Keynote Address: Coasting Uphill in the Global Human Capital Economy Thomas Mortenson

advertisement
Coasting Uphill in Maryland
Tom Mortenson
October 31, 2005
Maryland
Maryland is a very well educated state (ranks 5th in percent of adults with bachelor’s
degrees or more). Maryland is also relatively very prosperous (state per capita personal
income ranks 5th also). But this apparent status was produced less by the efforts of
Maryland to higher educate its native population than it is the result of Maryland’s
proximity to the Washington, DC job generator. Maryland’s college educated workforce
was disproportionately higher educated elsewhere then attracted to the DC area by the
large and growing numbers of jobs requiring college educated workers.
When Maryland education data is examined in more detail, a far weaker state effort to
educate its native population becomes apparent. Maryland’s public high school
graduation rate ranks 22nd among the states. Maryland’s college continuation rate for its
public and private high school graduates ranks 25th. The chance that a 19 year old
Marylander will be enrolled in a college somewhere in the U.S. ranks 17th among the
states. The chance that a low income student from Maryland will reach college ranks 18th
among the states. And young Marylanders apparently do not think much of the higher
education choices they have within the state: many more Marylanders leave the state to
start college elsewhere than come to Maryland from other states to start college here.
Worst of all Maryland ranks 41st among the states in its state tax fund investment effort in
higher education. These data indicate that Maryland is coasting along, making minimal
efforts, living off its fortuitous proximity to Washington, DC, and doing little to assist its
native population get the higher education they need to thrive in the Human Capital
Economy.
This Human Capital Economy began in the United States in the early 1970s when income
became ever more strongly tied to higher education attainment. Now, according to Tom
Friedman who writes The World is Flat, the Human Capital Economy went global around
2000. Today’s young people are no longer competing with young people in other states.
From 2000 on they are competing with the best and brightest in the world. And the
international data all indicate that we are doing very, very poorly in this international
higher education race.
As long as the nation’s capital remains in DC Maryland will do well compared to other
states. But native Marylanders will fall farther behind the college educated immigrants to
the state. And the prosperity of the state and country will deteriorate relative to growing
Human Capital super powers like India and China.
If Maryland is to thrive in the global Human Capital Economy it must do a far better job
of higher educating its native population than it has done in the past and is doing today.
Maryland must begin by examining its changing demography and educational attainment
requirements of its workforce. Then Maryland needs to develop a response—an
increased investment effort focused on its demographic and labor market needs. Doing
business the way Maryland has done in its past will mean coasting downhill instead of up
in a flat world.
Policy Imperatives
Over the last 25 years a chasm has developed separating reality and policy regarding
opportunity for higher education in the United States. Our failure to align policy with
reality is costing us dearly and these costs will continue to accumulate and multiply until
either effective alignment is achieved or we dissolve from within.
There are two policy imperatives that we have ignored for decades: the labor market of
the new Human Capital Economy and the changing demography of the United States.
This brief contrasts these two policy imperatives with the federal, state and institutional
policy choices we have made and concludes with evidence of this leadership failure.
Human Capital Economy: The Human Capital Economy began in the United States
about 1973. Until then real incomes were rising at all levels of educational attainment.
About 1973 the labor market began to change in fundamental ways that continue today.
Income and the living standards that income supports began to be redistributed according
to educational attainment. Real incomes of college graduates continued to increase while
real incomes of those with high school educations or less began to decline. These
changes have been in place in the United States for three decades.
This redistribution of income along educational attainment lines reflects imbalances
between the demand and supply of labor. The labor market is oversupplied with workers
with high school educations or less and it is undersupplied with workers who have
college educations or more. The persistence of this redistribution over the last three
decades reflects the lagging pace of upgrading workers’ educations relative to the
growing needs of the labor force for workers with postsecondary educations and training.
It also reflects a continued and growing oversupply of unskilled workers relative to the
number of unskilled jobs available in the labor force.
These shifts have somewhat different implications for males and females. Traditional
male jobs (farming, manufacturing, etc.) are in decline. But the growing number of jobs
in service industries has attracted an increasingly college-educated female labor pool.
In this decade the Human Capital Economy has spread world wide. The outsourcing of
white collar jobs should not have been unexpected. The U.S. watched for decades as
manufacturing jobs went overseas. We could have anticipated that the same would occur
for the white collar high skill jobs that are the foundation for our economic prosperity.
