Economic Strategies to Reduce Acid Deposition:

advertisement
Tammy Coe
Ecological Economic Theory
Fall 2003
Economic Strategies to Reduce Acid Deposition:
A Review of Current Policy Initiatives
Externalities were first recognized in Pigou’s (1920) Economics of Welfare as
costs that society incurs, which are not reflected in market transactions. For the most part
externalities were considered an abnormal market failure until Ayres and Kneese (1969)
presented evidence to the fact that environmental externalities – “those associated with
the disposal of residuals resulting from the consumption and production process” – were
an inevitable part of resource use. The laws of thermodynamics tell us that processes that
use stocks of raw materials and convert them to other forms must result in waste. No
conversion of energy is 100% efficient; therefore, when natural resources are taken from
the environment and employed to make consumer goods, waste results from the material
transformations. This waste or pollution is returned to the environment. Most consumer
products do not reflect the costs associated with this waste disposal and society bears the
cost in terms of health effects and degraded ecosystems.
This paper outlines one of the many externalities associated with fossil fuel
consumption – acid deposition – and the issues involved with developing policies to
control it. Acid deposition is an excellent example of an environmental externality
because it has attributes characteristic of many pollution problems in that it is a nonlocalized problem that crosses political boundaries; has effects that can reach well into
the future; and has multiple point and non-point, natural and anthropogenic sources.
Because of these and other issues, policymakers struggle to find effective ways to
regulate such externalities. Using the example of fossil fuel consumption and acid
deposition, this paper reviews the three main economic strategies that seek to internalize
the cost of environmental externalities: command and control strategies, environmental
taxes, and tradable permit systems.
EXTERNALITIES OF FOSSIL FUEL CONSUMPTION
Electricity production and transportation are two areas where environmental
externalities abound. In our consumption of fossil fuels, humans produce emissions that
1
Tammy Coe
Ecological Economic Theory
Fall 2003
affect public goods and the cost of these effects are not borne by the person receiving the
benefits of the fossil fuel use. Fossil fuel consumption has environmental externalities
associated with every phase of use from extraction and refining to transportation and
distribution. This paper will focus on the post-distribution externalities associated with
the conversion of fossil fuels to useable energy. Emissions from fossil fuel burning
include several greenhouse gases (carbon dioxide, methane, carbon monoxide, other
hydrocarbons), particulate matter, trace metals, and gases that produce acid rain (sulfur
dioxide (SO2) and nitrogen oxides (NOX)). These pollutants have detrimental effects on
human health, ecological systems, and built capital that are not reflected in the
consumers’ price for fossil fuels.
SO2 and NOX (including nitrous oxide, nitrogen dioxide, and nitric oxide) emitted
from fossil fuel burning are released into the atmosphere where they react with water to
form sulfuric and nitric acids. This anthropogenic acidification process leads to effects on
human health, built capital, and ecosystems. Human health effects include increased
respiratory problems due to inhalation of dry particles and increased formation of
tropospheric ozone via NOX compounds (U.S. EPA, 2003). Acid rain also has an effect
on buildings and construction materials exposed to low pH precipitation over time. Paint,
brick, and stone are degraded at faster rates when exposed to acids, thereby accelerating
their natural deterioration processes. This can lead to the loss of historic buildings and
sculptures and increased economic costs associated with the shorter lifespan of
construction materials and restoration efforts (McGee, 2003). Aquatic ecosystems feel the
effects of acid deposition through decreased pH of their waters. As these systems become
more acidic, many organisms cannot survive, thus leading to habitat loss for pH sensitive
species. Also increased nitrogen inputs from NOX emissions enhance eutrophication of
aquatic systems. In terrestrial environments, acid deposition depletes calcium (Ca) in
soils and directly leaches physiologically important pools of Ca from foliage. In forested
ecosystems, this loss of Ca leads to an increased vulnerability to environmental stressors
like cold temperatures, disease, and drought, which can ultimately lead to forest decline
(Schaberg et al. 2001).
2
Tammy Coe
Ecological Economic Theory
Fall 2003
ISSUES AFFECTING POLICY FORMATION
Like many environmental problems, acid deposition has many attributes that
make policy implementation difficult. It is a non-localized problem that crosses political
borders. In the United States Midwestern states are major producers of SO2 and NOX
emissions from large coal-fired power plants. Air currents transport the pollutants outside
of state and regional borders until they are released over Northeastern states.
