The UK experience with sectoral policies Helen Miller

advertisement
The UK experience with sectoral policies
Helen Miller
Expert workshop – 21-22 May 2012, IPTS, Sevilla
© Institute for Fiscal Studies
Outline
• Brief overview of UK position and policy
• Main examples of UK sectoral policies
– Technology strategy board
– Enterprise Zones
• Should the UK have a new industrial policy?
– current debate and evidence
– are horizontal policies sufficient or is there a need for sectoral
support?
© Institute for Fiscal Studies
Features of the UK
• growth has come less from high/med tech firms and more from
knowledge intensive sectors and service firms
– since the mid 1990s investment is higher in intangible that tangible
assets
© Institute for Fiscal Studies
Percentage contribution to growth in GVA, 1992-2007
Taken from BIS (2011a), based on OECD STAN database
© Institute for Fiscal Studies
Investment in innovation; share of market sector GVA
Taken from Nesta Innovation
Index (2009)
© Institute for Fiscal Studies
Features of the UK
• growth has come less from high/med tech firms and more from
knowledge intensive sectors and service firms
– since the mid 1990s investment is higher in intangible that tangible
assets
• UK has a relatively strong science base
– high share of publications and citations
– science spending was increased under previous government
• large share of involvement of foreign investors and collaborators
• but notably low R&D intensity
– 1.6% of GDP in 2007
© Institute for Fiscal Studies
UK policy motivation
• Motivation usually based on understanding of and focus on
market failures
– externalities; information asymmetries; institutional deficiencies;
coordination failure; system failures
– true of recent policy - 'Innovation and Research Strategy for Growth―
(2011)
• Main policies have tended to be horizontal
– higher education and skills; competition policy; infrastructure;
regulatory framework ; IPR; tax policy
– R&D tax credits and science budget account for larger spending than
policies aimed at specific sectors
– there a many smaller policies that have a sectoral flavour. Includes
direct spending, advice and information, finance provision, prizes
© Institute for Fiscal Studies
What is the aim of sectoral policy?
• Two types of aims motivating sectoral policies
– sector specific market failures
– desires to encourage high growth potential sectors
• Example – support for UK biotechnology sector
– support during the 1990s in the form of funding collaborative R&D,
mentoring and advice , training grants, organising events
– motivated by externalities / coordination failure / lack knowledge by
new firms/ lack of economies of scale
– true of a range of industries
– evaluation suggests policies had some effect, but were not key
determinants of UK‖s success
© Institute for Fiscal Studies
Technology Strategy Board
•
Administers most policies with sectoral dimension
•
“aim to help turn the emerging technologies of today into the growth
sectors of tomorrow for UK business”
•
“develops technology strategies and makes choices on the allocation of
funding to particular sectors markets and challenges, as well as to
emerging technologies, by taking a strategic view of where UK
capability exists and where future opportunities may emerge.”
• Policies:
– promote collaboration (invest in collaborative projects)
– Knowledge Transfer Networks / Partnerships
– direct investment in projects in ―focus areas‖
– technology centres : Innovation and Knowledge Centres; Catapult
centres
© Institute for Fiscal Studies
UK sectoral policies – comments
• Lots of relatively small polices - usually small sums of money
• Piecemeal approach
– are policies targeting the same problem?
– need to consider other policies (e.g. tax policy/ regulation )
• Policy changes regularly
– hard for businesses to know what is available
– often change in line with political cycles
• Lack of systematic evaluation
© Institute for Fiscal Studies
Regional policy - Enterprise Zones
• 21 new enterprise Zones (EZ) announced in 2011
– aim: boost local growth and create jobs
– features: 100% business rates relief for 5 years (revenue cost 201415: £65m); simplified planning; support for fast broadband;
potentially enhanced capital allowances and UKTI support.
– each has a ―sectoral focus‖
• The UK had EZ from the early 1980s until mid 1990s
– features: reductions in business rates, relaxed planning, often
alongside infrastructure investment.
– focused on areas with large patches of unused land – often where an
industrial industry had closed.
• Motivation – equity vs efficiency ?