Just as income has followed educational attainment in the U.S. we should have
anticipated that other countries would come to see our Human Capital advantage and
seek to replicate or surpass it.
Other industrial democracies which we compete in the global economy have been and
continue to be aggressively expanding their college educated workforces—something we
stopped doing in the 1990s. As a result tertiary education participation rates for the
United States now rank in the bottom half of the industrial democracies. And among 20
to 24 years olds the United States now ranks in the bottom third.
Therefore the first policy imperative must be to expand higher education participation to
advance our economic, social and political interests in a globally-competitive Human
Capital Economy.
Changing Demography. The second policy imperative is to deal positively and
aggressively with the changing demography of the United States. When I graduated from
high school in 1961 about 7 percent of all high school graduates were minorities. Today
30 percent are, and by 2018 about 45 percent of public high school graduates will be
minorities. These children have been born and are living with us today. They may be
still at home, or second graders, or seventh graders or tenth graders. But they are real,
they are here, and they are approaching college age and the adult workforce. These
black, Hispanic, Asian and American Indian children will gradually replace the whitenon-Hispanic population of this country’s past. They represent a growing share of the
country’s future workers, citizens and parents of the generation that will follow.
These demographic shifts in the population are also evident in the share of school
children approved for subsidized school lunches. To receive a subsidized school lunch
family income must fall below 185 percent of the poverty threshold. Between 1992 and
2003 the share of K-12 enrollment approved for free or reduced-price school lunches
increased from 37.0 to 42.9 percent in the U.S. Similar increases occurred in all but four
states.
These new populations share a common characteristic: these children are growing up in
families with incomes very much lower than the incomes of the white non-Hispanic
children that they are gradually replacing. Some are children of immigrants and are just
learning the ropes of success in the United States. Some are children of parents who
never received much formal education. Many are growing up in schools that are not
effective in preparing them for success in college. Most live in communities where few
children every go on to college or even graduate from high school.
These new populations are gradually replacing the shrinking white non-Hispanic
populations. They will require equivalent or better higher educations to maintain national
prosperity, social cohesion and world leadership than we have today.
Policy Choices
The increasing educational attainment requirements of the labor force and the changing
demography call for a set of policy choices that have not been made in the United States
over the last 25 years. In fact the federal, state and institutional policy choices that have
been made have been quite the opposite of what these two policy imperatives require.
Federal policy choices. In 1965 the federal government assumed a key role of fostering
higher educational opportunity by providing financial aid to institutions for those who
needed money to help pay college attendance costs. This was a part of President
Johnson’s War on Poverty. In 1972 this federal commitment was affirmed and greatly
expanded when the Basic Grant program was created with financial aid in the form of
grants targeted on students from low and lower-middle income families. Through the
remainder of the 1970s the federal government added eligibility and funding to the Basic
Grant program (now called Pell Grant program).
Then, in two brief economic recessions in the very early 1980s Congress faced a choice
about how to address a funding shortfall in the Pell Grant program. Congress could
either rescind the Middle Income Student Act passed in 1978 or it could reduce the Pell
Grant maximum award for students from lowest income families. Congress chose the
latter, and for two years in a row Congress reduced the Pell Grant maximum award to
preserve middle income eligibility it had enacted in 1978. This choice began to redirect
federal student financial aid policy from the 1960s focus on lowest income students
toward students from middle income and eventually upper income families.
The share of federal student financial aid based on demonstrated financial need continued
to grow until the mid 1980s when it peaked around 86 percent. Thereafter non-need
based student financial aid grew much faster than need-based aid and by 2004 just 50
percent of federal aid was awarded on the basis of need. (Note that when a needs-test is
removed from eligibility policy makers intend the resources to go to students who do not
need them.)
The reversal in federal student financial aid policy was completed in 1997 when
Congress enacted President Clinton’s proposed Hope and Lifetime Learning Tax Credits.
This program deliberately excluded students from families with incomes below about
$40,000 from program benefits. (These tax credits are not refundable and families not
paying federal income taxes cannot receive them.)
As Congress considers reauthorization of the Higher Education Act of 1965 there is little
evidence of a renewed concern for the growing numbers of students from low income
families and their growing difficulties paying for higher education.
