Research Journal of Applied Sciences, Engineering and Technology 6(2): 297-303,... ISSN: 2040-7459; e-ISSN: 2040-7467

advertisement
Research Journal of Applied Sciences, Engineering and Technology 6(2): 297-303, 2013
ISSN: 2040-7459; e-ISSN: 2040-7467
© Maxwell Scientific Organization, 2013
Submitted: September 22, 2012
Accepted: November 23, 2012
Published: June 10, 2013
Implementation Decision-making of WEEE Take-Back Directive
Guojun Ji
School of Management, Xiamen University, Xiamen, Fujian 361005, China
Abstract: In this study, based on the objective of social welfare maximization, the issues of take-back network,
recycling targets setting, recovery catalogs sorting, supervision and stimulation of take-back models are discussed.
Conclusion demonstrates that: manufacturers, recyclers and consumers do not always share the same preference
over three patterns, but the mode of manufacture-leading take-back can reach maximum social welfare; the most
efficient network system should be around the manufacturer individual take-back responsibility to build; the takeback level and the recovery catalogs must synthesize the factors involve environmental impact of product, take-back
cost/benefit and recycling and manufacturing industries' market structure etc., the supervision and stimulation
decision matrix associated with the PROs is as an effective tool to balance the environmental benefits and social
welfare.
Keywords: Closed-loop supply chain, end-of-life waste, extended producer responsibility, take-back directive, twostage sequential decision-making game
Organizations (PROs) perspective, Mayers (2007)
based on a case of SONY Computer Entertainment in
Europe, indicates that the PROs have the important role
under the EU WEEE regulations; From the recycling
firms, according to reverse logistics process of the
waste computers, without any laws support, the firms’
benefit is less. Thus, the government should promote
the circulation economic legislation as soon as possible
and to promulgate; from the government's perspective,
the environment subsidy policies shall have effect on
the firms decision-making environment as well as
motivate remanufacturers (Mitra and Webster, 2008).
From the quantitive models: Savaskan et al. (2004)
studies the manufacturer's decision-making to establish
quantitative models of three reverse logistics operation
(retailer
take-back,
third-party
take-backand
manufacturer take-back), then they found the basic
properties of the three models optimization;
Subramanian et al. (2009) analyzed a supply chain to
know how coordination can lead to remanufactured
products of better DfE under the WEEE regulations;
Atasu et al. (2009b) presented the impact of product
reuse design and “pick-up” patterns based on two PROs
models, which found that individual take-back model
has better stimulation than the collective take-back
model; Toyasaki et al. (2008) based on the
manufacturing and processing industries characteristics,
presented the individual take-back model and the
collective take-back model to the stakeholders reflect
the different impacts and figured that the PROs are
critical to the recovery system by using two-stage game
models, but the manufacturers' disposal capacity is
omitted. Atasu and Subramanian (2009a) based on the
INTRODUCTION
Increasing economic growth has been the principal
cause of the waste increasing: economic growth reflects
the increase of production, consumption and thus
increases the waste. The environmental pressure based
on waste generation presents: Firstly, the permanent
loss of materials and energy increases day by day.
Secondly, with the current landfill sites are filling up, it
leads to pressure to use new sites with the loss of that
land use for housing, leisure or agriculture. Thirdly, the
additional waste left in these landfill sites increases air,
water and land pollutions.