© Institute for Fiscal Studies
Evaluation of Enterprise Zones
• EZ tended to increase firms and jobs, but this was largely the
result of displacement from other neighboring areas
– evaluations: PA Cambridge Economic Consultants (1995); Potter J &
Moore B (2000); Jones C (2006)
• Per job the scheme was expensive
– government-funded evaluation: cost of £23,000 per new job (PA
Cambridge Economics (1987))
– estimate for the original 11 zones: cost at £45,000 per new job
(Schwarz and Volgy (1988))
• US states – most operate enterprise zones, each with slightly
different focus & policies
– evaluation mixed, some find some success. (Bondonio D & Engberg J
(1999); Papke (2003) ; Busso M & Kline P (2007))
– more focus on unemployment and low skills than on property and
infrastructure
© Institute for Fiscal Studies
What did we learn?
•
policy details are really important
– EZ most likely to work when designed with a clear rational for
government intervention
– it matters where the zones are
• “accessible” zones attracted highest proportion of inward investing firms
(Potter & Moore (2000))
• Canary Wharf identified as a success story
• Tax incentives can be effective, but are easily offset by other cost
differentials
• ‘Focusing public expenditure on “turning around” declining
places has not worked; policy should instead focus primarily on
people (e.g. through skills investment), improving incentives and
removing regulatory barriers’ Henry Overman (LSE)
© Institute for Fiscal Studies
Other regional policies
•
Regional selective assistance (RSA), 1972-2004
– discretionary grant to private sector (manufacturing) firms for primarily
capital investment projects
– aims: address labour market inequalities; safeguard ―at risk‖ jobs;
– became Selective Finance for Investment – increase productivity and
proportion of skilled jobs
•
BERR (2008)
– positive effect of RSA on employment growth; increased productivity, skills &
technical capability
•
Criscuolo, Martin, Overman and Van Reenen (2012)
– positive program treatment effect of RSA on employment, investment and net
entry but not on TFP
•
Devereux, Griffith and Simpson (2007)
– positive but small effect in attracting new plants to specific areas
– a region's existing industrial structure affects location of new entrants
© Institute for Fiscal Studies
A new industrial policy?
• Idea of a new industrial policy has gained prominence recently
• Aim to ―rebalance the economy‖
– concerns that too much investment in financial and business services
and not enough in tradable goods
• ―We shouldn't be shy about identifying our successful industries
and reinforcing them’ - George Osborne , 2012 budget
• Sectors identified in ―The plan for Growth‖:
– healthcare and life sciences; advanced manufacturing; construction;
digital and creative industries; retail; professional and business
services; the space industry; tourism
• What does sector support mean?
© Institute for Fiscal Studies
Justification for govt intervention
• Traditional arguments against sectoral policies:
– prevents competition, encourages governments to ―pick winners‖ (or
losers)
– often implemented without a clear justification
– what can the government actually achieve (are there appropriate
policy levers? ), does it have more information than the market?
– risk of capture and rent seeking
© Institute for Fiscal Studies
Support for idea of an industrial policy
• Government ... ―needs to scan ahead to where Britain has
comparative advantage in the growth industries of the future and
do its level best to remove barriers to the growth of these sectors
and to at all costs avoid putting up new ones.‖
John Van Reenen, LSE
• “If the EU is to grow and compete globally, there is a case for the
European Commission to allow national or EU sectoral aid, if it is
appropriately designed and governed to encourage the redirection
of innovation and production. Horizontal support and sectoral aid
for upstream research and development are on their own not
sufficient to foster the transformation of the European economy.”
Aghion, Boulanger, Cohen (2011)
© Institute for Fiscal Studies
Support for idea of an industrial policy
Philip Aghion (Havard) – need to rethink industrial policy. Why?
• climate change - role for government to redirect technical change
(innovations are path dependent)
– alongside a carbon price
– remove subsidies for dirty energy
• credit constraints in high tech areas (intangible assets)
– this will be true for a range of sectors
• China is a big (and successful) deployer of sectoral aid
– need good evaluation of policies (why they worked and why they would be
useful in other countries). Lots of examples of failure (Latin America)
– are sectoral policies more important if other countries have them?
• inefficient growth of non-tradable sectors at the expense of
tradables
– what determines what counts as ―inefficient growth‖?
– is an industrial policy the right solution?
© Institute for Fiscal Studies
Sector shares of total economy GVA
Taken from Corry, Valero, Van Reenen (2011), Figure 4.
