequently expanded his original research to include fifth65 and sixth66
dimensions that he argued captured additional cultural differences not brought out in his
earlier work. He referred to the fifth dimension as ‘Confucian dynamism’, which is now
referred to as ‘long-term orientation’. According to Hofstede, long-term orientation captures
attitudes towards time, persistence, ordering by status, protection of face, respect for
tradition, and reciprocation of gifts and favours. As might be expected, East Asian countries
such as Japan, Hong Kong and Thailand scored high on long-term orientation, while
nations such as Australia and New Zealand scored low (see Table 5.2). In countries scoring
LONG-TERM ORIENTATION
Extent to which a society adheres
to values about time, persistence,
ordering by status, protection
of face, respect for tradition and
reciprocation of gifts
EMERGING MARKETS
A TALE OF TWO COUNTRIES
The two Asian countries in the spotlight for Western
companies seeking to internationalise—via export or
offshore production or offshore servicing—are India and
China. India is best known for its IT-related services such
as call centres, and China is better known for its lowcost manufacturing capabilities. Who has not received
a marketing call from someone with an Indian accent or
doesn’t own clothes marked ‘Made in China’? What are the
similarities and differences between these two countries?
Both countries have undergone major economic
reforms and, as a result, are two of the fastest
growing economies in the world. In 2015 both countries
recorded growth rates of around 7 per cent. Both India
and China have huge populations and pools of willing
workers for production facilities, as well as a small
but growing middle class with a sizeable disposable
income for buying foreign goods.
India’s and China’s scores are similar on some of
Hofstede’s cultural value dimensions (see Table 5.2).
The numbers in the table show that both countries
are considered high power distance and collectivistic
(although China is more collectivistic). China’s culture is
considered more long-term oriented than India’s.
Although there are similarities, it would be foolhardy
for a Western manager to think of China and India in
the same way. For Anglo-Westerners, doing business
CHAPTER 5
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd 239
DIFFERENCES IN CULTURE
239
08/06/19 07:50 PM
in India is ‘easier’ because English is widely spoken.
In China, finding a good interpreter remains essential
if you want to negotiate a complex business deal. The
governments in the two countries are dissimilar: India’s
government is a robust democracy; and although
there are elections in China, the country has just one
party—the Communist Party of China. China is officially
atheist, although many Chinese practise Confucianism
in conjunction with local beliefs and/or Buddhism.
In India it is hard to miss the religious practices of
the majority Hindu population (80.5 per cent) whose
colourful temples are dotted throughout the cities.
Muslims are also well represented among the Indian
population (13.4 per cent).
It is imperative that Western managers develop their
cross-cultural literacy to understand how these similarities
and differences play out in business behaviour.
Western managers are often surprised about how long
it takes to set up a business in these countries. The
World Bank reported that starting a business in India
took 89 days (on average). In China it takes 41 days
for a business to be registered. Enforcing a contract
also takes an extended time in both countries; in India
it takes 425 days, compared to 241 days in China.
Western companies wanting to set up business in either
country have to navigate copious amounts of red tape.
In India, companies have to be registered through the
Office of the Registrar of Companies (ROC) in New
Delhi. One Western company that wanted to establish a
foothold in India, Uzanto Consulting, applied to register
its company name in the last week of March, and it was
not until 2 June that year that it received its registration
certificate, and then had to wait a further two weeks for
bank accounts to become operational.
According to Amit Ranjan, Uzanto Consulting’s chief
operating officer in New Delhi, the length of time it took
the ROC was ‘due to bureaucratic red tape’. After originally
applying to register the name ‘Uzanto Technologies’,
the ROC wanted the company to change the second
part of its name because ‘technologies’ was considered
too generic. Concern in India over the use of the word
‘technology’ is ironic, given that the transformation from
an impoverished, Soviet-inspired state in the 1980s to the
global epicentre of communications technology is largely
due to the technology revolution of the 1990s. Although
Uzanto tried to reason with the ROC, it ‘soon realised that
all such attempts were futile. In sheer exasperation and in
an effort to get it over with’, the name Uzanto Consulting
was suggested and the ROC agreed. Amit Ranjan writes
in his blog that ‘wrangling over the name issue probably
took up 20–25 days’. He goes on to comment that the
role of his chartered accountant (CA) was crucial in the
start-up process because some CAs can exert influence
in the ROC office. The role of the CA might be related to
the importance of personal relationships in India—some
India watchers deem relationships the most effective form
of communication in India.