In the early 1990s some European Union member
states, notably the Netherlands, Germany and Sweden
developed their own national policy to deal with their
growing waste problems. This principle has been most
clearly implemented in the WEEE Directive on Waste
Electrical & Electronic Equipment. At present, China’s
WEEE recycling disposals are undertook mainly by
some informal sectors, which not only waste resources
but also pollute the environment and even face the
occupational safety. At the same time, without enough
WEEE recycling, it will result in the official processing
firms “await urgently necessary condition”, which they
involve in the red state. Therefore, the government
should develop and implement the feasible legislation
to regulate the WEEE recycling industry. As for the
consumer behavior, if the customer behaviors are
willing to returns, it would help the home appliances
recycling; as for the manufacturers, the home appliance
firms recycling behaviors were systematically analyzed
(Wang and Yin, 2008); From Producer Responsibility
297
Res. J. Appl. Sci. Eng. Technol., 6(2): 297-303, 2013
social welfare maximization objective to balance
economic and environmental impacts, in order to ensure
the fairness of implementation the WEEE regulations,
but there is shortage of comparative analysis on the
take-back and disposal models. Different with the
above literatures, we will integrate various essential
factors to bring into the WEEE regulations system, thus
obtain the whole understanding of the PROs roles and
the stakeholders.
Considering the objective of social welfare
maximization, the issues of take-back network,
recycling targets setting, recovery catalogs sorting,
supervision and stimulation of take-back models are
discussed. Based on abovementioned, this study
analyzes assumptions of models, then builds the takeback models and reveals the implementation decisionmaking of the WEEE regulations.
concentrative take-back can be achieved. The
organizations play a crucial role in successful
implementation of EPR principle particularly, when
small and medium-sized enterprises involving in the
organizations, they can greatly reduce the difficulty and
cost of WEEE recovery. And they play a good role with
linkage of manufacturers, processors, retailers,
governments and other interest groups (Mayers, 2007).
They are also responsible for expropriation the specific
take-back fund to manufacturers, build the recycling
standardization system, develop the effective product
DfE incentive regulation, enhance consumers'
environmental education, etc.
Consumers: consumers as the important stakeholders
to the effective implementation of the WEEE
regulations have direct effect. They not only care
environmental protection, but fear manufacturers to
increase product price because of adjustment WEEE
take-back-related costs. Convenient for analysis,
suppose that consumers reverse demand function meets
P = 1-q, where, q total consumption of the product is.
Then the consumer surplus reflects:
ASSUMPTIONS OF MODELS
Due to the above discussion, it is impossible for a
qualified WEEE take-back company to operate
successfully before enforcing the legislations and
formulating favorable policies and regulations on
WEEE. From the recycling pilot firms in China, the
pilot effects reflect:
•
•
Π C=
1
(1 − p )q
2
(1)
Manufacturers: Their main responsibilities reflect: On
the one hand, green production facilitates resources to
synthetically utilize and design harmless processing
programme, convenient for take-back materials must
reach the minimum r; on the other hand, take-back
WEEE by own or outsourcing must reach the minimum
c. Manufacturers through two ways complete their
WEEE management responsibilities (Toffel, 2003), i.e.,
individual take-back responsibility and collective takeback responsibility. Individual take-back responsibility
refers to the manufacturers that have their own
recycling network, is responsible only for take-back
own manufactured products; the collective take-back
responsibility is aim at all manufacturers product of one
profession, manufacturers pay determinate take-back
costs to PROs who take on the recycling
responsibilities.
Suppose that there are two identical manufacturers,
both utilize the Cournot game to get their market share
(Fig. 1), then 𝑃𝑃 = 1 − ∑2𝑖𝑖−1 π‘žπ‘žπ‘–π‘– (i = 1, 2.), q i is the
manufacturer M i sales products. Manufacturers are
responsible for take-back the waste products
manufactured by themselves and then decide to dispose
those whether by themselves or by the qualified
processing enterprises. Assume that manufacturers per
unit cost of production is µ, t is the unit cost of takeback WEEE and 1-µ-tc>0. When the manufacturers
dispose by themselves, they can obtain subsidies d of
unit.
A recycling industrial road is explored, which
conforms to China's conditions, the extracted
experience will help to institute China’s recycling
industrial standards
The management organizations similar to PROs are
engendered
The national WEEE take-back network systems
can be established (Yang et al., 2008).
