Presentation to Wisconsin Park and Recreation Association November 8, 2006

advertisement
Presentation to Wisconsin
Park and Recreation
Association
November 8, 2006
By
Craig Maher
Assistant Professor
Masters of Public Administration Prgm.
University of Wisconsin - Oshkosh
Understanding Wisconsin’s
Tax Rankings and Possible
Solutions
[Or, Do Local Governments Need
Another State Intervention to
“Control” Property Taxes?]
“…After generations of trying to
reign in out-of-control taxes, it is
time to let people decide on a new
approach.”
Wisconsin State Senator Glenn Grothman
“The present tax and spending
situation in our state cannot
stand. We cannot afford to
continue the pattern…”
Wisconsin State Representative Frank Lasee
“With Wisconsin losing jobs, being ranked
as the most costly state to retire in, and
having the 5th highest taxes in the country,
we need to let people exercise their right
to place limits on government”
Wisconsin State Representative Jeff Wood
Which of the Following is the
Correct Answer?

Based on US Census data, When Combined,
Wisconsin’s State and Local Tax Collections in
2004 Ranked:




5th
12th
15th
20th
Of Course, the Answer is:
All of the Above
State and Local Revenue
Per Capita

Total Revenue







$958
26th highest
$985 Nat’l Average
Federal Aid

$3,714
12th highest
$3,447 Nat’l Average
Fees/Charges


20th highest
$6,447 Nat’l Average
Taxes

$6,455
35th highest
$1,452 Nat’l Average
$1,319
State and Local Revenue
Per $1,000 of Personal Income

Total Revenue







$29.76
29th highest
$29.84 Nat’l Average
Federal Aid

$115.39
5th highest
$104.45 Nat’l Average
Fees/Charges


15th highest
$195.38 Nat’l Average
Taxes

$200.55
33rd highest
$44.01 Nat’l Average
$40.99
Possible Explanations For WI’s
Above-Average Rankings




Expenditures
Economies of Scale (are there too many small
governments?)
Service Provision (contracting out)
Revenue Mix
Does WI Government Stand Out in
Spending?
Amt
Rank
US Avg.
Direct general expenditure
$
6,670
16
$
6,493
Higher education
$
767
12
$
591
Elementary & secondary
$
1,585
16
$
1,542
Public welfare
$
1,246
15
$
1,144
Hospitals
$
178
36
$
329
Health
$
236
15
$
215
Highways
$
522
17
$
403
Police protection
$
252
11
$
238
Fire protection
$
93
18
$
97
Correction
$
210
9
$
193
Does WI Government Stand Out in
Spending? (Con’t)
Amt
Rank
US Avg.
Natural resources
$
122
14
$
79
Parks and recreation
$
99
25
$
104
Housing and community development
$
81
35
$
127
Sewerage
$
138
9
$
121
Solid waste management
$
79
15
$
70
Financial administration
$
87
42
$
123
Explanation #2:
Economies of Scale
Per Capita
Expenditures
NHH*
Number of Households
Counties are Generally Below
100,000 Population
400
Thousands

Counties

300
200



100





















  






 

 






















 




0
Most Cities are
Below 50,000 Population
200
Thousands

Cities
150
100





50









































 











































































































































0 

 




Villages are Typically
Below 5,000 Population
30
Thousands
Villages

25
20

15


10





 





















  




 





 



















































































































































































































































































0 














5
Towns Tend to be
Under 2,500 Population
25
Thousands
Towns


20
15

10





 








5

 
  







 



















 







 


























































































































































































































































































































































































































































































































0 








Here’s the rub: We want smaller local
governments in a Jeffersonian sense to
enhance effectiveness but it comes at
higher costs due to economic
inefficiencies.
Economies of Scale Continued

According to Work by UW-Economist Steven
Deller:




Average number of households in WI:
2,400
Madison:
89,019
Milwaukee:
232,188
Based on this analysis the “optimal size” city
would be bigger than Madison, but about half the
size of Milwaukee (118,300)
Explanation #3: Contracting Out


It is a common belief that public services can
be more efficiently delivered when contracted
out to private or not-for-profit firms.
Based on survey work done in 2004, 83% of
the responding counties and municipalities
contract out some service.

The most frequently cited services that are
contracted out include solid waste and recycling
collection.
Explanation #4: Fiscal Partnership
Between State and Local Gov’ts

Current Policy in WI (Source: Kettl Commission
Report)

Fiscal Partnership. State raises money. Entrusts local
government to manage programs and deliver services.
Think about services in Wisconsin, how many are actually
provided by the State versus local gov’t. Does “home-rule”
really exist?

Shared benefits. Recognize benefits to non-residents of a
locally provided public service or good. Education benefits
society as a whole as well as those receiving the education.

Equalization. Offset tax base disparities. Key programs in
Wisconsin: Shared Revenues and Equalization Aids
Current Policy Con’t

Property tax relief. Reduce dependence on property tax (e.g.,
2/3rds, tax “freeze”). Wisconsin first state to adopt income tax
in 1911, why? Sales taxes in 1962, and county portion in
1986, why?

Tax policy. Modify who pays what portion of the tax burden.

Lost tax base. Offset a narrowing of the local tax base. M&E
Exemption, Personal Property (e.g., computers)

Required services. Provide funding for mandatory duties.
Taxes and Fees Paid
Services Received
Federal Aid
State Services
State Receipts
Paid To State
Citizen Taxpayer
$5,136
State Aid
Paid To Local
Local Receipts
Local Services
Federal Aid
Source: Kettl Commission Report
Is Current Policy Sustainable?