Recently, the ROC office has reduced the time it takes
to register a company name by moving the process
online. Approval of a company name can take as little
as just a few minutes if companies apply online with all
the necessary documentation.
The time taken to craft a deal in a negotiation with
Indians and Chinese can frustrate Westerners. The
particular tactics used in China and India are different,
but they can have the same outcome. In China it is
common for negotiators to repeat their position over
and over again. In India, ‘they have a tendency to
badger one to the point of exasperation, when the
average American or European business man will
give in just to get rid of them or to move things along.
Alternatively they will stall when things are not going
their way, until the silence becomes unbearable and
you give in.’ Silence is a commonly used tactic in China,
too. Sometimes Chinese negotiators close their eyes
and say nothing for extended periods.
Coping with these behaviours is challenging for
Western managers. Even if they are culturally literate,
Western managers have to modify their responses to
behaviours at the very least and, ideally, should modify
their behaviours to achieve the goals they are seeking
in China or India.
SOURCES: M. Butcher, ‘India isn’t quite perfect but she has good opportunities for Australia’, On Line Opinion—Australia’s e-journal of social and
political debate (2004), www.onlineopinion.com.au; CIA World Factbook, www.cia.gov/cia/publications/factbook; ‘India eyes white-hot economic
growth’, cnn money.com, 7 February 2007, accessed via www.cnnmoney.com/2007/02/07/news/international/bc.india.economy.gdp.reut; J. Frederick,
‘Thriving in the Middle Kingdom: China’s middle class holds the key to the future of the country’, Time Asia (2002), www.time.com/time/asia/features/
china_cul_rev/middle_class.html; Itim International, www.geert-hofsted.com.hofsted_dimensions.php?culture1=42&culture2=18; R. Kumar,
‘Brahmanical idealism, anarchical individualism, and the dynamics of Indian negotiating behavior’, Cross Cultural Management, 4(1) (2004), pp. 39–58;
A. Ranjan, ‘Time taken to incorporate a company in India falls from three months to one hour’ (2006), www.amitranjam.com/category/managing-itstartups; A. Ranjan, ‘Starting up business in India—beware of ROC red-tape’ (2005), www.amitranjan.com/2005/08/12/starting-up-a-business-in-india%e2%80%93-watch-out-for-the-roc-redtape; ‘India 89’, rediff.com (2005), rediff.com/money/2005/aug/10busi.htm; World development indicators
database, http://dexdata.worldbank.org/external/CPProfile.asp?PTYPE=CP&CCode=IND.
240
PART 3
COUNTRY DIFFERENCES
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd
240
08/06/19 07:50 PM
high in long-term orientation, establishment of relationships comes before business, unlike
in Western countries where relationships are secondary to business.67 The sixth dimension
is based on the work of Michael Minkov. Hofstede and Minkov defined this dimension as
‘Indulgence versus restraint’ where indulgence is the human need to enjoy life and have
fun, and restraint is the need to control indulgence via social norms. New Zealand and
Australia are ranked 9 and 11 out of 93 countries.68 However, more empirical validation of
the sixth dimension is needed prior to common usage.
Two additional cultural values frameworks that have been examined and have been related
to work-related and/or business-related issues are the Global Leadership and Organizational
Behavior Effectiveness (GLOBE) Instrument and the World Values Survey (WVS).
The GLOBE instrument is designed to address the notion that a leader’s effectiveness
is contextual.69 It is embedded in the societal and organisational norms, values and beliefs
of the people being led. The initial GLOBE findings from 62 societies involving 17 300
middle managers from 951 organisations build on findings by Hofstede and other culture
researchers. The GLOBE research established nine cultural dimensions: power distance,
uncertainty avoidance, humane orientation, institutional collectivism, in-group collectivism,
assertiveness, gender egalitarianism, future orientation and performance orientation. (See
Table 5.3 for a summary.)