Our decision sequence is as follows: firstly, the
PROs determine recovery rate c, which means recovery
rate after sale, reuse rate r denotes recycled products
can reuse ratio (Tojo et al., 2001) and d denotes the
subsidies of recovery and processing; Secondly, based
on the cost of recovery and processing, manufacturers
determine their products sales volume and price;
Thirdly, each processing firm decides to charge a
processing fee to manufacturers; and finally, the
consumers purchase remanufactured products, where,
0≤c, r≤1, d≥0. The roles under the WEEE regulations
reflect as follows: PROs are the nonprofit
organizations, which dominated by the Government and
constituted by the producers, industrial associations and
the processing firms and so on, shall monitor the
producers to bear the responsibilities and obligations of
WEEE recovery. Usually, they are organized by
product category, so the maximum efficiency of
298
Res. J. Appl. Sci. Eng. Technol., 6(2): 297-303, 2013
Fig. 1: Two-stage sequential decision-making game
Outsourcing take-back model: In this model, suppose
that the processing provider is as a Stackelberg leader,
the manufacturers are followers. This is just as the
current WEEE recovery demand in the Europe which
far exceeds the existing recovery capacities, the
recycling industry is still in the developing phase, at the
same time the manufacturers must meet the minimum
requirements of the WEEE directive. For example, in
Germany there are about 20 recycling firms provide
take-back service of old computers and old electrical
product to more than 20,000 manufacturers and
importers. Similarly, in Netherlands, non-profit
organizations through four recovery firms to process
the waste products of more than 1200 manufacturers
and every recovery firm is only responsible for a
specific product category (Future Energy Solutions,
2003). In fact, on the one hand, manufacturers face to
compete in the new products market; on the other hand,
processing firms set competitive recovery costs in the
waste product market.
•
( t + er −η ) c ( ∑ q ) i =
q ( p − u − t c) =
i 1, 2.
Π CR (t C ) =
The analysis of take-back models: At present, there
are two major types of WEEE take-back models in
China: one is the outsourcing take-back model, which
can be divided into single take-back model and
collective take-back model; another type is
manufacturer internalization take-back model, i.e.,
recovery and processing by itself (Toffel, 2003).
C
i
Π Ci (q=
i)
C
i
1, 2.
(2)
To reverse deduce the two-stage game, considering
the manufacturer Cournot game in the second stage,
when given tc, manufacturer M 1 determines its output
(π‘žπ‘žπ‘π‘πΆπΆ (π‘žπ‘ž2𝐢𝐢 ) from (2), then the specific response function
meets:
q1C (q2C ) =
1 − q2C − u − t C c
2
(3)
Similarly, manufacturer M 2 response function can
be deduced. Uniting two functions, Nash equilibrium
solutions as follow:
=
qiC (t C )
1− u − tCc
=
i 1, 2.
3
(4)
Let (4) substitutes for (2) in the first stage, the
processing provide R follows the oligopolistic games,
then:
tC =
The collective recovery processing: From model
C, based on wastes of all manufacturers in one
profession, PROs usually according to the
profession’s average processing cost to collect the
manufacturers processing fund. The manufacturers
M 1 , M 2 separately sign a contract with PROs and
pay the processing cost tc, then, PROs assign the
third party processing provider R to operate and
pay the processing fund tc. For instance, Holland,
Sweden often uses this model.
1 − u − cer + cη
2c
(5)
Let tc substitutes for (4), the equilibrium output and
the market price of the product reflect as follows:
qiC=
1
2 1 1
1
(1 − u + cer − cη ) i= 1, 2. p C = + u − cer + cη
6
3 3 3
3
(6)
At the same time, we can obtain the manufacturer’s
profit, processing provider’s profit, consumer’s surplus
as well as the system profit, where the system profit ∏ S
is defined as the sum of manufacturer’s profit,
processing provider’s profit and consumer’s surplus
(Table 1).