State continues to face fiscal pressures (some
say structural deficit, particularly according to
GAAP standards)
WI a “tax hell”, with property taxes among
highest
WI distributes 2/3rds of GPR funds to local
government
Lack of accountability at both state and local
level
Top Ten State Expenditures
Good News for Schools… Not So Good
for Counties and Municipalities
School Aid Share Up - Shared Revenues Share Down
60%
Shared Revenues
School Aids
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
2007
2005
2003
2001
1999
1997
1995
1993
1991
1989
1987
1985
1983
1981
1979
1977
1975
1973
1971
1969
0%
School Aids Double Total GPR
Growth
Cumulative Change in GPR Spending
250%
School Aids
Total GPR
200%
Income
150%
100%
FY07
FY06
FY05
FY04
FY03
FY02
FY01
FY00
FY99
FY98
FY97
FY96
FY95
FY94
FY93
FY92
FY91
0%
FY90
50%
Property Tax “Freeze” Coupled
With Flat Shared Revenue A Major
Cause of Stress
STATE SHARED REVENUES INDEX
WISCONSIN TOTAL
140
Index Value (1987 = 100)
135
130
125
120
115
110
105
100
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
Wisconsin Total
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
Intergovernmental Aid

One of the areas where WI stands out is the degree
and type of intergovernmental aid


WI’s Shared Revenue Prgm. is relatively unique when
compared to other states
Other states tend to give local governments more
revenue options



Sales tax
Motor vehicle tax
Chicago area has own income tax, gas tax, sales, etc!
Local Revenue Contribution to
Local Spending
Local Revenue Share
of Local Spending
Over 71%
67% - 71%
62% to 67%
57% to 62%
Under 57%
(10)
(10)
(9)
(11)
(10)
WI’s Shared Revenue Prgm.




Initiated in 1911 when WI became 1st State to adopt
an income tax the purpose of providing property tax
relief
Current model created in early 1970s following M&E
exemption
State now collects all income taxes, most sales taxes,
all utility property taxes
Through the Shared Revenue Prgm., WI redistributes
some of these revenues on the bases of:




Need (aidable revenue entitlement: 82% of formula)
Population
Utility
Hold Harmless
Aidable Revenues Component
(Current Model)

Distribution based on equalization


Assumes need to equalize tax rates at the local
level through state distribution (if expenses are
equal, so too should be tax rates)
Redistribution based on



Per capita property wealth
Net local revenue effort
Thus, if wealth is low and revenue effort is high –
high aidable revenues entitlement
Aidable Revenues Con’t

Formula compares local per capita value to a standard
valuation adopted by the State (a per capita figure that is
manipulated based on available state aid)




If local revenue is high compared to others – need more aid to
reduce tax burden
Corollary: if you spend a lot – logic is you must need more aid
If property value is low compared to a standard value – need aid
to keep tax rate low
Hold harmless – protects communities from big swings in
formula benefit; communities receive no less than 95% of
previous year’s revenues. The maximum increase is set annually
to fund the 95% guarantee
Impact of Shared Revenues

Pros



Provides equity across communities re. service
provision
Provides some property tax relief
Offsets state decisions to exempt certain types of
property

E.g., M&E exemption in 1970s
Shared Revenues

Cons

Inefficient




Very Expensive


“Flypaper” Effect
“Fiscal Illusion” (Kettl Commission)
Formula has disincentive for efficient service delivery
One of the most expensive State GPR expenses
Greater State Intervention – limits “home rule”

Why not give local governments more revenue options
in exchange for “significant” reduction in shared
revenues
My Research With Steven Deller




shared revenues increase local government spending, meaning
that when comparing two communities with the same general
characteristics, the one that receives more shared revenues will
spend more;
shared revenue payments are related to reductions in property
taxes, meaning that as shared revenues increase, local property
taxes decrease;
in general, municipalities that have received lower shared
payments over recent years, have responded by replacing those
aids through a combination of increased property taxes, fees
and debt service;
communities that lose shared revenues are most prone to
replace funds for “core” services such as police and fire than
for services such as culture, education parks and recreation.
Recommendation #1

Explain why there is a problem:

State needs to realize its role as cause

There has been a tendency over the past years to treat
property tax limits (TABOR, or “simple” levy limits)
separately from shared revenue payments. This is not
practical in WI for the simple reason that local
governments have limited revenue options. So, when
state lawmakers freeze shared revenues as they
essentially have done since the mid-1990’s, it should not
be surprising that property taxes rise at a faster rate.
Recommendation #2

Cut Shared Revenues “substantially” and give
municipalities more revenue options. The most
common in other states is a sales tax.

A local tax for municipalities would enable the State to
address some of its fiscal woes by reducing shared
revenues and simultaneously provide property tax relief. In
addition it would force local policy makers (including
myself) to be more accountable for their budgeting
practices in two ways: 1) they would no longer be able to
blame the State for the lack of growth in aid payments and;
2) given that sales taxes are sensitive to economic cycles,
communities would be forced to budget accordingly.
Local Revenue Option, Con’t

Several recent study, including one of the
Chicago metropolitan area, where
municipalities have a number of local tax
options including sales, income and gas taxes,
found that communities with greater revenue
diversity have lower tax effort. This suggests
that when communities have a broader range
of revenue available, they act more efficiently,
thus lowering taxes.
Recommendation #3



Local governments need to reevaluate their budgeting
processes.
Too much incremental budgeting
What is missing from most of local budget
deliberations in WI is a discussion of the broader, and
I believe, more important matters such as:




Whether services/programs are necessary
How well services are being provided
What are the expected outcomes from programs
How well did the program meet its outcome objectives the
previous year
Thank You
Questions?
Download