TABLE 5.3 GLOBE culture constructs
CULTURE
CONSTRUCT
DEFINITIONS
BRIEF DESCRIPTION OF GLOBE FINDINGS
IN RELATION TO SOCIETAL ATTRIBUTES
Power distance
The degree to which members of a collective expect
power to be distributed equally.
In high-power-distance societies there is a divide between
the rich and poor. Economic growth does not necessarily
result in greater employment for the poor. Low score in the
Human Development Index.
Uncertainty
avoidance
The extent to which a society, organisation or group
relies on social norms, rules and procedures to
alleviate unpredictability of future events.
Societies with high uncertainty avoidance have
government support for economic activities and good
infrastructure.
Humane
orientation
The degree to which a collective encourages and
rewards individuals for being fair, altruistic, generous,
caring and kind to others.
People in societies with high humane orientation tend to
be hospitable, extend warm greetings and show others
empathy.
Institutional
collectivism
The degree to which organisational and societal
practices encourage and reward collective
distribution of resources and collective action.
Countries with high institutional collectivism tend to be
those countries influenced by Confucian values. Decisions
are made by the group and economic systems are geared
towards maximising the wellbeing of the society.
In-group
collectivism
The degree to which individuals express pride,
loyalty and cohesiveness in their organisations or
families.
Societies with high in-group collectivism have a strong
distinction between in-groups and out-groups and an
emphasis on relatedness with groups.
Assertiveness
The degree to which individuals are assertive,
confrontational and aggressive in their relationships
with others.
In high-assertive societies competition and success
is valued and communication is direct. In addition
subordinates are expected to take initiatives.
Gender
egalitarianism
The degree to which a collective minimises gender
inequality.
In high-gender-egalitarianism societies women can be in
positions of authority and there is more gender equality.
Future
orientation
The extent to which individuals engage in futureoriented behaviours such as delaying gratification,
planning and investing in the future.
High-future-oriented societies tend to achieve economic
success and save for the future. The emphasis is on longterm success.
Performance
orientation
The degree to which a collective encourages
and rewards group members for performance
improvement and excellence.
Performance-oriented societies value training,
development and value results over people with
performance being rewarded.
SOURCE AND ACKNOWLEDGMENT: This table attempts to summarise some of the key GLOBE study findings in relation to societal attributes based on R.
House, P. Hanges, M. Javidan, P. Dorfman and V. Gupta, Culture, Leadership, and Organizations: The GLOBE Study of 62 Societies, Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage
Publications, 2004. It is an incomplete list.
CHAPTER 5
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd 241
DIFFERENCES IN CULTURE
241
08/06/19 07:50 PM
COUNTRY FOCUS
INDONESIA: CROSS-CULTURAL
AND GEOPOLITICAL
Indonesia is the world’s third largest democracy with the
world’s largest Muslim population. It is also the largest
economy in South-East Asia, the 16th largest economy
in the world and one of Australia’s closest geographic
neighbours. Australian mining equipment and
agricultural products (mainly wheat and live animals)
are among the major exports to Indonesia, while crude
petroleum and manufactured goods are key imports.
These trade flows are largely in primary and
intermediate products, mainly business to business. As
such, cross-cultural issues generally do not come into
play since the parties on either end of the transaction
are mainly focused on technical needs (e.g. the
appropriateness or effectiveness of a machine) and
relationships are typically purely business focused.
A notable exception: changes had to be made to
Australian live animal exports to Indonesia after 2016
when press reports indicated that some local Indonesian
abattoirs were operating below the humane treatment
standards that governed their Australian counterparts;
indeed, the whole live animal trade is based on
requirements for halal butchering of animals that meets
Islamic law requirements acceptable in Indonesia.
However, the bigger future growth potential is in trade
and investment in services and goods marketed directly
to consumers—and here cultural differences do have to
be understood and navigated more closely. Tourism is
already a major two-way relationship, as is education,
but much more growth is possible. Indonesian students
studying in Australia brought A$833 million into the
Australian economy in 2017, while Australian tourists
travelling in Indonesia contributed $3.1 billion to the
Indonesian economy—large numbers but with much
room to grow. Australia has had periodic hiccups with
other nations over local treatment of foreign students
but has been very responsive in addressing these (e.g.
quickly making security improvements in response to
periodic incidents where foreign students are victims of
crime). Such events can momentarily upset diplomatic
relations and cause a ruffle of media attention, but so far
people from both Australia and Indonesia seem to show
no let-up in wanting to visit one another’s countries.
