The role of capital requirements in macroprudential policy Javier Suarez CEMFI

advertisement
The role of capital requirements in macroprudential policy
Javier Suarez
CEMFI
Conference on Financial Stability and Macroprudential Policy
Banco de Portugal, 10 February 2015
1
Introduction
• Macroprudential policy is a reality (authorities+tools)
• The goals are clear
• We are in a hurry to complete the institutional architecture
2
• Pressure to respond to prior weaknesses has produced an overly complex architecture
• There has been no time to fully understand foundations, implications, degree of substitutability, and the most suitable calibration of
the candidate tools
• It is unclear questions on their “expected effects” and “when to
activate them” can be properly answered at the moment
3
• We understand what the macroprudential approach is meant to be,
but I am not sure we know which tools should be truly assigned to
macroprudential policy
• Is it all about touching specific tools? Or about fine-tuning structural
regulations taking the macroprudential trade-offs in mind?
• We now face a long learning-by-doing period in the implementation
of macroprudential policy
4
• In this setup, analytical frameworks constitute the other big alternative to advance in the process
— They can help explore the logical connections between candidate
tools and the moving parts of the system
— They can assist in the design and communication of the new
policies and improve their accountability
• The development of these frameworks is still at its infancy but has
already yielded some valuable fruit
5
• I am going to devote the rest of my talk to comment on papers that
I know first hand
• They deal with capital requirements (CRs) and the convenience or
not of cyclically adjusting them
• Some of the unexpected results of these papers constitute a call-forcaution
• I will conclude with a critical assessment of the results and a brief
thought on the debate about rules vs. discretion in macroprudential
policy
6
Paper 1 (“The Procyclical Effects of Bank Capital Regulation” with
R. Repullo, Review of Financial Studies, 2013)
• Analyzes the procyclicality induced by capital requirements in a
model of relationship banking with a simple time structure
— Borrowers need loans for two consecutive periods and become
dependent on their initial lenders (banks)
— These lenders cannot issue equity in between the two periods and
may lose the capital needed to extend the 2nd period loans
• As a precaution, banks may start holding voluntary buffers of capital
on top of the regulatory minimum (γ s)
• The credit cycle is captured as 2-state Markov chain for the PDs of
the loans (s=l: low PD; s=h: high PD)
⇒ the IRB approach implies γ h > γ l
7
• Basel II produces larger expected credit rationing than Basel I (esp.
after s=h) but, importantly, it also reduces the probability of bank
failure (esp. in s=h)
• Net impact on welfare depends on the social cost of bank failure (c)
W 0.0975
0.0925
0.0875
0.0825
0.00
0.10
0.20
0.30
Basel I
Laissez-faire
0.40
0.50
Basel II
Optimal requirements
0.60
c
— Basel 1 Â Basel II for very low c
— Basel II requirements ' socially optimal γs for c ' 0.25
8
Optimal γ s vs social cost of bank failure c
8%
γs
7%
6%
5%
4%
3%
2%
1%
0%
0.00
0.10
0.20
0.30
0.40
0.50
0.60
c
Basel II, s=l
Optimal, s=l
Basel II, s=h
Optimal, s=h
[Basel III seems a good idea for c > 0.30:
optimal γ s are higher but less cyclically varying]
9
Paper 2 (“Banks’ Endogenous Systemic Risk Taking” with D. MartinezMiera, 2014)
• Simple macroeconomic model where some investments fail when a
rare event occurs
• Systemic risk results from banks’ voluntary exposure to these investments, which are attractive to them due to standard risk-shifting
incentives of levered firms [“Heads we win, tails you lose”]
• Although systemic risk taking is unobservable ex ante, a capital requirement (γ) helps ameliorating banks’ gambling incentives through:
— Standard leverage-reduction effect
— A last bank standing effect (Perotti-Suarez 2002): bankers’ greater
incentive to preserve wealth when other bankers are losing it
[Bankers’ wealth e is needed for banks to comply with CRs]
10
Equilibrium dynamics with low and optimal γ
Equilibrium dynamics (CR=7%)
Equilibrium dynamics (CR=14%)
3
3
2.5
Dynamics if shock realizes
Dynamics if shock realizes
Aggregate bank capital at t+1
Aggregate bank capital at t+1
Dynamics if no shock realizes
Dynamics if no shock realizes
2.5
45-degree line
2
1.5
1
0.5
45-degree line
2
1.5
1
0.5
0
0
0
0.5
1
1.5
Aggregate bank capital at t
2
2.5
0
(γ =7%)
0.5
1
1.5
Aggregate bank capital at t
2
2.5
(γ =14%)
• With higher CRs bankers gamble less and a shock implies a lower
loss of bankers’ wealth e (aggregate bank capital)...