Therefore, the profit function of the processing
provider and the manufacturer are follows, respectively:
299
Res. J. Appl. Sci. Eng. Technol., 6(2): 297-303, 2013
Table 1: Optimal value of three take-back scheme
Model C
Processing fee t
1 − u − cer + cη
2 1
1
1
+ u − cer + cη
3 3
3
3
Product sales q
1
(1 − u + cer − cη )
3
1
2
(1 − u + cer − cη )
18
1
(1 − u + cer − cη ) 2
6
1
(1 − u + cer − cη ) 2
18
5
(1 − u + cer − cη ) 2
18
Manufacturer’ profit ∏M
Processing provider’s profit ∏R
Consumer’ surplus Consumer’
surplus ∏C
System’s profits ∏S
•
Model T
5 4
4
4
+ u − cer + cη
9 9
9
9
4
(1 − u + cer − cη )
9
8
(1 − u + cer − cη ) 2
81
4
(1 − u + cer − cη ) 2
27
8
(1 − u + cer − cη ) 2
81
28
(1 − u + cer − cη ) 2
81
1 2
2
2
2
+ u − cer + cη − drc
3 3
3
3
3
2
(1 − u + cer − cη + drc)
3
2
(1 − u + cer − cη + drc) 2
9
1 − u − 2cer + 2cη
3c
2c
Product price P
Model I
2
(1 − u + cer − cη + drc) 2
9
4
(1 − u + cer − cη + drc) 2
9
Let (10) substitutes for (7) and (8), respectively,
The single recovery processing: From model I,
considering Cournot game, then the equilibrium
each manufacturer freely signs a contract with
solutions of processing expense satisfy:
single processing provider, in which PROs are in
the supervision role, such as Germany and Austria
1 − u − 2cer + 2cη
tends to this model. Assume that manufacturer M 1
=
tiI =
i 1, 2.
signs a recovery processing contract with
3c
(11)
processing provider R A and pays unit processing
expense 𝑑𝑑1𝐼𝐼 to R A ; manufacturer M 2 signs a
Thereby, the equilibrium output and price of the
contract with processing provider R B and pays unit
manufacturers
are as follows:
processing expense 𝑑𝑑1𝐼𝐼 to R B . Then, the profit
functions of the processing providers reflect as
5 4
4
4
2
qiI= (1 − u + 2cer − cη ) i= 1, 2. p I = + u − cer + cη
follows, respectively:
9 9
9
9
9
(12)
(
)
Π IA (t1I ) = ( t1I + er − η ) cq1 Π IB (t2I ) = t2I + er − η cq2
(7)
Therefore, in this mode, we can obtain the
manufacturer’s profit, the processing provider’s profit,
the consumer’s surplus as well as the system’s income
(Table 1).
(8)
The individual take-back model: As shown, model T
is a closed-loop supply chain, not only includes the
forward flow of the manufacturer's product, but the
reverse flow of waste product from consumers. This
model is actually internalization and integration of
recovery processing, which the manufacturer by oneself
fulfill take-back responsibility or the WEEE
regulations. For example, IBM and DELL have used
the model (Toffel, 2003). The model can be performed
by the third party providers as well as in virtue of
retailers “trade new good for old” way etc. In this
model, Government usually gives certain subsidies to
manufacturers to encourage them take-back WEEE.
Then, manufacturer's profit includes sales’ profit, profit
from processing WEEE as well as subsidies, as follows:
The manufacturers profit functions satisfy:
Π iI (q=
qi ( p − u − tiI c ) =
i 1, 2.