Both countries have an experience base to work from
in navigating occasional serious disagreements and
misunderstandings in these areas, something that bodes
well for increasing growth in trade and investment.
However, moves into other markets such as consumer
goods, where a growing Indonesian urban middle class
offers great possibilities for Australian companies,
will require a new learning curve based on careful
due diligence and in particular mutual respect for the
differences between the dominant religious systems
in the two nations. Geopolitics can often enter into
this equation. For example, in 2018 the Australian
government followed the US government in announcing
that it would move its embassy in Israel from Tel Aviv
to Jerusalem. This provoked a strong protest from the
Indonesian government, which opposed the move
because it suggested Israeli sovereignty over a city
that Muslim nations believe should be more open given
its significance to Christians and Muslims as well as
Jews. Indonesia threatened to pull out of an upcoming
bilateral free trade deal and the Australian government
has since pulled back from its commitment.
Geopolitics aside, Australia and Indonesia need each
other economically. Increasing trade and investment
relationships does not require constant agreement
over cultural and religious concerns, but it does
require mutual understanding and sometimes political
compromise. As interdependency grows, so will the
need for these considerations.
Cameron Gordon
Australian National University
SOURCES: ‘Indonesia: Doing business’, Australian Government: Australian Trade and Investment Commission, www.austrade.gov.au/Australian/Export/
Export-markets/Countries/Indonesia/Doing-business, accessed February 2019; ‘Indonesia country brief’, Australian Government: Department of Foreign
Affairs and Trade, https://dfat.gov.au/geo/indonesia/Pages/indonesia-country-brief.aspx, accessed February 2019; A. Smith, ‘A year of turmoil for live export
industry’, Farm weekly, 31 December 2018, www.farmweekly.com.au/story/5824642/a-year-of-turmoil-for-live-export-industry/ accessed February 2019; ‘The
World Bank in Indonesia’, The World Bank, www.worldbank.org/en/country/indonesia/overview, accessed February 2019; V. Asri, ‘Number of Indian students
studying in Australia at a seven-year high’, SBS, 16 February 2018, www.sbs.com.au/yourlanguage/hindi/en/article/2018/02/16/number-indian-studentsstudying-australia-seven-year-high, accessed February 2019; R. Callinan, ‘Racial Attacks Trouble Indian Students in Australia’, Time, 6 June 2009, http://
content.time.com/time/world/article/0,8599,1903038,00.html, accessed February 2019; C. Sutton, ‘Left behind to rot: Bali ‘Five’ to die in jail’, news.com.au, 15
November 2018, www.news.com.au/national/crime/left-behind-to-rot-bali-five-to-die-in-jail/news-story/d66e41262452556d292cf8b708325630, accessed
February 2019; K. Murphy, ‘Simon Birmingham says Indonesian trade deal critical amid Israel embassy spat’, The Guardian, 18 November 2018, www.
theguardian.com/australia-news/2018/nov/18/simon-birmingham-says-indonesian-trade-deal-critical-amid-israel-embassy-spat, accessed February 2019.
242
PART 3
COUNTRY DIFFERENCES
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd
242
08/06/19 07:50 PM
The WVS is a research project spanning more than 100 countries that explores people’s
values and norms, how they change over time and what impact they have on society and
business.70 The WVS includes dimensions for support for democracy; tolerance of foreigners
and ethnic minorities; support for gender equality; the role of religion and changing levels
of religiosity; the impact of globalisation; attitudes towards the environment, work, family,
politics, national identity, culture, diversity and insecurity; and subjective wellbeing.
CULTURAL CHANGE
LO 5.5
Culture is not a constant; it evolves over time. Changes
in value systems can be slow and painful for a society.