Northeastern states are receiving detrimental effects of the pollution without receiving the
benefits of purchasing power from these plants. Regulating a non-localized externality
such as acid deposition means forging a relationship between the environmental regulator
(in this case, the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency) and the public utilities. These
two groups have conflicting interests. The EPA is responsible for achieving an acceptable
balance between abatement technologies and environmental damage while the public
utilities are responsible for pricing their product based on production costs (including
abatement) (Baron 1985). In some cases in Europe and Asia, acid deposition is an
international problem. Emissions from Chinese coal-fired power plants reach Japan; and
European nations trade pollution problems in the same manner as U.S. states (Wetstone
and Rosencrantz, 1983).
The components of acid deposition have many sources including natural and
anthropogenic, point and non-point sources, adding another difficulty to policy
formation. Natural sources of NOX include bacterial activity, wildfires and lightening,
while SO2 is emitted from wetlands, oceans and volcanoes. Policymakers must adjust
their emissions standards based on these natural background levels of these compounds.
Many policies that attempt to mitigate the externalities of fossil fuel burning focus on
point source emitters, like power plants, because it is much easier to monitor and regulate
a stationary source. Mobile sources, like automobiles, are more difficult to control, thus
creating an equity problem – how can the government tell power plants to control
emissions or pay a fine, when people are driving more cars that are increasingly larger
and less fuel-efficient without paying any fines for their pollution?
Another issue involved with creating policies to address acid deposition is
uncertainty. What is the acceptable level of pollution in terms of human and ecosystem
3
Tammy Coe
Ecological Economic Theory
Fall 2003
health effects? How much is pollution “costing” society in terms of human health
problems and loss of ecosystem services? Can these values be quantified in monetary
terms? These are the difficult questions policymakers address when faced with regulating
pollutants. Several studies have been conducted to quantify these externalities in terms of
a monetary value. The cost of environmental damage ranges from $0.13-$9.15 per pound
of SO2 and $0.02-$12.25 per pound of NOX in terms of 1989 U.S. dollars (Koomey and
Krause, 1997). As evident from the large range of values, there is much uncertainty in
determining monetary values for ecosystem services damaged by human actions.
Ecosystems are dynamic systems with several feedback loops making it difficult to
accurately predict outcomes of events. In economic terms the best-case scenario for
policymakers would be to find the point where the marginal cost of emitting one more
pound of pollution would equal the marginal benefit of services gained from the impacted
ecosystems. Any ecologist will tell you that determining this point is impossible, yet
when policymakers contact ecologists for their expert advice that is precisely what they
are looking for – that “magic” level of pollution that is acceptable to both economic and
environmental health. Despite the problems associated with formulating policies to
address acid deposition, three major economic strategies have been developed and
utilized throughout the world: command and control techniques, environmental taxes, and
tradable permit systems.
COMMAND AND CONTROL STRATEGIES
One method employed to manage pollution is a command-and-control (CAC)
strategy where regulatory agencies set emissions standards or abatement levels and
enforce monetary fines on those who do not comply with the standards. Ideally the fines
are used to pay for damages associated with the pollution. As stated earlier, problems
arise with uncertainties about appropriate levels at which to set standards. How much
pollution is acceptable to humans and sustainable for ecosystems? Once an appropriate
limit is determined, regulation is reasonable – monitor the polluters for compliance and
fine those sources which exceed the defined emissions standard or abatement level.
4
Tammy Coe
Ecological Economic Theory
Fall 2003
Japan has the strictest CAC policies aimed at a reduction in SO2 and NOX
emissions. In 1968 Japanese authorities set limits for acceptable concentrations of NOX
and SO2. The daily average of hourly values is the lowest in the world – pollutant levels
cannot exceed 0.02 ppm for NOX and 0.04 ppm for SO2 (Wetstone and Rosencrantz,
1983). To meet these strict standards, Japan became the first nation to require power
plants and factories to use both SO2 and NOX abatement technologies. They also invoked
the CAC strategy of setting limits for SO2 emissions at the largest pollution sources and
collecting fees from those that do not comply. The main impetus for setting these
standards was to reduce human health effects so the fees collected were used to fund the
medical care of patients suffering from the effects of air pollution (Morishima, 1999). In
addition to CAC strategies, Japan also imposes a tax on vehicles related to the amount of
pollution they release and a lower sales tax on vehicles powered by electricity or
methanol.