State policy choices. Historically states have assumed the major responsibility for
expanding higher education capacity. Currently about 80 percent of undergraduates are
enrolled in public colleges and universities. Until the late 1970s states also sought to
keep colleges financially accessible by heavily subsidizing their operations so that
institutions could keep their tuition low (and actually declining in real terms). But by
1980 states were starting to shift state resources away from higher education toward other
state budget priorities such as prisons and health care. The state tax fund investment
effort in higher education that peaked at $10.58 per $1000 of state person income in
FY1976 began a ratcheted decline. By FY2005 the state effort stood at $6.91 per $1000
of personal income or about 35 percent below the FY1976 peak.
As a result of deteriorating state financial support public colleges and universities began
raising tuition charges to students to offset loss of state support. These tuition increases
were greater than inflation, greater than family income growth (especially for students
from lowest income families) and were not offset by increases in grant assistance. The
costs of public higher education were and continue to be shifted from state taxpayers to
students.
Many states have created state merit scholarship programs based largely on Georgia’s
popular Hope Scholarship Program. These programs do not include a needs-test for
eligibility, but instead employ academic eligibility criteria that strongly favor students
from highest income families. The result is state financial aid that is directed toward
students who do not need it, and is denied to those with real financial needs to pay
college attendance costs.
Institutional policy choices. Both public and private four-year colleges and universities
have become more academically selective at least since the mid 1980s. Because of the
high correlation between academic criteria (SAT and ACT test scores, high school
grades, etc.) and family income, academic selectivity is nearly synonymous with family
income selectivity. Thus selective admissions colleges and universities are effectively
focusing on the most affluent but shrinking segment of the college student population.
Under enrollment management the admissions offices in four year colleges and
universities are increasingly using institutional financial aid resources to attract high
ability and high income students. At least four studies of institutional tuition discounting
have shown that colleges and universities are shifting their own financial aid resources
away from low income toward high income students. This does not appear to be the
practice of top-tier institutions, but rather institutions that lack national visibility and
reputation.
In their pursuit of profits and prestige for themselves these institutions have lost sight of
their broader social mission to educate rather than select—a mission that justifies taxexempt status, public subsidies and eligibility for Title IV student financial aid program
participation. These institutions increasingly compete for the shrinking share of the high
school graduate market, and turn away from the growing shares. These practices do not
expand higher education participation and social welfare. They instead address shortterm institutional interests of profits and prestige.
Policy Consequences
The failure to align policy choices with policy imperatives has direct and measurable
consequences for higher education opportunity, participation and degree production in
the United States. Among them are these:
College participation rates have stagnated since the early 1990s. College participation
rates expanded significantly in the years after World War II. But that growth stopped in
the early 1990s. Since then college participation rates in the United States have flattened,
and in some cases declined slightly.
Gains in bachelor’s degree attainment have gone almost entirely to students born into the
top quartile of the family income distribution. In our studies of bachelor’s degree
attainment by age 24, students born into the top quartile of family income (above about
$95,000 per year) increased their bachelor’s degree attainment rates by 30 percentage
points between the late 1970s and the early 2000s. For those in the third family income
quartile bachelor’s degree attainment increased by 9 percent, in the second quartile by 3
percent, and in the bottom quartile by 0.03 percent. In the late 1970s students from the
top quartile of family income earned about 44 percent of all bachelor’s degrees by age 24.
By 2003 they were earnings 58 percent of all bachelor’s degrees by age 24.
Higher education opportunity is now contributing directly to growing income inequality
in the U.S. and has been doing so for more than 30 years. Since about 1973 income has
been redistributed according to educational attainment. Those with the most formal
educations have seen their real incomes rise, while those with high school educations or
less have seen real income declines. As higher education is increasingly reserved for
those lucky enough to be born into the top half of the family income distribution, their
growing higher educational attainment contributes directly to growing income inequality
in the U.S.
Other countries continue to expand college participation rates while in the U.S. rates fall
ever farther behind. Among the 30 countries that are members of the Organization for
Economic Cooperation and Development the U.S. college participation rates rank in the
bottom half. Among 20 to 24 year olds the U.S. rates rank in the bottom third. We have
fallen behind most other industrial democracies in the higher education of our future
workforce.
We are once again a Nation at Risk. And just as we learned in 1983 that we had done
this to ourselves by lax policies in K-12 education, so too now we learn that we have
done this to ourselves in higher education as well.
Download