Change, however, does occur and can often be quite
profound. In the 1960s, for example, Australian values
relating to the role of women, love, sex and marriage
underwent significant changes. Much of the social turmoil
of that time reflected these changes. For example, at the
beginning of the 1960s, the idea that women might hold
senior management positions in major corporations or be
a premier of a state or prime minister of the country was
not widely accepted. Many scoffed at the idea. Today, few
in mainstream Australian society question the development
or the capability of women in the business world. However,
although Australian culture has changed, it is still more
New Zealand Prime Minister Jacinda Ardern is a role model
difficult for women to gain senior management positions
for other aspiring leaders.
than men. According to the World Economic Forum Global
Gender Gap Index (see Table 5.4), Australia is ranked 46th, below the United States at 45th
and significantly below New Zealand ranked 9th. Regrettably, change is coming slowly:
globally, it is estimated that it will take another 217 years to reach gender equality.72
TABLE 5.4 World Economic Forum Global Gender Gap Index
RANK
ECONOMY
SCORE
1
Iceland
0.874
2
Finland
0.845
3
Norway
0.842
4
Sweden
0.815
5
Rwanda
0.8
6
Ireland
0.797
7
Philippines
0.786
8
Slovenia
0.786
9
New Zealand
0.781
45
United States
0.722
46
Australia
0.721
SOURCE: ‘Global Gender Gap Index 2016’, World economy forum, accessed via http://reports.weforum.org/globalgender-gap-report-2016/rankings/.
Why is gender equality important for business? Apart from the ethical and moral
imperative to stop discrimination, there is a significant economic benefit to gender equality.
According to a McKinsey Global Institute report, advancing equality could result in more
than US$12 trillion being added to the global GDP by 2025.73
CHAPTER 5
hiL23674_ch05_207-254.indd 243
DIFFERENCES IN CULTURE
243
08/06/19 07:50 PM
© Hagen Hopkins/Stringer/Getty Images
71
The value systems of many former Communist states, such as Russia, are undergoing
significant changes as those countries move away from values that emphasise collectivism
and towards those that emphasise individualism. While social turmoil is an inevitable
outcome of such a shift, the shift will still probably occur.
Similarly, some claim that a major cultural shift is occurring in Japan and Japanese
companies as highlighted in the opening case, with a move towards greater individualism.74
The model Japanese office worker, or ‘salaryman’, is characterised as being loyal to his boss
and the organisation to the point of giving up evenings, weekends and vacations to serve
the organisation, which is the collective of which the employee is a member. However, a
new generation of office workers does not seem to fit this model. An individual from the
new generation is likely to be more direct than the traditional Japanese. He acts more like a
Westerner, a gaijian. He does not live for the company and will move on if he gets the offer
of a better job. He is not keen on overtime, especially if he has a date. He has his own plans
for his free time, and they may not include drinking or playing golf with the boss.75
Several studies have suggested that economic advancement and globalisation may
be important factors in societal change.76 For example, there is evidence that economic
progress is accompanied by a shift in values away from collectivism and towards
individualism.77 Thus, as Japan has become richer, the cultural emphasis on collectivism
has declined and greater individualism is being witnessed. One reason for this shift may
be that richer societies exhibit less need for social and material support structures built
on collectives, whether the collective is the extended family or the paternalistic company.
People are better able to take care of their own needs. As a result, the importance
attached to collectivism declines, while greater economic freedoms lead to an increase in
opportunities for expressing individualism.
The culture of societies may also change as they become richer, because economic
progress affects a number of other factors, which in turn influence culture. For example,
increased urbanisation and improvements in the quality and availability of education
are both a function of economic progress, and both can lead to declining emphasis on
the traditional values associated with poor rural societies. A 25-year study of values
in 78 countries, known as the World Values Survey, coordinated by the University of
Michigan’s Institute for Social Research, has documented how values change. The study
linked these changes in values to changes in a country’s level of economic development.78
According to this research, as countries get richer, a shift occurs away from ‘traditional
values’ linked to religion, family and country, and towards ‘secular rational’ values.
Traditionalists say religion is important in their lives. They have a strong sense of national
pride; they also think that children should be taught to obey and that the first duty of a
child is to make his or her parents proud. They say abortion, euthanasia, divorce and suicide
are never justified. At the other end of this spectrum are secular rational values.
Another category in the World Values Survey is quality of life attributes. At one end of
this spectrum are ‘survival values’, the values people hold when the struggle for survival is
of paramount importance. These values tend to s
Download