Kochi et al. (1999) conducted cost-benefit analyses on the Japanese SO2 fee
policy using values of human health effects as the benefits gained from pollution
reduction. They found that since its induction in 1968, the ratio of benefits to costs has
been on the decline. During the first five years this ratio was 3.32, from 1974-1983 it
dropped significantly to 0.80; and from 1983-1993 it again fell to 0.28. In terms of human
health benefits, it appears that CAC strategies are only cost-effective in their early stages.
This may be due to a lack of incentives to reduce pollution below the mandated limits.
Once the limits are reached, no further reductions are necessary so pollution remains at
the set levels. The early stages of regulation prompted the private sector to develop
abatement technologies that were less expensive than the steep fines imposed by the
government and an insurgence of new technologies came into the market, including fuel
desulfurization processes, fuel conversion to liquefied natural gas, and sulfur scrubbers to
remove SO2 from emissions. Eventually marginal costs of incrementally reducing
pollution (via technological advancements for abatement) exceed the marginal benefits
gained from human health protection. The CAC strategy of SO2 fees was responsible for
producing new technologies and cleaning up the most populated areas of Japan, however
it appears that now other strategies may be necessary if Japan is to further reduce their
impacts.
5
Tammy Coe
Ecological Economic Theory
Fall 2003
In contrast to Japan, China’s CAC strategies have proven to be only marginally
successful in cleaning up their acid deposition problem. Similar to Japan, the Chinese
Environmental Protection Bureau (EPB) set ambient air quality standards, conducted
dispersion models to estimate impacts from their largest sources, and set individual levels
for specific polluters (Raufer, 1999). Fees collected from polluters exceeding their
pollution allowance were supposed to be used to for additional pollution abatement at
sources. However, funds collected from SO2 fees have never exceeded administrative
costs of implementing the program.
There are several reasons why China’s policies failed and Japan’s succeeded.
Limits and fees set by the Chinese authorities are not severe enough to elicit change.
Ambient air standards for SO2 are set at 0.06 ppm for residential areas and 0.10 ppm for
industrialized sectors. Monitoring efforts in 1999 (Wu et al. 2000) showed that 33% of all
suburbanized areas exceeded the 0.06 ppm standard. This points out one of the failures of
the system: if fees are not high enough, it may be more cost-effective to industries to pay
the fine rather than reduce their emissions. China followed Japan’s lead and based their
fee structure on human health effects. However, the value placed on a human life in
China was a nominal 270 US$, resulting in very low fees for non-compliance (Wu et al.
2000). Another criticism of China’s CAC strategy is poor regulatory systems. Studies
have often shown that China’s EPB is more concerned with pursuing production goals
and economic growth rather than environmental protection (Raufer, 1999). In 2000 China
agreed to accept Japanese aid in developing air pollution control strategies. Currently the
government is working on a cap-and trade system similar to the one in the U.S. discussed
in a later section of this paper. This is good news for Japan and other Asian nations since
China is the largest source of acid deposition precursors and these pollutants travel
outside of national boundaries to be deposited in other countries.
ENVIRONMENTAL TAXES
Based on Pigou’s solution to externalities of imposing a tax equal to the
externality costs (Pigou, 1920), environmental or “green taxes” are used worldwide to
control pollution. In contrast to the regulatory nature of CAC strategies, environmental
6
Tammy Coe
Ecological Economic Theory
Fall 2003
taxes use economic theory and the market system to protect public goods. Although the
degree of environmental protection is not as absolute as with CAC strategies,
environmental taxes often lead to more long-term behavioral changes (Milne, 2003).
Often environmental taxes are complimented with government subsidies for abatement
technologies, making it more cost effective to use abatement strategies instead of paying
the tax, thus providing further incentive for reducing emissions. In countries employing
environmental taxes, income tax is generally reduced and the tax base shifts to
environmental taxes. Businesses receive compensation for paying environmental taxes
through reductions in their contributions to employees’ social security funds (EEA,
2000).
Environmental taxes have been the key policy initiative for European countries
looking to internalize the costs of pollution. European environmental taxes include all
taxes on energy, transportation, pollution, and resources, which accounted for 6.71% of
the European tax base in 1997 (EEA, 2000). Worldwide, environmental taxes account for
less than 3% of tax revenue (Fischlowitz-Roberts, 2002). All European countries have a
tax on motor fuels and most have a tax on motor vehicle registration and use. In recent
years, an increasing number of European countries have imposed taxes on energy use and
industrial emissions. At the same time, income taxes are reduced to offset the cost of
environmental taxes (EEA, 2000). Sweden, Denmark, and The Netherlands have been
leaders in this tax-base shift from income taxes to environmental taxes.