i)
To reverse deduce a two-stage game, considering
the manufacturer Cournot game in the second stage,
when given the unit processing expense 𝑑𝑑1𝐼𝐼 , the
manufacturer M 1 can determine its output π‘žπ‘žπ‘π‘πΆπΆ (π‘žπ‘ž2𝐢𝐢 ), then
the response function meets:
q1I (q2I ) =
1 − q2I − u − t1I c
2
(9)
Similarly, the manufacturer M 2 response function
can be deduced. Uniting two functions, Nash
equilibrium solutions follow, respectively:
q1I (t1I , t2I ) =
1 − u + t2I c − 2t1I c I I I
1 − u + t1I c − 2t2I c
; q2 (t1 , t2 ) =
(10)
3
3
T
Π=
qi ( p − u + erc − η c + drc) =
i 1, 2.
i
300
(13)
Res. J. Appl. Sci. Eng. Technol., 6(2): 297-303, 2013
Thereby, the manufacturer through Cournot game,
the Nash equilibrium of sales volume and prices satisfy:
1
(1 − u + cer − cη + drc) i= 1, 2.
3
1 2
2
2
2
pT = + u − cer + cη − drc
3 3
3
3
3
channels, encourage retailers via trade-in or deposit to
recycle waste product etc.
πœ•πœ•π‘‘π‘‘ 𝑐𝑐
πœ•πœ•π‘‘π‘‘ 𝐼𝐼
πœ•πœ•π‘‘π‘‘ 𝑐𝑐
πœ•πœ•π‘‘π‘‘ 𝐼𝐼
Proposition 4: If
< 0,
< 0 π‘Žπ‘Žπ‘Žπ‘Žπ‘Žπ‘Ž
> , it
πœ•πœ•πœ•πœ•
πœ•πœ•πœ•πœ•
πœ•πœ•πœ•πœ•
πœ•πœ•πœ•πœ•
shows that in outsourcing take-back model, the
manufacturers that improve the reuse rate can reduce
the processing costs and the incentive of single
recovery responsibility is more stronger than
qiT =
(14)
At the same time, we can obtain the manufacturer's
profit, consumer’s surplus and the system’s profit in the
model (Table 1).
By comparing optimum values of three models in
Table 1, we have the following Propositions.
the collective recovery responsibility; If 0 <
πœ•πœ•Π πΌπΌπ‘€π‘€
πœ•πœ•Π π‘‡π‘‡
𝑀𝑀
2
πœ•πœ•Π πΆπΆ
𝑀𝑀
πœ•πœ•πœ•πœ•
<
<
= π‘žπ‘žπ‘‡π‘‡ 𝑐𝑐(𝑑𝑑 + 𝑒𝑒) it indicates that T model
πœ•πœ•πœ•πœ•
3
can better motivate manufacturers to improve reuse
rate, In particular, when government gives subsidies.
πœ•πœ•πœ•πœ•
Proposition 1: If t C >𝑑𝑑1𝐼𝐼 , it means that the average
processing costs of the collective recovery model is
always greater than the single recovery model; If
∏𝐢𝐢𝑅𝑅 > ∏𝐼𝐼𝑅𝑅 = ∏𝐼𝐼𝐴𝐴 + ∏𝐼𝐼𝐡𝐡 , it indicates that processing
providers prefer the collective recovery model.
It is easy to see due to the lack of competition and
motility of reducing cost, none but those monopoly
processing providers have a better scale economy, they
will collect a quite low expenses, i.e., only in the
perfect recycling market, the recovery processing costs
will be reduced. The EU experience of take-back
packaging has demonstrated when introducing the
competition mechanism to the recovery processing
industry, the processing cost will be reduced obviously
(Savage et al., 2006).
Proposition 5: If ∏𝐢𝐢𝑆𝑆 > ∏𝐼𝐼𝑆𝑆 > ∏𝑇𝑇𝑆𝑆 , from the profit
maximization of the recycling system, it shows that
optimal model is T, next is model I, the worst is model
C.