© Institute for Fiscal Studies
Support for idea of an industrial policy
• Philip Aghion (Havard) – policy implications:
– sectoral aid targeted at green tech/ skill intensive/competitive sectors
• Nunn and Trefler (2010) find that tariff protection that is biased towards
skill intensive sectors is positively correlated with productivity growth
(~25% causation)
– not biased towards individual firms & not at the expense of
competition
• Aghion, Dewatripont, Du, Harrison, and Legros (2012) consider Chinese
firms and state aid . Find (i) the more competitive the sector the more
positive the effect of subsidies on TFP growth and product innovation in
that sector (ii) greater effect when state aid is less concentrated
• export oriented as a way to encourage competition?
•
Still (for the most part) grounded in rationale that there are knowledge
spillovers / market failures
•
More discussion is needed of the design of industrial policies
© Institute for Fiscal Studies
Discussion: a role for sectoral support?
• There may be some role for sectoral policies
– especially where there are specific market failures / specific solutions
– in effect many policies have a sectoral dimension
But:
• there are first order things that need to get right (e.g. skills)
– UK: 10% real terms cuts to science base over next 4 years
• there needs to be a clear justification
– whether horizontal policies are sufficient will depend on the problem
– example - innovative firms in Germany and UK
© Institute for Fiscal Studies
Discussion: a role for sectoral support?
• is industrial policy the right tool?
– how does a government identify sectors?
– are the same solutions required for a range of sectors?
– are there other policies that should be removed? (subsidies for coal)
– do other policies target the same problem? (R&D grants and tax credits)
– does the government have sufficient information and policy tools?
• what should a sectoral policy look like? How to design?
– not at the expense of competition /broad based
– which policies (direct funding/ information / prizes etc.)?
– how long should support last (and what determines this)?
– need to conduct and learn from evaluation
© Institute for Fiscal Studies
Discussion: a role for sectoral support?
• consider interactions with other policies / country features
• limited benefits to plethora of small polices that change regularly
– need an approach that considers government policy as a whole
• what role does the EU play?
© Institute for Fiscal Studies
References
• BIS (2011a) ECONOMICS PAPER NO. 15, Innovation and Research
Strategy for Growth, December 2011
• BIS (2011b) Innovation and Research Strategy for Growth,
December 2011
Regional Policy
• PA Cambridge Economic Consultants Ltd (PACEC) (1987) An
Evaluation of the Enterprise Zone Experiment (London: HMSO).
• Jones C (2006) ―Verdict on the British Enterprise Zone
Experiment‖, International Planning Studies,11:2,109 —123
• PA Cambridge Economic Consultants (1995) Final Evaluation of
Enterprise Zones. [referenced a lot but I can‖t find a copy of this]
• Potter J & Moore B (2000) ―UK Enterprise Zones and the
Attraction of Inward Investment.‖ Urban Studies, 37(8): 12791312.
© Institute for Fiscal Studies
References
• Busso M & Kline P (2007) ―Do Local Economic Development
Programs Work?Evidence from the Federal Empowerment Zone
Program.‖ SSRN Working Paper Series
• Bondonio D & Engberg J (1999) ―Enterprise Zones and Local
Employment: Evidence from the States‖ Programs.‖
• Papke L (2003) Tax Policy and the Economy, 7: 37-72
• BERR (2008), Evaluation of Regional Selective, BERR
OCCASIONAL PAPER NO. 2, March 2008
• Criscuolo, C., R. Martin, H. Overman and J. Van Reenen (2012)
―The Causal Effects of an Industrial Policy‖ , NBER Working Papers
• Devereux, Griffith and Simpson (2007), ‘Firm location decisions,
regional grants and agglomeration externalities’, Journal of Public
Economics 91 413–435.
© Institute for Fiscal Studies
References
Industrial Policy
• Aghion, Boulanger, Cohen (2011), ―Rethinking Industrial Policy‖,
Brugel Policy brief
• Corry, Valero, Van Reenen (2011), UK economics performance
since 1997: Growth, productivity and Jobs
• Nunn and Trefler (2010) , American Economic Journal:
Macroeconomics : 158–194
• Aghion, Dewatripont, Du, Harrison, and Legros (2012), Industrial
Policy and Competition, NBER Working Paper No. 18048
© Institute for Fiscal Studies
Download