Sweden was one of the first countries to start a tax-base shift, beginning in 1991
with taxes on sulfur and carbon emissions that were offset by reductions in income tax.
At this time they also imposed a tax on fuels based on the amount of sulfur (4.40 US$/kg
S). Only those fuels with less than 0.1% S content were exempt. Because of these taxes,
the average content of S in fuels has steadily decreased. In just the first year, the average
amount of S in diesel fuel dropped from 0.15% to 0.10%. As a result, Swedish authorities
continued to lower the S level at which taxes were incurred. By 2000, only fuels with less
than 0.005% S were exempt from taxes (EEA, 2000). Swedish taxes on electricity have
also proven to be successful. As of 2000, energy taxes have reduced emissions by 4%
below 1990 levels in Sweden, while the economy and population continued to grow
(Fischlowitz-Roberts, 2002). By reducing income taxes and shifting the tax base to
7
Tammy Coe
Ecological Economic Theory
Fall 2003
energy, citizens gain more control in determining how their money is spent and feel
empowered to make energy-conserving choices, thus reducing the amount of pollution
from these sources.
Denmark’s tax shift from income to environmental taxes is the highest in Europe.
As of 2000, 9.5% of Denmark’s tax base came from environmental taxes (EEA, 2000).
Their energy taxes are among the highest in the world, with the largest income resulting
from an aggressive tax on SO2 emissions that was implemented in 1996. Their car
registration tax, which is based on vehicle fuel efficiency, is the highest in Europe. As a
result of effectively incorporating the externalities of fossil fuel consumption into its
price, consumer and producer behavior has undeniably changed. Denmark has
consequently become a world leader in wind turbine and energy-efficient appliance
industries (Fischlowitz-Roberts, 2002). The demand for renewable energy technologies
and efficient products spiked due to high taxes on fossil fuel consumption and firms
answered that demand.
The Netherlands is another fine example of a tax base shift resulting in new
technologies and a cleaner environment. Second only to Denmark, 9.4% of Dutch tax
base is generated from environmental taxes (EEA, 2000). Their Green Tax Commission
implemented a broad Regulatory Energy Tax (RET) on natural gas, fuel oil, electricity,
and heating oil. The goal of RET was to change consumer behavior, rather than generate
revenue. Most of the tax is borne by the consumer, effectively increasing the cost of
household energy use. In exchange for this increase in energy costs, income taxes were
reduced. The RET has resulted in a 15% decrease in household energy use and 10%
decrease in fuel use since its inception in 1998 (Fischlowitz-Roberts, 2002). Like
Denmark, The Netherlands is a world leader in renewable energy technologies,
particularly wind turbines and solar power (EEA, 2000).
TRADABLE PERMITS
In a tradable permit system, authorities set a maximum level of total emissions
nationwide and distribute limits to individual pollution sources, much like CAC
strategies. Instead of collecting fees for non-compliance, however, tradable permits take
8
Tammy Coe
Ecological Economic Theory
Fall 2003
pollution control into the economic market. Polluters who reduce emissions below their
limit receive pollution “credits” equal to the extra pollution kept from the atmosphere.
These credits or permits are tradable in that polluting companies can use the permits to
offset pollution at other sources that they own, sell the permits to other firms, or bank
them for future use. If a firm must exceed pollution limits, they must purchase permits to
do so. The major benefit of this system is its focus on total pollutant levels, which is
better correlated to environmental damage than setting maximum emission rates at
individual sources (Schmalensee et al, 1998).
Lately trends in environmental externality policy have been leaning toward
adoption of a tradable permit system to replace CAC strategies. The U.S. has been a
leader in the development of such policies. Originally the Clean Air Act Amendments of
1970 and 1977 imposed CAC strategies similar to those discussed earlier. In 1990 the
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency amended the Clean Air Act once again, including
the establishment of an SO2 and NOX permit trading program. The program capped total
SO2 emissions from point sources nationwide at 11.2 million tons, decreasing annually to
reach 4.5 million tons in 2010 and 3 million tons in 2018. NOX emissions are capped at
5.1 million tons, decreasing to 2.1 million tons in 2010 and 1.7 million tons in 2018
(EPA, 2003). Total reductions in emissions by 2018 amount to a 73% reduction in SO2
and a 67% reduction in NOX emissions from 2000 levels.