It is easy to see from Proposition1, 2, 3, to
consumers, treatment enterprises, manufacturers and
other stakeholders, the preferences of take-back models
are inconsistent, so coordinating the incentive of all
stakeholders is almost impossible. However, whether
they incent to take-back waste products (Proposition 3)
or incent to product design (Proposition 4), our
conclusion shows that T model is optima land
according to the results of Proposition 5, PROs should
first select T model, which manufacturers select
individual take-back model, followed by mode I, the
worst is model C. In fact, by using model T, the
manufacturers can reach integration, internalization of
recovery processing by themselves, reduce middle
circulation channels, low transaction costs, improve the
forward and reverse circulation efficiency, so increase
the overall social welfare.
Proposition 2: If pC>pI>pT, ∏𝑇𝑇𝐢𝐢 > ∏𝐼𝐼𝐢𝐢 > ∏𝐢𝐢𝐢𝐢, it
indicates that the consumers prefer the manufacturers
themselves to take-back model.
In General, manufacturers’ processing funds
charged can be compensated by three ways: part price
transfers to the consumers, profit from the recovery
processing as well as the government subsidies. In T
model, Proposition 2 has shown that the processing
funds have less impact on the equilibrium price and the
recovery processing cost-sharing to consumers is also
less.
Treatment providers: under outsourcing take-back
mode, there are two kinds of market structures in the
recycling industry: the individual take-back model
reflects Cournot competition and the collective takeback model reflects monopolistic competition. Under
the latter kind of situation, the recovery processing
providers, through the game to determine the
processing expenses, where the recovery processing
cost η (Xie and Chen, 2003) includes the disassembling
costs of waste product, the remanufacturing costs,
landfill and collecting costs, etc.
We do not consider the economies of scale of
recovery processing. Suppose that recovery processing
providers may obtain the income e from reusable
product. In outsourcing take-back model, the recovery
processing providers can receive the unit processing
profit is t from the manufactures. To guarantee the
Proposition 3: If ∏𝑇𝑇𝐼𝐼 > ∏𝐼𝐼𝑖𝑖 > ∏𝐢𝐢𝐼𝐼 , it indicates that the
single recovery model is optimal for manufacturers; If
min( ∏𝑇𝑇𝑀𝑀 , ∏𝐼𝐼𝑀𝑀 + ∏𝐼𝐼𝑅𝑅) ≥ (∏𝐢𝐢𝑀𝑀 + ∏𝐢𝐢𝑅𝑅), it means that from
the take-back incentive effect of the manufacturers, the
single recovery model is better than the collective
recovery model.
In reality, Proposition 3 will reflect the recovery
processing should pay more attention to the
manufacturer participated fashion and their role, i.e.,
should encourage manufacturers to participate in takeback; take full advantage of the manufacturers
301
Res. J. Appl. Sci. Eng. Technol., 6(2): 297-303, 2013
Since reuse rate r is close related with the
production technology, we suppose that r is exogenous
variables and r = 1, i.e., full reuse. Let ρ = η-er, we
have the following Proposition 6:
recovery processing providers profitable, so t+er-η≥0.
Let ρ = η-er denotes the net cost of recovery
processing, generally, ρ≥0, the reason may reflect in the
recovery processing’s costs and benefits of pilot
projects. Suppose further that:
•
•
Proposition 6: If 𝜌𝜌 ≥
The processing provider and recovery provider are
regarded as one, i.e., the processing provider’s
work includes take-back and processing of WEEE.
Social surplus (welfare) meets linear additive
condition, i.e., the social welfare (SW) equals to
manufacturer’s profit recovery processing,
providers’ profit + consumer’s surplus +
environmental protectional benefits-Government
expenditures.