• But levels of economic activity are lower ⇒ interior optimal γ
11
What happens if γ is cyclically adjusted?
[higher when e is high, lower when e is low]
• The partial equilibrium logic points to a decline in the credit crunch
that follows a systemic event
• However, the adjustment weakens the last bank standing effect and
banks, in anticipation of this, gamble more
⇒ The partial equilibrium prediction gets off-set or even reversed
∴ Countercyclical adjustments may be destabilizing!
12
Paper 3 (“Capital Regulation in a Macroeconomic Model with Three
Layers of Default” MaRs Model Team∗, 2014)
[∗Clerc, Derviz, Mendicino, Moyen, Nikolov, Stracca, Suarez, Vardoulakis]
• Model in DSGE tradition with microfounded intermediaries
— All external financing is based on debt subject to default risk
— Default produces deadweight losses; final borrowers borrow an
endogenous multiple of their net worth
• Banks enjoy deposit insurance and neglect their contribution to deposit insurance costs as well as to the residual pricing of their failure
risk by depositors...
— underprice default risk, potentially leading agents to overborrow
— their leverage is controlled by the regulatory CRs
13
• Banks satisfy CRs with equity funding provided by bankers using
endogenously accumulated wealth
— Negative shocks increase bank failure rates and get amplified by
a channel connected to banks’ financial vulnerability
— CRs are effective in shutting down bank-related amplification channels, but at a cost in terms of the level of economic activity
⇒ interior optimal CRs (levels)
14
Are countercyclical capital buffers a good idea?
D e p r e c ia tio n S h o c k
G D P (8 % C a p ita l R e q u ire m e n t)
G D P (1 0 .5 % C a p ita l R e q u ire m e n t)
0.2
0.2
0
0
-0 . 2
-0 . 2
-0 . 4
-0 . 6
-0 . 6
-0 . 8
-0 . 8
-1
per cent
per cent
-0 . 4
CCB
R e le a s e
NO CCB
R e le a s e
-1
-1 . 2
-1 . 2
-1 . 4
-1 . 4
-1 . 6
-1 . 6
-1 . 8
-1 . 8
-2
5
10
15
q u a rt e rs
20
25
-2
30
CCB
R e le a s e
NO CCB
R e le a s e
5
10
15
q u a rt e rs
20
25
30
Underlying trade-off: (+) potentially smaller fall in credit supply; (-) higher bank default rate
• With HIGH baseline CRs, overall margin for improvement!
• With LOW baseline CRs, (+) short-run effect is off-set by destabilizing long-run effect
15
This question is further addressed (under a proper calibration and an
explicit “stochastic welfare” calculation) in a new paper
(“Designing Capital Regulation in a Quantitative Macroeconomic Model”
with C. Medicino, K. Nikolov and D. Supera, 2015)
• Key qualitative result is confirmed: CCB is a good idea only when
CRs are high enough to start with
• When overall desirable, its impact on the welfare of borrowers (↑)
and lenders (↓) is asymmetric
• Its total contribution to the gains associated with optimally designed
CRs (level+risk weights+CCB) is modest
16
Conclusions
• Some of the existing analytical frameworks offer good rationales for
prudential tools and allow for a model-based assessment of the contribution coming from adding some explicit macroprudential ingredient to the basic tool
• The reviewed papers identify advantages & disadvantages associated
with the cyclical adjustment of capital requirements:
— If excessive or applied to CRs that are too low to start with, the
effects can be counterproductive
— From this perspective, the Basel III approach (CCB as a releasable
add-on) seems a good compromise
17
• The reviewed papers abstract from asset price bubbles and bank
panics, potentially understating the role of macroprudential policy,
esp. regarding the detection and fight against unsustainable developments
• At the current state of knowledge, simple and recurrently revised
rules (which operate like “automatic stabilizers”) can & should be
seen as complementary to the continuous surveillance of the system
and the willingness to act on a discretionary basis
18
Download