Early effects on emissions due to the implementation of the tradable permit
system showed a significant decrease in SO2 emissions. For example, in 1995 SO2
emissions were 5.2 tons – 39% below the set cap for that year (Schmalensee et al, 1998).
One reason for this over-compliance is that many of the pollutant permits are being
banked for future use because the cost of a permit is expected to increase significantly as
cap levels decline. Because the tradable permit system acts within the economic market
system, as fewer permits are allowed (based on lower emissions caps), demand for the
permits increases, resulting in higher costs. Although this system has resulted in
decreased SO2 emissions, the fact that many companies have banked permits does not
bode well for future reductions. Another reason for the over-compliance involves
influence from other market factors. In the mid-1990s rail rates declined, allowing
inexpensive access to low-S fuels in Wyoming (Schmalensee et al, 1998). By extracting,
9
Tammy Coe
Ecological Economic Theory
Fall 2003
refining, transporting, and burning low S coal, many power plants are able to meet pointsource emissions standards from their plants. Because the transportation sector does not
participate in the tradable permit program, emissions have essentially been transferred
from point source to mobile source emissions.
The U.S. EPA has declared the tradable permit system a success – SO2 rates have,
in fact, declined. However, this decline has not prompted a reduction in acid deposition.
This is likely due to the fact that although SO2 emissions are declining, total NOX
emissions are not. More NOX is emitted from the transportation sector than from the
point sources regulated in the cap-and-trade program. Unlike Europe’s environmental
taxes that are more equally distributed between transportation and energy sectors, the
U.S. cap-and-trade program does not address the mobile sources of acid-causing
pollutants.
CONCLUSIONS
The general trend in pollution control policies is to move from CAC strategies to
those that work within the market framework – environmental taxes or tradable permit
programs. These alternatives have proven successful in reducing emissions in a costeffective manner, but they must address issues of scale and equity in order to be effective
over the long term. European countries have been successful in reducing pollution and
providing incentives for renewable energy technologies because the scale of the tax is
appropriate to elicit such changes. If the tax were set too low, consumers would have
chosen to simply pay the tax rather than reduce their emissions. Since consumers pay a
tax on each unit of pollution, there is always an incentive to reduce emissions through
new technologies or efficient behaviors. Environmental taxes, therefore, provide
incentives both for firms to develop more efficient technologies and for consumers to
change their behaviors.
In terms of the three main principles of ecological economic theory - sustainable
scale, equitable distribution, and efficient allocation - tradable permit policies fall short of
being the panacea for pollution control. As is the case with most policies based around
efficient allocation, tradable permits are a success. They present a cost-effective way of
10
Tammy Coe
Ecological Economic Theory
Fall 2003
reducing emissions, based on our existing market system. The question of sustainable
scale is much more difficult to answer. As discussed earlier, uncertainties abound in
terms of appropriate levels at which to set caps. The lack of correlation between reduced
SO2 emissions from the U.S. cap-and-trade program and a reduction in acid deposition
indicates that this policy is not the ultimate solution to the problem. The tradable permit
system does not address mobile sources because it works at a different scale. Imagine a
policy where automobile drivers had a set level of pollutants they could emit during the
course of a year. If you wanted to take a cross-country road trip and you might have to
bank permits or purchase them on the market in order to do it. This policy would not be
very cost-effect and enforcement would be difficult, if not impossible.
Perhaps the greatest failure of the cap-and-trade program is its lack of regard to
issues of equitable distribution across time and space. In temporal terms, the strong overcompliance of today could lead to more pollution in the future as firms cash in on their
banked permits. This creates an equity problem across generations. The cap-and-trade
program also does little to address the fact that acid deposition is a non-localized
problem. Midwestern coal-fired power plants can purchase permits to maximize
production while Northeastern states pay in terms of increased acid deposition. A third
equity failure can occur if one firm owns several pollutant sources. That firm could opt to
clean up one source to well below cap limits and give their earned pollution credits to the
other sources.