1, d =
𝑐𝑐 =
T
•
•
(15)
i
In this way, the social welfare function reflects:
•
max SW (c, d ) = ΠTM + ΠTC + ΠTE − drc∑ qiT
s.t. 0 ≤ c ≤ 1
and when
2
4𝜌𝜌−4𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒 −3πœ€πœ€+3πœ€πœ€πœ€πœ€ −3πœ€πœ€πœ€πœ€
2𝜌𝜌(2𝜌𝜌−3πœ€πœ€)
, when ε≥ρ, then we have c =
4 (1−𝑒𝑒)𝜌𝜌
3 (1−𝑒𝑒+𝜌𝜌)
≤ πœ€πœ€ < 𝜌𝜌, we have
, 𝑑𝑑 = 0; If 𝜌𝜌 <
1−𝑒𝑒
3
, when ε≥ρ,
Proposition 6 shows that the take-back level and
the take-back product catalog require comprehensive
environmental consideration, such as the costs or
benefits of take-back, the market competitive structure
of processing industries and manufacturing industries
etc. The subsidies bear fruit only if the product is
serious harmful to our environment and can be effective
recycled. Subsidies can compensate part of the takeback costs, but also increase the output as well as the
emission of pollutants. Therefore, the PROs
(government) need from two dimensions of the net
processing costs and environmental pollution degree to
weigh the environmental benefit and social profit.
Environmental benefits (costs): Only when the firms
explicitly bring environmental protection costs into
their product design and production, then they are
considered as environmentally friendly design. Usually,
per unit product contains hazardous substances to harm
our environment. The environmental impact or
processing cost of the substances is defined as the
environmental protection cost ε and assuming that the
cost can be monetized (Atasu et al., 2009b). Where
there is harmful to the environment, it will not involve
the recycled part 1-c and port (1-r)c after recovery
processing, so the environmental protection benefit is as
follows:
(∑ q )
3
we have c = 1, d = 1-u-ρ/2 and when ε<ρ, we have c =
0, d = 0.
The implementation decision-making of the WEEE
regulations: Considering PROs have selected the
optimal take-back model T by using the recovery rate c,
reuse rate r and subsidies d, we can restrict or incent the
recycling behavior of manufacturers to achieve social
welfare SW maximization and balance economic and
environmental impacts (Jacobs and Subramanian,
2009). The social welfare implicated by those factors
should include the following items:
Subsidy expenditure: to encourage manufacturers
to take-back WEEE, PROs pay the manufacturers unit
subsidies d, then the total subsidies are drc∑π‘žπ‘žπ‘–π‘–π‘‡π‘‡ .
Π E =−ε (1 − rc )
1−𝑒𝑒−𝜌𝜌
1−𝑒𝑒
(16)
d ≥0
302
Voluntary take-back: Usually, that means
products are less environmental pollution and takeback costs are relatively small, through selfdiscipline of manufacturers and the consumer's
environmental drive to set recycling goals. And
without no legal requirement to comply or unmeet
recycling targets, firms will not be punished. For
instance, carpet take-back in US Savage et al.
(2006)
Incomplete take-back: That means the product
has the slight environmental pollution, but the takeback costs are higher. Government does not give
subsidies, so use the incomplete take-back targets
to protect the manufacturers or consumers benefits,
such as the WEEE in home appliances. The
products because of high processing costs,
economies of scale has certain requirements, so
manufacturers may be outsourced the take-back
activities to the professional service provider,
especially to small and medium manufacturers, i.e.,
T model will transforms to I model.
Complete take-back: That means the product has
heavy environmental pollution, no matter how high
processing cost, it is mandatory take-back by the
government regulation and government gives some
subsidies to the processing firm. For example,
waste oil, waste paint etc.
Res. J. Appl. Sci. Eng. Technol., 6(2): 297-303, 2013
Jacobs, B. and R. Subramanian, 2009. The Impacts of
Sharing Responsibility for Product Recovery
Across the Supply Chain. Working Paper, Georgia
Institute of Technology.
Mayers, C.K., 2007. Strategic, financial and design
implications of extended producer responsibility in
Europe: A producer case study. J. Ind. Ecol., 11(3):
113-131.
Mitra, S. and S. Webster, 2008. Competition in
remanufacturing and the effects of government
subsidies. Int. J. Prod. Econ., 111(2): 287-298.