The best policies for reducing pollution must consider ecological and human
health effects when determining a sustainable scale for pollution levels. In absence of
hard data indicating safe pollutant levels for ecosystem and human health, policies to
address pollution should focus on reductions in general, coupled with monitoring to track
effects. Policies should also focus on adaptive management principles and be flexible
when monitoring data indicates a need for change. In the case of acid deposition
policymakers might make more headway if ecosystem vulnerability is used as a guideline
for equitable distribution. More vulnerable systems, like those in the Northeastern U.S.
that have received relatively more acid deposition, could be protected by stricter
standards in areas that are source regions for the Northeast.
11
Tammy Coe
Ecological Economic Theory
Fall 2003
On a final note, one must address the issue of enforcement. In recent months, the
Bush administration has implemented several exemptions for firms to disregard the Clean
Air Act provisions by relaxing regulations. This ironically named Clear Skies Act
undermines the Clean Air Act’s New Source Review laws (NRDC, 2003). The New
Source Review requires old plants to install modern abatement technologies before
expanding and increasing emissions. Under the new legislation, these provisions would
be weakened, allowing 20,000 older facilities to increase emissions in order to expand
and increase profits. The first step towards effective pollution prevention policy is to
enforce its regulations. With exemptions like ones proposed in the Clear Skies Act, the
U.S. cap-and-trade program has little hope of success in reducing acid deposition.
12
Tammy Coe
Ecological Economic Theory
Fall 2003
REFERENCES
Ayers, R.U. and Kneese, A.V. 1969. Production, consumption and externalities.
American Economic Review, 59, 282-297.
Baron, D.P. 1985. Noncooperative regulation of a nonlocalized externality. Rand Journal
of Economics, 16(4), 553-567.
European Environment Agency. 2000. Environmental taxes: recent developments in tools
for integration. Copenhagen, Denmark: European Environment Agency.
Fischlowitz,-Roberts, B. 2002. Analysis: restructuring taxes to shelter the earth.
Washington, D.C.: Earth Policy Institute.
Kochi, I., Shunji, M., Matsumoto, R., Iwase, M., Memon, M.A. Cost benefit analysis of
the sulfur dioxide emissions control policy in Japan.
Koomey, J. and Krause, F. 1997. Introduction to Environmental Externality Costs. CRC
Handbook on Energy Efficiency. Boca Raton, FL: CRC Press, Inc.
McGee, E. 1997. Acid Rain and Our Nation's Capital: A Guide to Effects on Buildings
and Monuments. Denver, CO: U.S. Geological Survey Information Services
Milne, J.E., 2003. Environmental taxation: Why theory matters. Draft.
Morishima, A. 1999. Japan’s environmental policies amid a changing global landscape.
Tokyo, Japan: National Institute for Research Advancement Review.
Natural Resources Defense Council (NRDC). 2003. Clean air and energy: Air pollution
brief. Online: http://www.nrdc.org/air/pollution/qbushplan.asp#clearskies last
updated September 5, 2003.
Pigou, A.C. 1920. Economics of Welfare. London, England: MacMillan and Company
Limited.
Raufer, R. 1999. Urban Air Pollution Control Programme Newsletter, No. 4, May 1999.
Beijing, People’s Republic of China: China International Center for Economic
and Technical Exchanges.
Schaberg, P.G., DeHayes, D.H., Hawley, G.J. 2001. Anthropogenic calcium depletion: A
unique threat to forest ecosystem health? Ecosystem Health, 7(4), 214-228.
Schmalensee, R., Joskow, P.L., Ellerman, A.D., Montero, J.P., Bailey, E.M. 1998. An
interim evaluation of sulfur dioxide emissions trading. The Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 12 (3), 53-68.
13
Tammy Coe
Ecological Economic Theory
Fall 2003
U.S. Department of Energy. 1995. Electricity generation and environmental externalities:
case studies. Washington, D.C.: Energy Information Administration, Office of
Coal, Nuclear, Electric and Alternate Fuels.
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. 2003. Clear Skies Initiative. Online:
http://www.epa.gov/air/clearskies/basic.html last updated September 8, 2003.
Wetstone, G.S. and Rosencranz. 1983. Acid Rain in Europe and North America: National
Responses to an International Problem. Washington, D.C.: Environmental Law
Institute.
Wu, Z., Wang, J., Meng, F. 2000. Proposed scenarios for total amount control of sulfur
dioxide during the tenth five-years in China. Paper presented at the Second EPASEPA Workshop on Sulfur Dioxide Emissions Trading, Washington, D.C.
14
Download