Savage, M., S. Ogilvie and J. Slezak, 2006.
Implementation of the waste electric and electronic
equipment directive in EU 25. Institute for
Prospective Technological Studies (IPTS),
European Commission Joint Research Centre,
Technical Report Series EUR 22231 EN, ISBN:
92-79-01926-0.
Savaskan, R.C., S. Bhattacharya and L.N. Van
Wassenhove, 2004. Closed-loop supply chain
models with product remanufacturing. Manag. Sci.,
50(2): 239-252.
Subramanian, R., S. Gupta and B. Talbot, 2009.
Product design and supply chain coordination
under extended producer responsibility. Prod.
Oper. Manag., 18(3): 259-277.
Toffel, M.W., 2003. The growing strategic importance
of end-of-life product management. California
Manag. Rev., 45(3): 102-129.
Tojo, N., T. Lindhqvist and G.A. Davis, 2001. EPR
programme implementation: Institutional and
structural factors. Proceedings of OECD Seminar
on Extended Producer Responsibility: EPR
Programme Implementation and Assessment. Paris,
pp: 226-275.
Toyasaki, F., T. Boyaci and V. Verter, 2008. An
Analysis of Monopolistic and Competitive Takeback Schemes for WEEE Recycling. Working
Paper, McGill University.
Wang, Z.H. and J. Yin, 2008. An analysis of the
influences and characteristics of the behavior of
electric waste reclaiming in China’s household
appliances industry. Manag. World, 4: 175-176.
Xie, J. and R. Chen, 2003. The cost-benefit analysis
model of recovery processing in reverse logistics of
assembly product. China Bus. Market, 1: 25-28.
Yang, J.X., B. Lu and C. Xu, 2008. WEEE flow and
mitigating measures in China. Waste Manag., 28:
1589-1597.
CONCLUSION
The elements and process of current WEEE Takeback Directive are analyzed in the current regulations.
And by using a two-stage sequential decision-making
game model, the economic behavior of the main
stakeholders fewer than three different types of takeback models are presented in this study. Our conclusion
demonstrates that: The preferences of three take-back
modes for manufacturers, treatment enterprises,
consumers and other stakeholders are inconsistent, but
from the view of take-back incentive, product design
incentives, the system profits, we find that
manufacturers’ individual take-back model is optimal.
Therefore, the most efficient recycling network system
should focus on the manufacturers’ individual recovery
responsibility, make full use of their channel advantage,
encourage retailers by trade-in or deposit to recycle the
waste products, etc.; To determine the take-back level
and recovery product catalog, it is necessary to consider
the impact on the environment, take-back
costs/benefits, the market competitive structure of
processing industries and manufacturing industries as
well as consumers acceptance of environmental costs,
etc.; The government must weigh the environmental
protection benefits and social benefits. Effective
subsidies only utilize in the product has great harmful
to environment and fully take-back. When product has
slight pollution, according to the size of the net
processing cost, incomplete take-back or the voluntary
take-back is considered, respectively.
ACKNOWLEDGMENT
This study is supported by the National Natural
Science Foundation of China (NSFC) (Project nos.
70971111; 71201138) and the Young Foundation of
Ministry of Education of China in 2012 project (Project
nos.12YJC630264) and the Fujian Provincial Natural
Science Foundation Project (2012J01304).
REFERENCES
Atasu, A. and R. Subramanian, 2009a. Competition
under product take-back laws: Individual or
collective systems? Working Paper, Georgia
Institute of Technology.
Atasu, A., L.N. Van Wassenhove and M. Sarvary,
2009b. Efficient take-back legislation. Prod. Oper.
Manag., 18(3): 243-258.
Future Energy Solutions, 2003. Study into European
WEEE schemes. Study into European WEEE
Schemes. Report to U.K. Department of Trade and
Industry (November). Retrieved from: http://
164.36.164.20/sustaina bility/weee/aeatreport.pdf.
303
Download